Skip to main content
Brief

Dentsply Int'l, Inc. v. United States -
Opposition/Title>

Docket Number
No. 05-337
Supreme Court Term
2005 Term
Type
Petition Stage Response
Court Level
Supreme Court

No. 05-337

In the Supreme Court of the United States

DENTSPLY INTERNATIONAL, INC., PETITIONER

v.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

ON PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI
TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT

BRIEF FOR THE UNITED STATES IN OPPOSITION

PAUL D. CLEMENT
Solicitor General
Counsel of Record
THOMAS O. BARNETT
Acting Assistant Attorney
General
GERALD F. MASOUDI
Deputy Assistant Attorney
General
ROBERT B. NICHOLSON
ADAM D. HIRSH
Attorneys
Department of Justice
Washington, D.C. 20530-0001
(202) 514-2217

QUESTION PRESENTED

Whether the court of appeals erred in holding that a monopolist's successful efforts to prevent key dealers from distributing the products of its rivals violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 2, when those efforts contribute significantly to the preservation of the manufacturer's monopoly and serve no purpose other than to eliminate competition.

In the Supreme Court of the United States

No. 05-337

DENTSPLY INTERNATIONAL, INC., PETITIONER

v.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

ON PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI
TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT

BRIEF FOR THE UNITED STATES IN OPPOSITION

OPINIONS BELOW

The opinion of the court of appeals (Pet. App. 1a-26a) is reported at 399 F.3d 181. The opinion of the district court (Pet. App. 27a-145a) is reported at 277 F. Supp. 2d 387.

JURISDICTION

The judgment of the court of appeals was entered on February 24, 2005. A petition for rehearing was denied on May 17, 2005. Pet. App. 146a-147a. On July 28, 2005, Justice Souter extended the time within which to file a petition for a writ of certiorari to and including Septem ber 14, 2005, and the petition was filed on that date. The jurisdiction of this Court is invoked under 28 U.S.C. 1254(1).

STATUTORY PROVISION INVOLVED

Section 2 of the Sherman Act provides, in relevant part: "Every person who shall monopolize * * * any part of the trade or commerce among the several States * * * shall be deemed guilty of a felony." 15 U.S.C. 2.

STATEMENT

The United States alleged in this antitrust action that petitioner Dentsply International, Inc., maintained its monopoly in prefabricated artificial teeth in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 2, by prevent ing independent tooth dealers from distributing the teeth manufactured by petitioner's rivals. The com plaint also claimed that petitioner made exclusive deal ing agreements that are illegal under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1, and Section 3 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 14. Following a bench trial, the district court entered judgment for petitioner on all counts. Pet. App. 27a-145a. The United States appealed the district court's Section 2 ruling. The court of appeals held that the district court incorrectly applied the controlling le gal standards and that several of its key findings of fact were clearly erroneous. Id. at 1a-26a. The court of ap peals therefore reversed, and remanded "with directions to grant injunctive relief requested by the Government." Id. at 26a.

1. The district court made extensive findings of fact. Pet. App. 28a-134a. It properly found that the relevant market is the market for "sale of prefabricated artificial teeth in the United States" and that petitioner has held, "for at least" a decade, a "predominant market share" amounting to 75% to 80% of the market, based on reve nue. Id. at 28a (FF 1), 88a-89a (FF 238-240), 140a (CL 23).1 Petitioner's "primary" and "next closest" competi tors, Ivoclar and Vita, have 5% and 3% market shares, respectively. Id. at 32a (FF 26), 34a (FF 36), 89a (FF 239).

The district court also found that petitioner is the "price leader" in the market, has "a reputation for ag gressive price increases," and "create[s] a high-price umbrella" for artificial teeth. Pet. App. 85a-86a (FF 226, 230). Petitioner "has not reacted with lower prices when others have not followed its price increases." Id. at 86a (FF 229). Although the tooth market has been "stagnant in terms of unit growth," id. at 88a (FF 237), the district court found that petitioner's profit margins on teeth have been "high" and "increasing over time," id. at 88a (FF 233-234), and its tooth division "has long been a highly profitable, 'cash cow' business," id. at 88a (FF 235).

