Skip to main content

Mexico's Experience With Single-firm Dominant Conduct


Slide 1

Comisión Federal De Competencia México Logo

Mexico's experience with
single-firm dominant conduct


Eduardo Pérez Motta

September 2006

 


Slide 2

The Constitution provides a broad definition of illegal anticompetitive practices...

Article 28: Monopolies, monopolistic practices and
government monopolies are prohibited. The law will severely
punish:

Check MarkAll concentration or hoarding in one or a few hands of basic commodities with the object of raising prices",

Check Mark All agreements, processes or combinations undertaken by producers, industrialists, tradesmen or service entrepreneurs, to prevent competition or free market access or competition and force consumers to pay exaggerated prices"

Check Mark Whatever constitutes an undue exclusive advantage in favor of one or more persons and against the public in general or a certain social class"


Slide 3

... and the Federal Law of Economic Competition (LFCE) translates these definitions into specific procedures - one of which addresses single-firm dominant conduct

Procedure Relevant LFCE provisions
Merger review process Article 16: The CFC shall challenge and punish those concentrations whose object or effect is to diminish, damage or impede competition and free market access involving similar or substantially related goods and services
Absolute monopolistic practices Article 9: Contracts, agreements or combinations among competing agents whose object or effect is to: 1) fix prices, 2) restrict output, 3) divide markets, 4) rig bids. These conducts shall have no legal effects

Relative
monopolistic practices

Articles 10 (in conjunction with 11,12 and 13), 7 and 24 paragraph V

Today's subject


Slide 4

The Commission evaluates relative monopolistic practices through two broadly defined processes

  Description Legal basis (LFCE)
Conduct Relative monopolistic practices: acts, agreements or combinations whose object or effect is to unduly exclude, substantially impede access, or establish exclusive advantages in favor of one or more persons. Subject to rule of reason analysis
  • Art. 10 (typification of practices)
  • Arts. 11,12, 13 (rule of reason)
Regulation Declaration on effective competition conditions: CFC empowered to resolve on the existence of effective competition conditions as a prerequisite for economic regulation by sectoral regulators or the Ministry of the Economy
  • Art. 7 (Ministry of the Economy)
  • Art. 24 (sectoral regulators)

Slide 5

The LFCE lays out a structured analysis process to determine whether a conduct constitutes an illegal practice

Steps for analysis (LFCE)

  Practice Object or effect Rule of reason Efficiencies
Steps for analysis (LFCE)
How does it work?

Typifies observed conduct into one of 11 practices

Determines if conduct:
Arrow Unduly excludes
Arrow Substantially impedes access
Arrow Establishes exclusive advantages

Agent must wield substantial market power in the relevant market

Efficiency defense must show:
Arrow Conduct has favorable effect on competition
Arrow Anticompetitive effects offset by consumer benefits

Why is it there? Typification provides legal certainty Size does not demonstrate harm Competitor injury doesn't demonstrate a violation What's important is the net effect on welfare

Slide 6

Relative practices are not limited to single-firm dominant conduct...

Relative monopolistic practices typified in Art. 10 LFCE

[D]


Slide 7

... and some of them were only recently raised to the level of law

Relative monopolistic practices typified in Art. 10 LFCE

  1. Vertical market division by reason of geography or time
  2. Vertical price restrictions
  3. Tied sales
  4. Exclusive dealing
  5. Refusals to deal
  6. Exclusionary group boycotts
  7. Predation
  8. Loyalty discounts
  9. Cross subsidization
  10. Discrimination in price, sales or purchasing conditions
  11. Raising rivals' costs
[Applies to VII-XI]
  • Previously contained in catch-all provision and specificed in LFCE rules (therefore declared unconstitutional)
  • Clarified during reforms

Slide 8

Efficiency considerations may tilt the balance against illegality of single-firm dominant conduct

Case example: Wal Mart

Claim v. Efficiencies image

[D]


Slide 9

Mexico's competition law doesn't prosecute exploitative prices, but allows for price regulation when warranted by competition analysis

Article 24 LFCE Article 7 LFCE
  • Sectoral legislation foresees price regulation only when effective competition conditions are absent:
    Arrow
    • Telecommunications
      Arrow Railroads
      Arrow LP gas
  • CFC charged with judging whether competition conditions exist
  • The Executive has the constitutional attribution to issue price controls throughout the economy
  • Recent reforms to LFCE now require the Executive to obtain a CFC resolution declaring the absence of competition conditions before exercising this attribution

Slide 10

A dominance determination triggers sectoral regulation in telecommunications (once litigation concludes)

Case example: Telmex
 

  • The Federal Telecommunications Law empowers the Commission to determine if carriers have a dominant position
  • A dominance determination allows the Federal Telecommunications Commission to impose specific obligations on this carrier

In 1997 the Commission initiated an ex-officio procedure to determine if Telmex had a dominant position

The Commission determined that Telmex possessed substantial market power in five telephony markets:

  1. Local telephony service
  2. National long distance service
  3. International long distance service
  4. Access or interconnection to local networks
  5. Interurban transport
Underpinning the CFC's analysis were the following considerations:
  • Telmex's degree of vertical integration
  • Its ability to unilaterally fix prices
  • The existence of high entry barriers

Telmex amparo still pending

Updated December 29, 2023