Economics Of Loyalty Rebates: Where Are We Now?
Slide 1
Economics of Loyalty Rebates:
Where Are We Now?
NYU Compass |
|
University of Rochester |
FTC/DOJ Hearings November 29, 2006
Slide 2
Encompass a broad array of business practices that are deployed in a wide range of market settings by "dominant" and "non-dominant" firms including in markets in which exclusionary effects are not possible or even likely
- LRs must be analyzed in a market context in which they occur
- Exclusion does not suffice as proof of harm to competition (Willig (2006))
Slide 3
- bundled discounts --- two or more goods
- all-units discounts --- the buyer's price reduced on every unit purchased when purchases exceed the target quantity
- market-share discounts --- depend on the buyer's purchases of rivals' products (exclusive dealing is a limiting case)
Slide 4
- Substantial current interest among industrial organization economists and antitrust scholars in such business strategies
- Plethora of illustrative (often dubious) examples
- Some formal, game-theoretic modeling but little empirical work
- And plenty of disagreement on proper antitrust tests linked to "Type I versus Type II" arguments
Slide 5
- Practices can be good for consumers and be an intrinsic part of competition
- Practices can harm competition and consumers by seriously weakening ability of rivals to compete effectively
- Fact-intensive inquiry needed to distinguish the two in any given context (an open challenge for economists, antitrust authorities, judges, and juries)
Slide 6
- The essential feature of LRs is that the purchaser's payment (on the margin) depends on the overall level of activity of the buyer with the seller (and possibly with other sellers)
- These links can be across (i) volume, (ii) time, or (iii) products
- links may be engendered by some form of below-cost pricing
- locally negative marginal prices along the outlay schedule
- a bundled good with an implicit price below cost
- links may be engendered by some form of below-cost pricing
Slide 7
- Multi-product firm produces goods A and B at marginal costs $12 and $7, respectively.
- Price of A is $14, price of bundle is $20
- Although the bundle price is above cost for the multi-product firm, a B-only competitor would have to price at $6 or lower (below cost) if it is to sell to consumers who would otherwise buy the bundle
Slide 8
- One might conclude that bundled discount is exclusionary
- it "excludes" an equally-efficient competitor from selling to consumers who would buy both goods
- and thus ultimately harms consumers
- But one might also conclude that bundled discount increases consumer welfare — because it lowers the price of A and B to consumers
Slide 9
- This standard exampje offers little in the way of lessons for public policy
- One cannot say whether the discount on A and B is good or bad for consumers without analyzing how the stand-alone prices would change if such 'below-cost' bundled discounts were prohibited
- For example, if competition ensures that the price of B is $7 before and after the ban, and if the price of A would remain at $14, then consumers would be worse off. But if it would drop to $13, then consumers would be better off
Slide 10
- In fact, one can show in a fully-specified model that either scenario is possible
- The reason is that bundled discounts coupled with relatively high stand-alone prices act as a price-discrimination device. Without this ability to charge different prices to heterogeneous consumers, prices may be higher or lower
- Because all pertinent "market realities" (emphasized by Prof. Muris) are stripped away in the example, we are only left with a 'theoretically possibility" of benefit or harm from the practice
Slide 11
LRs can create market situations in which an efficient, rival seller would have to price below its cost of production to make sales to the buyer whereas the seller might still be earning overall positive profit because its discount/rebate is averaged out over a larger volume of sales
- This is not so under a typical volume discount schedule T(Q), with T(Q)/Q > T'(Q) > MC (Fig 1A)
- But there is such dissonance when the seller's outlay schedule "jumps down" if the buyer meets the minimum target (Fig 1B)
Slide 12
(Homogeneous Products)
Figure 1A shows a non-linear outlay schedule where buyer selects Q* units of output and pays T'(Q*) with the marginal price T'(Q*) = MCI,. A competitor with MCE MCI, can gain sales against the schedule In Figure 1B, marginal price "jumps" at Q* from p° to MCI,. An entrant with MCE MCI cannot gain any sales unless it can profitably offer at least (Q*-QI) units of sales
Slide 13
Slide 14
Slide 15
- Diagrams show that in the presence of LR, the rival may have to capture a non-trivial volume of sales in order to be profitable
- This is not an obstacle to effective competition if the rival can readily win the requisite volume of sales
- e.g., hospitals often convert "full house" its purchases of medical supplies from one vendor to another
- When the buyer's demand is readily contestable, the more likely it is that LR is designed to generate efficiency gains
Slide 16
- Even if the rival cannot profitably convert the necessary increment in the short-term, it is not necessarily impeded from competing
- E.g., if the rival can finance its first-period losses with profitable sales to the buyer in subsequent periods, ceteris paribus, the lower is the hurdle created by the LR
- In fact, ceteris paribus, the closer is the hypothetical exclusionary profit to the monopoly level, the easier it will be for the rival to gain sales against the LR, provided it can retain sales to the customer for a sufficiently long run and commit to a low price
Slide 17
Exclusionary LRs
- But LRs can lead to exclusion when, for example,
- rivals cannot profitably convert the necessary increment in the short-term
- rivals cannot finance first-period losses with profitable sales to the buyer in subsequent periods
- rivals cannot commit to low future prices over a sufficiently long run