As the district court recognized, petitioner sells its teeth and related products exclusively through a net work of 23 national and regional dental laboratory deal ers, which collectively have about 100 tooth stock outlets essentially covering almost every major metropolitan area and far exceeding the number of stocks of any com petitor. Pet. App. 31a (FF 20, 22), 38a (FF 56), 52a (FF 109); C.A. App. A1931-A1932. Those dealers supply the 7,000 dental laboratories that fabricate dentures with "the full range of products that dental labs use." Pet. App. 37a-39a (FF 55, 58-59). The dealers are "inde pendent businesses, selling under their own name and not [petitioner's], and offering thousands of different products that are made by hundreds of different manu facturers," including "large inventories" of artificial teeth. Id. at 80a (FF 212), 38a (FF 57). The services that dealers provide to laboratories include delivery, same-day availability, one-stop shopping, handling tooth returns, inventory management, and handling accounts receivable. Id. at 45a-49a (FF 82-98). Petitioner is the only tooth manufacturer that makes no direct sales to laboratories. Id. at 2a, 31a-32a, 34a-35a, 36a, 57a-58a, 60a (FF 20, 27, 40, 47, 131, 139).

The district court found that, for more than fifteen years, petitioner has operated under a policy that dis courages its dealers from adding competitors' teeth to their product lines. See Pet. App. 69a (FF 174). Peti tioner prohibits existing dealers from adding the teeth of competitors-a policy codified in 1993 as Dealer Cri terion 6-and, as a condition of acceptance, requires prospective Dentsply tooth dealers to drop most or all competing brands.2 Id. at 68a, 70a (FF 169-170, 178). Under a "grandfather" provision, petitioner has permit ted dealers to continue carrying competing brands that they were carrying when that criterion was announced. Id. at 70a (FF 175). Vita and Ivoclar, however, are "not among the grandfathered brands." Id. at 127a-128a (FF 349).

The district court found that the "express" and "sole" purpose of Dealer Criterion 6 was "anti-competi tive"-to "block competitive distribution points," "[t]ie up dealers," and "exclude [petitioner's] competitors from the dealers." Pet. App. 81a, 70a, 119a (FF 216, 176, 217, 332). The district court rejected, as "merely pre textual," id. at 143a (CL 37), petitioner's proffered busi ness justifications for its dealer policies-that the poli cies were needed to help "focus" dealers and to prevent "free riding" by rival manufacturers. Id. at 119a-134a (FF 331-369).

The district court also found that petitioner's exist ing and prospective dealers wanted to carry competing brands, and "[v]ehement[ly]" and "vigorously" opposed Dealer Criterion 6. Pet. App. 130a (FF 358). Despite that opposition, petitioner successfully enforced Dealer Criterion 6 by terminating or threatening to terminate several dealers. Id. at 72a-80a (FF 186-211). The dis trict court documented numerous incidents in which pe titioner coerced a current or prospective dealer not to sell rival brands. Id. at 36a, 59a, 69a-72a, 73a-80a, 82a- 84a (FF 47, 136, 174, 179-185, 187-211, 218-223). Al though dealers distributing petitioner's teeth have the legal right to end their agreements at any time without contractual penalty, id. at 53a (FF 110-111), the district court found that since at least 1992 "no dealer ha[d] agreed to walk away from [petitioner's line of] tooth business to take on a competitive line," id. at 70a (FF 177).

Nevertheless, the district court also found that direct distribution to dental laboratories-bypassing deal ers-provided petitioner's rival manufacturers with a "'viable' method of distributing artificial teeth." Pet. App. 42a (FF 71).3 That finding formed the basis for its conclusions that petitioner did not violate the exclusive dealing prohibitions of Section 1 of the Sherman Act or Section 3 of the Clayton Act; did not possess monopoly power; and did not violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act, which prohibits monopoly maintenance. See id. at 140a- 141a (CL 22-26). The court also concluded that the low level of success of rivals Ivoclar and Vita was "due to their own business decisions" regarding poor product choices and marketing, id. at 91a (capitalization altered); id. at 91a-99a (FF 244-268), 137a-138a (CL 15), and that all rivals would increase their competitively important "levels of promotion and marketing" (e.g., sales forces, laboratory education/training, and advertising) if the challenged conduct were enjoined, id. at 129a-130a (FF 355).

