N002193

Monday, January 21, 2002 7:45 PM
Comments on documented Interim Rules

To:
Kenneth Feinberg
Deborah E. Greenspan
Office of the Special Master

Re:
Comments on the Interim Rules of the 9/11 Victim Compensation Fund

From:

We have received from your office the additional information on the presumed economic loss calculations for the September 11 Victim Compensation Fund, and we have comments on the Interim Rules for calculating damages. First, we want to thank you for making this information available.

We agree with      comments to us that much confusion has occurred over the past month concerning the interpretation of the Interim Rules, and that a number of families of victims have, rightly or wrongly, been disturbed by the presumed economic loss calculations for the VCF. We would point out that this confusion partially results from the lack of detail and explanation contained in the original release of the rules on December 20. It was impossible to replicate or adjust the calculations given the level of information provided. The first explanatory release contained no specific information or documentation on effective tax rates, self-consumption rates, work-life expectancy, fringe benefit rates, or decipherable application of age-earnings growth rates. Whether the last formulas were part of the original calculation, or were added in response to criticism, is really irrelevant. We are grateful that that information has now been released and we have an additional set of observations concerning the accuracy and fairness of the calculations. You have not provided information related to documented sources that you relied upon, or will be relying on, to determine "effective tax rates" or the sources of the life-cycle earning adjustments (you simple state two actuarial boards). You have provided no detail regarding how the discount rate was determined and then adjusted for taxes, and the information regarding the self-consumption rates appears to be deficient. We hope that you will release this information as a part of the final rules.

You are correct that no one model will be viewed as fair or appropriate to all groups, or that one set of compensation tables will be relevant to a specific individual. You have stated that individual factors will be considered in each case of compensation, and that individuals may appeal your findings through the submission of an alternative set of compensation assumptions. No one can predict the outcome of such appeals in advance, but we are sure that you will strive to give a fair hearing to all claimants. Obviously, families will be reluctant to sign-up as claimants for the VCF without knowing the outcome of the final compensation in advance, but the same would be true in a litigation arena. We appreciate the opportunity to provide you with recommendations for enhancing the procedures for compensating the September 11 victims and their families. We know this is a difficult and unenviable task for you as Special Master. We have talked to a number of families of victims, as you have, and we can understand their anxieties about the compensation process. Our comments are directed at assuring the families that the process will be fair and accurate.

Specific changes to the methods of compensating economic damages can still be made that will address some of the concerns of economists and the victims' families. Below we offer some comments that fit broadly as a part of the plan. There are many specific issues that we do not address. We continue to offer a group meeting with you and your experts along with leading authorities in the academic study of forensic economics to go over the many necessary adjustments to your basic structure that will force a response on a case-by-case basis.

The most obvious deficiency in the plan is the omission of lost services as an economic loss suffered by families of victims who were working on September 11. The plan calls for the calculation of the value of such lost services for non-working or part-time working victims, but provides no direct compensation to families of working victims as clearly referenced in the "Act." Lost household services are almost universally recognized as an element of economic loss in personal injury/death litigation. There are a number of statistical sources and procedures for making such calculations, and their absence in the plan to all victim families is inappropriate.

The following are comments in the order matching your "Explanation of Process for Computing Presumed Economic Loss" that you released Friday, January 18, 2002 as follows:

1. Establish the victim's age and compensable income.

You should adjust the three years of earnings information to a 2001 constant dollar base. For example, in 1998 the Consumer Price Index for All Items (CUUR0000SA0) was 163.0, in 1999 it was 166.6, in 2000 it was 172.2, and in 2001 it was 177.1. Under this one approach, you would multiply 1998 total earnings by 177.1/163.0, 1999 total earnings by 177.1/166.6, and 2000 total earnings by 177.1/172.2. The average earnings will now be in base 2001 dollars for projection into the future.

As an example of the appropriateness of this calculation, it is easy to see that you would never average nominal earnings in 1990 (say $12.00 per hour) with nominal earnings in 2000 (say $20.00 per hour), for an expected earnings level of $16.00 per hour in 2001. The same logic applies when averaging 1998-2000 earnings for a 2001 earnings base.