- These conditions can arise in realistic market settings
Slide 18
Ordover and Shaffer (2006)
- Two sellers and one buyer and two periods
- In each period, the buyer wants at most 2 units of the good and prefers one each from each seller
- The 'incumbent' can supply both units per period. The 'entrant' can supply at most one unit per period
- In period two, the buyer becomes locked-in to the seller or the sellers from whom it purchased in period one
Slide 19
Ordover and Shaffer (2006)
- There are no restrictions on the feasible set of contracts that can be offered
- Key assumption is that the entrant faces a financing constraint (i.e., cap on how much it can borrow against its potential period-two lock-in gains in period one)
- and the entrant cannot commit to its second period price in period one
Slide 20
Ordover and Shaffer (2006)
- Then exclusion is possible even though it is efficient for the buyer to purchase one unit from each seller in each period (the sellers' goods are differentiated and the entrant is cost efficient)
- LRs arise in these equilibria even though the incumbent has no pro-competitive incentive for using them - a monopolist would rely on a simple discount (to induce the buyer to purchase two units)
Slide 21
What must be true in equilibrium
- In all exclusionary equilibria, TI**
- The incumbent's offer must match the entrant's best offer and also compensate the buyer for purchasing the "wrong" unit -- the buyer values the entrant's first unit by more than the incumbent's second unit
- Hence, the incumbent's marginal price for the second unit must be below cost if it is to exclude the entrant. And exclusion may potentially require a negative marginal price
Slide 22
Preliminary Conclusions
- In the model, exclusion does not arise (even when the entrant is financially constrained) if only 2PTs or other simple discounts (e.g., where the seller's marginal units are all priced at or above the seller's marginal cost) are allowed
- If (locally) negative marginal prices are allowed then exclusion is possible, if the entrant's financing constraint is binding
Slide 23
Efficient LRs
- LRs can also serve pro-efficiency objectives— e.g., they can induce non-contractible demand enhancing services
- For example, the seller can structure the rebate so that the buyer is unlikely to qualify unless the desired services have been performed
- This is modeled in Kolay, Shaffer and Ordover (2004) which illustrates a non-exclusionary use of LRs that can also conduce to higher overall economic welfare
Slide 24
Kolay, Shaffer, and Ordover (2004)
- One seller, one buyer
- Demand is not known at the time of contracting. Demand is either high or low
- Timing of the game:
Seller specifies the contract
Uncertainty is resolved
Buyer chooses how much to purchase - Typical self-selection results obtain
Slide 25
Standard Self-selection Results
- The buyer will earn zero surplus in the low demand state and positive surplus in the high demand state (because of information rent)
- The seller will distort downward the quantity chosen by a low-demand buyer, but not the quantity chosen by a high-demand buyer
- The information rent of a high-demand buyer depends on how much it could earn by choosing the contract meant for the low-demand buyer
Slide 26
Kolay, Shaffer, Ordover (2004)
- The seller earns higher profit with a menu of all-units discounts than with a menu of two-part tariffs. See Figures 2a and 2b
- All-units discounts imply negative marginal pricing on some units of the outlay schedule
- The effects of banning all-units discounts is ambiguous for consumer welfare
Slide 27
Kolay, Shaffer, Ordover (2004)
- The basic insight is that LRs permit more efficient price discrimination than simple 2-part tariffs because of the non-differentiability of the outlay schedule at the self-selection point chosen by the high-demand buyer
- Although price discrimination is not always welfare-enhancing, there are no public policy reasons to discourage the use of LRs for such purposes
- Leaving Chicago (yet again) The Chicago school presumption that as a matter of theory unilateral business arrangements between consensual buyers and sellers are likely to be efficiency-enhancing does not hold up
- Loyalty rebates can induce demand-enhancing services and facilitate better extraction of the monopoly rent that is potentially available to the seller
- But the same practices can also be used to protect this rent from dissipation or to enhance the size of the rent by lessening or removing the competitive constraint
- Two step approach (Willig (2006), Ordover and Willig (1999))
- Has the challenged rebate policy harmed competition (or is there a dangerous probability that it will)?
- If it has, is the practice nonetheless part of competition and thus "makes economic sense" or does it make sense only because of the adverse effects on present and future competition in the relevant markets?
- Prohibited conduct must be easily understood by market participants and readily avoidable
- Conduct tests must rely on information that is reasonably accessible, esp. to the defendant
- TI** is the incumbent's equilibrium contract,
- TI**(2) is the buyer's cost of purchasing 2 units
- TI**(1) is the buyer's cost of purchasing 1 unit,
- c is the marginal cost of production,
- VIE - VII is the difference in the value the buyer receives from consuming one unit from each seller rather than two units from the same seller,
- summarizes the severity of the entrant's financing constraint. It represents the amount the entrant can borrow and is weakly negative
- Kolay, S., Shaffer, G., and J.A. Ordover (2004), All Units Discounts in Retail Contracts, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 13: 429-459
- Ordover, J.A. and G. Shaffer (2006), Exclusionary Discounts, working paper, University of Rochester
- Ordover, J.A. and R.D. Willig (1999), Access and Bundling in High Technology Markets
- Willig, R.D., (Allegedly) Monopolizing Tying via Product Innovation, Presentation at the FTC/DOJ Hearings (November 2006)