The district court stated: "In sum, because direct distribution is viable, non-Dentsply dealers are avail able, and Dentsply dealers may be converted at any time, the [government] has failed to prove that [peti tioner's] actions have been or could be successful in pre venting 'new or potential competitors from gaining a foothold in the market[.]'" Pet. App. 143a (CL 35) (quot ing LePage's Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 159 (3d Cir. 2003) (en banc), cert. denied, 542 U.S. 953 (2004)). The district court held, as an independent basis for dismissal and as a matter of law, that its finding of non-liability under Section 3 of the Clayton Act precluded any violation un der Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Id. at 139a (CL 20).

2. The United States appealed the judgment with respect to monopoly maintenance under Section 2. Pet. App. 5a. The court of appeals unanimously reversed. Id. at 1a, 26a.

a. The court of appeals held that the district court clearly erred in finding that petitioner lacked monopoly power. Pet. App. 13a. The court agreed with the dis trict court that the relevant market consisted of "total sales of artificial teeth to the laboratories and the deal ers combined" and that petitioner's longstanding, "pre dominant" market share is "more than adequate to es tablish a prima facie case" of monopoly power. Id. at 9a- 10a; see id. at 140a (CL 23). The court of appeals re jected, however, the district court's determination that petitioner lacked the power to exclude rivals. Id. at 10a- 14a. It found clearly erroneous the district court's find ing that direct distribution to laboratories provided rival manufacturers with a "viable" distribution alternative to the dealer channel. Id. at 18a. The court of appeals ob served that direct distribution "is 'viable' only in the sense that it is 'possible,' not that it is practical or feasi ble in the market as it exists and functions." Ibid. Un der Section 2 monopoly maintenance law, the "mere ex istence of other avenues of distribution is insufficient without an assessment of their overall significance to the market." Id. at 23a-24a.

The court of appeals concluded that "realities of the marketplace" demonstrate in this case that it is "im practicable for a manufacturer to rely on direct distribu tion to the laboratories in any significant amount." Pet. App. 16a, 18a-19a. Rather, "the firm that ties up the key dealers rules the market," id. at 13a, and petitioner's "grip on its 23 authorized dealers effectively choked off the market for artificial teeth, leaving only a small sliver for competitors," id. at 24a-25a. Hence, rivals employ ing direct distribution could "stay in business," but can not "pose[] a real threat" to petitioner. Id. at 18a-19a (quoting United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 71 (D.C. Cir.) (en banc) (per curiam), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001)). The court of appeals accordingly con cluded that the "evidence demonstrated conclusively that Dentsply had supremacy over the dealer network and it was at that crucial point in the distribution chain that monopoly power over the market for artificial teeth was established." Id. at 13a. See id. at 14a-15a.

The court of appeals further concluded that peti tioner's "blocking of access to the key dealers," and not rivals' "apparent lack of aggressiveness," was responsi ble for the rivals' "paltry results." Pet. App. 11a. The court determined that the evidence established beyond question that petitioner's exclusionary conduct had "a significant effect in preserving [petitioner's] monopoly" and was a "solid pillar of harm to competition." Id. at 15a. It stated that the district court's theory that rival manufacturers could "steal" a dealer away from peti tioner "simply has not proved to be realistic." Id. at 21a; see id. at 25a. Rather, petitioner's "all-or-nothing" pol icy with dealers created "a strong economic incentive for dealers to reject competing lines in favor of [peti tioner's] teeth," despite the dealers' at-will relationship with petitioner. Id. at 19a, 22a, 23a. See id. at 20a-21a. The court of appeals agreed with the district court that petitioner's proffered justifications were "pretextual and did not excuse its exclusionary practices." Id. at 25a.