2. Determine after-tax compensable income

The tax rate data for this adjustment has yet to be published by your office so comment is difficult. An average effective tax rate across various household types can be deceiving. You note that you will consider the victim's tax returns, please do so. Also keep in mind the differences in tax rates possible based upon position in life with circumstances such as home mortgage deductions, number of dependents, tax deferred income, etc. For example, even though a person might earn $100,000 at their job, through 401(k) plans they might be able to defer up to $15,000 of that income. So, current income taxes would be computed on $85,000 of W-2 taxable earnings instead of $100,000. Simply applying some average statistics will not satisfy the requirement for this adjustment. Perhaps a more appropriate methodology would be to use the Consumer Expenditure Survey data, which actually includes tax payments by level of household income. We find it inconsistent that you are going to use national data for some major economic adjustments, but for a subtraction from loss you are planning to use local income tax rates, which are in many cases higher than national averages due to domicile.

3. Add pension and other benefits.

You state, absent supplied information, that you will substitute $2,400 per year in current dollars for loss of health insurance. To be made whole, loss must be based upon the cost to secure replacement insurance in the market by age and number of dependents. The $2,400 figure might be insufficient in many cases to replace this loss. We urge you to probe each claimant for the correct figures in each case.

Pension and other benefits can be very complicated. Many financial workers will be accumulating stock options, profit sharing, ownership positions, etc., which will require very detailed analysis. We urge you to consult known experts when making these computations.

Whatever collateral source benefit you deduct, you will need to consider adding the benefit back for an offset due to loss of benefit accumulation. For example, you state that you are deducting current pension income as a collateral source, so you rightly add it back in as a benefit. However, if you deduct current Social Security collateral income, you may also need to also add that benefit back in. For example, a survivor's Social Security is based upon the decedents earned Social Security credit to the time of death. A future Social Security benefit would be based upon additional Social Security credits at a higher earning level. By receiving Social Security now, lost Social Security may exist in the future. There is a literature in the forensic economic field regarding these calculations.

4. Worklife expectancy

The use of the Ciecka Work-Life Expectancies is an improvement over the previously unavoidable presumed use of Bulletin 2254 Work-Life Tables. Officials at the Department of Labor had told us that your analysts requested the Bulletin 2254 tables, and no mention of the Ciecka tables was contained in the Interim Rules.

These tables, however, still must be used with caution. The tables represent average labor force participation and death rates for males and females, by age, which may have limited applicability to a specific individual. A working single mother will likely have a longer worklife than a married wife/mother who has elected to stay at home because of financial security. Nevertheless, both are contained in the same average length of expected labor force participation. Many forensic economists generally use the "Male" category for career working females. We urge that education also be considered when using the tables.

An inconsistency in your application of worklife and lost services reveals itself in the case of women. Women often exit the labor force to provide services for their family members. The difference in worklife for younger women is 4 to 5 years shorter than younger men in the Ciecka table. You would compute replacement services loss damages for families of part-time or not in labor force (NILF) women and ignore their potential re-entry into the labor market. However, by using the shortened worklife of women, you implicitly consider the exit from the labor force of women in order to provide services that you compensate those that are NILF on September 11. You should recognize the 4-5 years of projected NILF status of women and at least give them the same damages for these years that you give those that were NILF on September 11. You should also give women who were NILF on September 11, the expected value of their future earnings upon probable future re-entry into the labor force. The problems you face using gender specific worklife tables can be mostly avoided using other gender-indifferent methods of determining worklife. We would be happy to discuss those alternatives with you and your experts.

Finally, Professor Ciecka, through his own publishing company, sells an expanded set of worklife tables based upon the exact methodology and data contained within his JLE article. We urge that you use the accurate, detailed tables that Professor Ciecka offers for sale instead of the abbreviated tables published in the JLE.

5. Project compensable income

The assumed growth rates in future earnings will likely overcompensate the lower paid (low human capital) individuals under 30, while under compensating the highly educated and high earner individuals. The methodology you employ is not generally accepted in the abundant literature regarding life-cycle earnings. The use of established age-earnings cycle formula by level of human capital would be preferable to the methods you employed in the proposed loss tables. Age-earning cycles should be recomputed based upon human capital. You have also not provided citation to the life-cycle growth rates in your calculations.