Finally, the court of appeals rejected as a matter of law the district court's conclusion that a determination that petitioner was not liable under the government's exclusive dealing claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act required a determi nation that petitioner was not liable under the govern ment's monopoly maintenance claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Pet. App. 25a-26a. It also rejected petitioner's corollary argument that the government was precluded from appealing the Section 2 judgment be cause it had not also appealed the adverse judgments under Section 1 or Section 3. See id. at 26a. The court of appeals remanded "with directions to grant the Gov ernment's request for injunctive relief," id. at 1a, and later denied rehearing and rehearing en banc, id. at 146a-147a. Petitioner did not seek a stay of the court of appeals' mandate. See Fed. R. App. P. 41(d)(2).

b. After the court of appeals' mandate issued, the parties made unsuccessful efforts to negotiate a final judgment specifying the appropriate terms of relief. On September 28, 2005, the district court denied the govern ment's motion for entry of its proposed final judgment, pending disposition of this petition. The district court referred the matter to a magistrate judge to assist the parties in negotiating the terms of a final judgment. If those efforts prove unsuccessful, the parties would pro ceed to litigate the remedy.

ARGUMENT

Petitioner's request for a writ of certiorari should be denied. As a threshold matter, petitioner seeks interloc utory review before entry of a final judgment specifying the remedy, contrary to this Court's policy against piecemeal review. More fundamentally, the court of ap peals' decision properly applies settled law to this mo nopoly maintenance claim and does not conflict with any decision of this Court or any court of appeals.

1. Petitioner seeks immediate review of an interloc utory decision that has resolved only petitioner's liabil ity and not the appropriate terms of relief. The court of appeals' decision reversed the district court's final judg ment in favor of petitioner and remanded "with direc tions to grant the Government's request for injunctive relief." Pet. App. 1a. The parties unsuccessfully at tempted to negotiate a joint proposed final judgment, and the district court has now referred the matter to a magistrate judge to assist the parties in reaching a ne gotiated decree. Hence, the Court does not have before it a final judgment in this case.

The interlocutory character of the case "of itself alone furnishe[s] sufficient ground for the denial" of peti tioner's request for this Court's review. Hamilton- Brown Shoe Co. v. Wolf Bros., 240 U.S. 251, 258 (1916); see also ibid. ("except in extraordinary cases, the writ is not issued until final decree"); Brotherhood of Loco motive Firemen v. Bangor & Aroostook R.R., 389 U.S. 327, 328 (1967) ("because the Court of Appeals re manded the case, it is not yet ripe for review by this Court"); Virginia Military Inst. v. United States, 508 U.S. 946 (1993) (Scalia, J., concurring in denial of peti tion for certiorari) ("[w]e generally await final judgment in the lower courts before exercising our certiorari juris diction"); Robert L. Stern et al., Supreme Court Prac tice § 4.18, at 258-261 (8th ed. 2002).

2. Petitioner's challenges to the court of appeals' application of Section 2 monopoly maintenance law are unpersuasive. The court enunciated well-settled legal standards: "A violation of Section 2 consists of two ele ments: (1) possession of monopoly power and (2) '. . . maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.'" Pet. App. 6a (quoting Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992)). Petitioner challenges neither the court of appeals' determination that peti tioner possesses monopoly power, id. at 10a-15a, nor the court's affirmance of the district court's finding that peti tioner's proffered procompetitive justifications were "merely pretextual," id. at 25a, 143a (CL 37).4

a. Petitioner argues that the court of appeals "did not properly consider all existing or potential alternative channels of distribution" (Pet. 13) in determining that petitioner's exclusionary conduct had "a significant ef fect in preserving [petitioner's] monopoly," Pet. App. 15a. That argument, which amounts to merely a dis agreement over the court of appeals' assessment of the facts, plainly does not warrant this Court's review.

In any event, the court of appeals carefully consid ered the various distribution alternatives to petitioner's dealer channel, and the court determined that it was clear that petitioner's "grip on its 23 authorized dealers effectively choked off the market for artificial teeth." Pet. App. 24a. The court explained that the independent dealers that petitioner used were the "key" dealers, "provid[ing] a critical link to end-users," id. at 15a, 24a, and that "the firm that ties up the key dealers rules the market," id. at 13a. Indeed, the district court had found that petitioner sought to deny its rivals access to those dealers precisely because petitioner recognized that those dealers were "key." See id. at 81a (FF 216), 84a (FF 221(e)).

The court of appeals also confirmed the district court's findings that petitioner wooed dealers once those dealers were poised to help rivals improve their compet itive positions and that petitioner authorized dealers it had previously rejected or terminated in order to deny them to rivals. See Pet. App. 12a-13a, 22a, 71a-72a (FF 183-185), 82a-84a (FF 220-223). The court of appeals did not "completely ignore[]" the availability of non- Dentsply dealers, Pet. 13, but rather held that those dealers were competitively insignificant. Petitioner cites the sheer number of remaining distributors with out addressing their relative capabilities. Pet. 14, 16. As the court of appeals emphasized, however, there is a wide disparity in "comparative size" between Dentsply's dealers and the others, contrasting as an example Dillon Co., a non-Dentsply dealer, with Zahn and Patterson, two of petitioner's largest dealers. See Pet. App. 22a (quoting Dillion's president: "Zahn does $2 billion, I do a million-seven. Patterson does over a billion dollars, I do a million-seven. I have ten employees, they have 6,000.").5

b. Contrary to petitioner's contentions (Pet. 14), the court of appeals properly considered the potential effec tiveness of alternative forms of distribution, invoking the principle that a monopolist may not shut competitors out of a major channel of distribution unless there are distribution alternatives that permit a rival "to pose a real threat to [defendant's] monopoly." Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 71; Pet. App. 19a. See Conwood Co., L.P. v. United States Tobacco Co., 290 F.3d 768, 787-788 (6th Cir. 2002) (defendant maintained monopoly through con duct aimed at the best channel of distribution), cert. de nied, 537 U.S. 1148 (2003). The court of appeals deter mined that direct distribution does not pose such a threat, expressly rejecting as clearly erroneous the dis trict court's finding that direct distribution to laborato ries was a "viable" alternative to the dealer channel. Pet. App. 18a-19a. See id. at 16a (the "record is replete with evidence of benefits provided by dealers" to labora tories), 16a-18a (describing benefits of dealers), 24a (peti tioner's dealers "provide a critical link to end-users").6

Petitioner argues that the mere existence of alternative distribution channels precludes liability as a matter of law and that the court of appeals erred by engaging in a "comparative analysis" of the "relative ineffectiveness of selling directly." Pet. 14-15. Cf. Pet. App. 23a-24a. The law of monopoly maintenance, however, is otherwise. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70- 71; see also Conwood, 290 F.3d at 787-788.7

c. Contrary to petitioner's assertion, the court of appeals did not express the view, or even suggest, that it is "per se unlawful" for all "firms with sizeable market shares" to employ exclusive dealing. Pet. 17. Rather, after reviewing the record as a whole in light of the proper legal standard under Section 2, the court of ap peals determined that petitioner-a monopolist-kept rivals out of the dealer channel and thereby preserved its monopoly. See, e.g., Pet. App. 13a, 15a. Although, as petitioner observes (Pet. 16), exclusive dealing contracts may be pro-competitive, both courts below found that petitioner's proffered justifications were "merely pretextual" and that the "express" and "sole purpose" of Dealer Criterion 6 was to exclude competition. Pet. App. 25a, 81a (FF 216-217), 143a (CL 37). Nothing in the court of appeals' fact-intensive decision suggests that it was announcing a per se rule respecting exclusive dealing.