6. Present value

You continue to not document the source for the interest rate and the procedure you used to adjust the interest rate for income taxes. In footnote 5, your statement of the net discount rates is mathematically incorrect, using a simple subtraction of growth rates from the discount rate rather than a geometric subtraction.

You will have to use a non-tax adjusted interest rate (i.e. pre-tax nominal interest rate) when figuring the present value of some collateral sources. For example, some collateral sources will generate taxable income (e.g. Social Security survivor benefits may be taxable given the level of future other income and most pension benefits would also be taxable) and using an after-tax interest rate to compute present value for the annuity collateral benefits will overstate their present value.

Reducing loss for pension, thrift or profit sharing payments and life insurance creates a set of potential difficulties in calculating loss. For example, the future marriage of a surviving spouse could revoke payments in specific pension or survivors benefit payments that would occur in the future. Yet, the loss might already be reduced for such payments. The calculation of net losses and gains in Social Security and pension payments because of early death or disability is very complex. These collateral income reductions will be a continuing source of conflict between the VCF and the families of victims.

7. Self-consumption

Self-consumption rates appear to be liberal in many cases. It is troubling, however, that you list Table 2 of the CES 1999 as the source for the computations. Table 2 simply presents consumption in households by total income level up to $69,999 and then $70,000 and over. Additional data would be required to make the calculations you show. For example, you compute rates for single households where no data for single households exist in Table 2. The understanding of the data is also limited by your comment about low-income households. Low-income households and low-earning households do not necessarily correspond. There is a portion of households in the low household total income range that are, in actuality, very wealthy households. For example, farmers owning 1000's of acres of land with millions of dollars of cash flow and expenditures could show $2,000 of total household income figuring huge farming losses. Such outlier households, in Table 2, are averaged with living poor with an actual $2,000 of total income and cash flow. The Consumer Expenditure Survey is a relatively small sample and just a few households can skew estimates. We urge caution when working with data at the low and high end of these income categories.

8. Computation methodology favors claimants

Statements you make in this paragraph are non-economic. You believe that your methods favor the claimants, but fail to provide relevant comparators. For example, a projected worklife of 20 years would benefit a person dying of cancer on 9-11, but it could hardly be applicable in the case of many career-working females.

Your last statement is without basis and can easily be turned around with relevant economic analysis. Your "wage growth" as stated in your documents is 1.03*1.005-1 = 3.52%. Your post-tax discount rate is 5.13%. The combination of these rates computes to a net post-tax discount rate of 1.56%. A post-tax net discount rate of 1.56% is not uncommon to see in wrongful death damages litigation. Unfortunately, you are confused in your secondary application of a series of life-cycle adjustments to account for growth due to individual productivity with the concept of the "net discount rate" that is used in the academic literature. In the academic literature, the net discount rate is the difference between the discount rate and the general rate of price or wage rate growth absent individual productivity. The application of life-cycle adjustments adds a concept outside the net discount rate term and your remark has no comparator in the literature. Every case generates a net discount rate that can be compared across cases, but it also generates a unique value of life-cycle adjustment. Your statement may provide confusion to academic work presented in courtrooms in the future that follow the generally accepted approach of comparing net discount rates.

Although you do not provide documentation of your pre-tax interest rate, we can turn around your arguments in this section with a simple adjustment. Suppose that you made a 25% adjustment to the interest rate to account for taxes. Dividing 5.13% by 75% yields a pre-tax discount rate of 6.84%, a reasonable figure if you are taking a historical average. Now, the relevant net discount rate that you are using must be figure on 6.84% and 3.52% to be comparable to those net discount rates in the literature. Under the 25% assumed tax adjustment, the net wage rate discount rate would be 1.0684/1.0352-1 = 3.21%, which would fall at the higher end of observed pre-tax net discount rates, not the lower.

Individual Comment

Previous Next Back to Comments by Date Back to Comments by Date
(Graphical Version) (Text Only Version)