3. Petitioner argues that the court of appeals' deci sion conflicts with Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320 (1961), and six other court of appeals decisions. See Pet. 9-12. Petitioner overlooks a critical distinction: None of those cases purported to address Section 2 monopoly maintenance-the only claim at is sue in the court of appeals in this case. Instead, those supposedly conflicting decisions all focused on exclusive dealing claims arising under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act. Here, the court of appeals determined, under Section 2, that the anticompetitive effects of petitioner's threats and its use of its monopoly power excluded rivals "despite the lack of long term contracts between the manufacturer and its dealers." Pet. App. 1a (emphasis added); see id. at 12a- 13a, 19a-25a.

a. Monopoly maintenance under Section 2 of the Sherman Act has its own elements and standards. See, e.g., LePage's, 324 F.3d at 157 n.10; Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70; U.S. Healthcare, Inc. v. Healthsource, Inc., 986 F.2d 589, 593, 597-598 (1st Cir. 1993). Unlike claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act, which generally require proof that the de fendant possesses market power, Section 2 claims re quire proof of monopoly power, which is "of course, something greater than market power under § 1." East man Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481.

Section 2 reflects the fundamental principle that the conduct of a monopolist is "examined through a special lens: Behavior that might otherwise not be of concern to the antitrust laws-or that might even be viewed as procompetitive-can take on exclusionary connotations when practiced by a monopolist." Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 488 (Scalia, J., dissenting) (citing 3 Philip Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application ¶ 813, at 300-302 (1978)). See also Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70 ("a monopolist's use of exclusive contracts" may violate Sec tion 2 even if it does not violate Section 1); LePage's, 324 F.3d at 157 n.10 (adverse jury finding on plaintiff's "ex clusive dealing claim under § 1 of the Sherman Act and § 3 of the Clayton Act does not preclude the application of evidence of [defendant's] exclusive dealing to support [plaintiff's] § 2 claim").

b. Petitioner mistakenly suggests (Pet. 17) that the government was not entitled to pursue its appeal of the district court's erroneous rejection of the Section 2 claim without also appealing the district court's rejection of the government's claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act or Section 3 of the Clayton Act. The govern ment-not petitioner-is entitled to choose the grounds for a government appeal. To be sure, the district court's holdings respecting Section 1 and Section 3 reflected some of the same erroneous factual findings that the court of appeals ultimately rejected in considering the government's appeal from the Section 2 ruling. See, e.g., Pet. App. 18a-19a (district court's finding of "viability" of direct distribution was clearly erroneous). As the court of appeals correctly observed, however, a judg ment that petitioner unlawfully maintained its monopoly in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act would allow the government to obtain all of the relief that it seeks in this case. Id. at 26a. The government accordingly had no need to seek review of the Section 1 and Section 3 claims, and the court of appeals had no occasion to con sider whether the district court erred with respect to those claims.

c. Petitioner also argues (Pet. 17-18) that this Court's decision in Tampa Electric, supra, precluded the court of appeals from finding Section 2 liability in the absence of Section 3 liability. Petitioner relies on the Court's observation in Tampa Electric that:

We need not discuss the respondents' further conten tion that the contract also violates §1 and §2 of the Sherman Act, for if it does not fall within the broader proscriptions of §3 of the Clayton Act it follows that it is not forbidden by those of the former.

365 U.S. at 335. See Pet. 17 n.7, 18. That statement, which petitioner abstracts without reference to its con text, has no bearing on the situation presented here, which involves anticompetitive conduct by a longstand ing monopolist.

The Court concluded in Tampa Electric that a util ity's requirements contract for coal did not violate Sec tion 3 because it did not "tend to foreclose a substantial volume of competition." 365 U.S. at 335. The Court ac cordingly concluded that the contract could not provide a basis for antitrust liability under any of the three claims before it, none of which involved monopoly main tenance. See Resp. Br. at 61-62 & Reply Br. at 26-27, Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320 (1961) (No. 87) (raising issue of unlawful acquisition of monopoly, but not monopoly maintenance).8 By con trast, the court of appeals in this case reviewed only the government's Section 2 claim. The court of appeals de termined that the government had demonstrated that a monopolist, lacking any nonexclusionary justification, engaged in conduct for the purpose and with the effect of foreclosing competition to maintain its monopoly power. The court of appeals was entitled to make that ruling based on the record before it and, for the reasons discussed above (see p. 16, supra), did not address the question whether petitioner also violated Section 1 or Section 3. See Pet. App. 25a-26a.

d. The decisions of other courts of appeals that peti tioner cites are similarly off point. Those cases all in volve the resolution of fact-intensive challenges to exclu sive dealing under Section 1 of the Sherman Act or Sec tion 3 of the Clayton Act. None of them involves the application of the established standards governing Sec tion 2 monopoly maintenance claims.

In CDC Technologies, Inc. v. IDEXX Laboratories, Inc., 186 F.3d 74 (2d Cir. 1999) (Pet. 11-12), the court rejected a Section 1 claim because all competitors sold directly, the "distributors" provided only sales leads, and the restraint did not prevent the plaintiff from "achiev[ing] distributor coverage almost nationwide" and increasing its sales. 186 F.3d at 76, 80-81. In Omega Environmental, Inc. v. Gilbarco, Inc., 127 F.3d 1157 (9th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 525 U.S. 812 (1998) (Pet. 11), the court determined that there was no viola tion of Section 3 when all of the competitors sold both directly and through dealers, the restraint did not pre vent another competitor from putting together a net work of over 100 dealers, and the market was character ized by "increasing output, decreasing prices, and signif icantly fluctuating market shares." 127 F.3d at 1164; see id. at 1162-1165. And in Healthsource (Pet. 10), the court rejected claims under Section 1 because the plain tiff failed to demonstrate that an HMO's optional exclu sivity with independent doctors had an effect on compe tition. Healthsource, 986 F.2d at 595-597. The court also rejected the plaintiff's claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act for failure to prove a "properly defined product market" within which the defendant "could ap proach monopoly size." Id. at 599; see id. at 597-599.

In Seagood Trading Corp. v. Jerrico, Inc., 924 F.2d 1555 (11th Cir. 1991) (Pet. 12), the court of appeals re jected a Section 1 claim of exclusive dealing because the exclusive relationship foreclosed only "one provider in the enormous market for restaurant delivery services." 924 F.2d at 1572-1573. In Ryko Manufacturing Co. v. Eden Services, 823 F.2d 1215 (8th Cir. 1987), cert. de nied, 484 U.S. 1026 (1988) (Pet. 12), the court rejected a distributor's claim under Section 1 and Section 3 be cause the distributor was precluded merely from selling its own product in competition with the distributed prod uct, and there was "no evidence suggesting" that the exclusive dealing provisions prevented defendant's "competitors from finding effective distributors for (or other means of promoting and selling) their products." 823 F.2d at 1234; see id. at 1233-1235.

In Roland Machinery Co. v. Dresser Industries, Inc., 749 F.2d 380 (7th Cir. 1984) (Pet. 12), the court reversed a preliminary injunction under Section 3 be cause of plaintiff's failure to show "a substantial anticompetitive effect, actual or potential," and defen dant demonstrated a plausible procompetitive justifica tion for its action. 749 F.2d at 394; see id. at 395. See also Roy B. Taylor Sales, Inc. v. Hollymatic Corp., 28 F.3d 1379, 1385 (5th Cir. 1994), cert. denied, 513 U.S. 1103 (1995) (Pet. 15) (rejecting Section 1 tying claim by distributor because it complained only of lost profits, not reduced competition).

Those Section 1 and Section 3 rulings share only one relevant attribute with the court of appeals' decision in this Section 2 case: They all turned on fact-intensive inquiries respecting the characteristics of the relevant market and the defendant's conduct. They announce no categorical rule that would be inconsistent with the re sult reached below, and they provide no reason to doubt that the court of appeals properly applied settled Sec tion 2 monopoly maintenance principles to petitioner's conduct. Further review of this case is unwarranted.

5. CONCLUSION

The petition for a writ of certiorari should be denied.

Respectfully submitted.

PAUL D. CLEMENT
Solicitor General
THOMAS O. BARNETT
Acting Assistant Attorney
General
GERALD F. MASOUDI
Deputy Assistant Attorney
General
ROBERT B. NICHOLSON
ADAM D. HIRSH
Attorneys

DECEMBER 2005

1 "FF" and "CL" refer, respectively, to the district court's numbered findings of fact, Pet. App. 28a-134a, and conclusions of law, id. at 134a- 145a.

2 Dealer Criterion 6 provides that "[i]n order to effectively promote Dentsply/York products, dealers that are recognized as authorized distributors may not add further tooth lines to their product offering." Pet. App. 68a (FF 169).

3 See also Pet. App. 137a (CL 11) (direct distribution is a "viable and, in some ways, advantageous method of distribution"); id. at 141a (CL 26); id. at 143a (CL 35) ("direct distribution is viable"). The district court further concluded that "non-Dentsply dealers are available, and Dentsply dealers may be converted at any time." Id. at 143a (CL 35).

4 Petitioner's claim that the court of appeals erroneously changed the market definition and thereby improperly "double count[ed]" sales to dealers (Pet. 12-13 & n.5) cannot be reconciled with the court's clear statement that "the District Court understood, as do we, the relevant market to be the total sales of artificial teeth to the laboratories and the dealers combined." Pet. App. 9a (emphasis added). Far from "double counting," Pet. 13 n.5, the court of appeals ensured that every tooth sale was counted just once. See Pet. App. 2a-3a, 9a.

5 The court of appeals also properly rejected petitioner's argument (Pet. 16) that rivals could "steal" dealers away from petitioner. Such "purloining efforts have been thwarted by [petitioner's] longtime, vigorous and successful enforcement actions." Pet. App. 21a. Peti tioner "imposes an 'all-or-nothing' choice on the dealers. The fact that dealers have chosen not to drop [petitioner's] teeth in favor of a rival's brand demonstrates that they have acceded to heavy economic pres sure." Id. at 23a. See id. at 12a-13a, 21a-22a (describing pressure petitioner brought to bear on dealers).

6 See also Pet. App. 13a (dealer network used by petitioner was the "crucial point" in distribution); id. at 18a (direct distribution is not "practical or feasible in the market as it exists and functions"); id. at 21a ("[t]he paltry penetration in the market by competitors over the years has been a refutation of theory by tangible and measurable results in the real world"); id. at 15a ("[b]y ensuring that the key dealers offer [petitioner's] teeth either as the only or dominant choice, Dealer Criterion 6 has a significant effect in preserving [petitioner's] monopoly"); id. at 11a ("[i]t has not been so much the competitors' less than enthusiastic efforts at competition that produced paltry results, as it is the blocking of access to the key dealers"). Petitioner mistakenly characterizes the decision below as holding that petitioner's rivals posed no threat merely because of their small market shares. Pet. 8, 15, 17. Rather, the court of appeals held, correctly, that the direct distribution channel does not allow any rival in this market to "pose a real threat" to petitioner's monopoly. Pet. App. 19a. The court of appeals' acknowledgment that petitioner's rivals were able to "survive" by em ploying direct distribution, ibid., does not undermine the conclusion that petitioner violated Section 2 because even a monopolist faces competitive constraints. See, e.g., Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70-71.

7 Petitioner mistakenly relies on debatable characterizations of lower court decisions addressing Section 3 of the Clayton Act, rather than on decisions addressing monopoly maintenance. See Pet. 14-15. Petitioner also relies on Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 415-416 (2004) (Pet. 15), but that reliance is misplaced. Trinko involved the application of Section 2 to the conduct of a monopolist, but the alleged violation was the monopolist's refusal to share its own facilities with its rivals. By contrast, petitioner's violation centered on its preventing independent dealers from sharing their assets with petitioner's rivals.

8 The requirements contract committed the utility to buy less than 1% of the coal available in the relevant market. See Tampa Elec., 365 U.S. at 321, 333, 335. It was obvious that the contract could not create a monopoly in violation of Section 2, and the Court's decision, not surprisingly, contains no discussion of monopoly maintenance.


Brief
Updated October 21, 2014