Skip to main content

This is archived content from the U.S. Department of Justice website. The information here may be outdated and links may no longer function. Please contact webmaster@usdoj.gov if you have any questions about the archive site.

Economics Of Loyalty Rebates: Where Are We Now?

Slide 1

Economics of Loyalty Rebates:
Where Are We Now?

Janusz A Ordover
NYU Compass
and
Greg Shaffer
University of Rochester

FTC/DOJ Hearings November 29, 2006


Slide 2

 

Loyalty Rebates

Encompass a broad array of business practices that are deployed in a wide range of market settings by "dominant" and "non-dominant" firms including in markets in which exclusionary effects are not possible or even likely

  • LRs must be analyzed in a market context in which they occur
  • Exclusion does not suffice as proof of harm to competition (Willig (2006))

Slide 3

 

Examples of Business Practices
  • bundled discounts --- two or more goods
  • all-units discounts --- the buyer's price reduced on every unit purchased when purchases exceed the target quantity
  • market-share discounts --- depend on the buyer's purchases of rivals' products (exclusive dealing is a limiting case)

Slide 4

 

Where are We Now?
  • Substantial current interest among industrial organization economists and antitrust scholars in such business strategies
  • Plethora of illustrative (often dubious) examples
  • Some formal, game-theoretic modeling but little empirical work
  • And plenty of disagreement on proper antitrust tests linked to "Type I versus Type II" arguments

Slide 5

The Good, the Bad, the Ugly
  • Practices can be good for consumers and be an intrinsic part of competition
  • Practices can harm competition and consumers by seriously weakening ability of rivals to compete effectively
  • Fact-intensive inquiry needed to distinguish the two in any given context (an open challenge for economists, antitrust authorities, judges, and juries)

Slide 6

 

The Salient Features
  • The essential feature of LRs is that the purchaser's payment (on the margin) depends on the overall level of activity of the buyer with the seller (and possibly with other sellers)
  • These links can be across (i) volume, (ii) time, or (iii) products
    • links may be engendered by some form of below-cost pricing
      • locally negative marginal prices along the outlay schedule
      • a bundled good with an implicit price below cost

Slide 7

 

Easily Illustrated
  • Multi-product firm produces goods A and B at marginal costs $12 and $7, respectively.
  • Price of A is $14, price of bundle is $20
  • Although the bundle price is above cost for the multi-product firm, a B-only competitor would have to price at $6 or lower (below cost) if it is to sell to consumers who would otherwise buy the bundle

Slide 8

 

Easily Critiqued
  • One might conclude that bundled discount is exclusionary
    • it "excludes" an equally-efficient competitor from selling to consumers who would buy both goods
    • and thus ultimately harms consumers
  • But one might also conclude that bundled discount increases consumer welfare — because it lowers the price of A and B to consumers

Slide 9

 

Is There a Lesson?
  • This standard exampje offers little in the way of lessons for public policy
  • One cannot say whether the discount on A and B is good or bad for consumers without analyzing how the stand-alone prices would change if such 'below-cost' bundled discounts were prohibited
  • For example, if competition ensures that the price of B is $7 before and after the ban, and if the price of A would remain at $14, then consumers would be worse off. But if it would drop to $13, then consumers would be better off

Slide 10

On Further Review
  • In fact, one can show in a fully-specified model that either scenario is possible
  • The reason is that bundled discounts coupled with relatively high stand-alone prices act as a price-discrimination device. Without this ability to charge different prices to heterogeneous consumers, prices may be higher or lower
  • Because all pertinent "market realities" (emphasized by Prof. Muris) are stripped away in the example, we are only left with a 'theoretically possibility" of benefit or harm from the practice

Slide 11

Price Dissonance

LRs can create market situations in which an efficient, rival seller would have to price below its cost of production to make sales to the buyer whereas the seller might still be earning overall positive profit because its discount/rebate is averaged out over a larger volume of sales

  • This is not so under a typical volume discount schedule T(Q), with T(Q)/Q > T'(Q) > MC (Fig 1A)
  • But there is such dissonance when the seller's outlay schedule "jumps down" if the buyer meets the minimum target (Fig 1B)

Slide 12

Illustrative Diagrams
(Homogeneous Products)

Figure 1A shows a non-linear outlay schedule where buyer selects Q* units of output and pays T'(Q*) with the marginal price T'(Q*) = MCI,. A competitor with MCE MCI, can gain sales against the schedule In Figure 1B, marginal price "jumps" at Q* from p° to MCI,. An entrant with MCE MCI cannot gain any sales unless it can profitably offer at least (Q*-QI) units of sales


Slide 13

Figure 1A shows a non-linear outlay schedule where buyer selects Q* units of output and pays T(Q*) with the marginal price T'(Q*) = MC,. A competitor with MCE^MC, can gain sales against the schedule

Slide 14

In Figure 1B, marginal price

Slide 15

What is the Margin?
  • Diagrams show that in the presence of LR, the rival may have to capture a non-trivial volume of sales in order to be profitable
  • This is not an obstacle to effective competition if the rival can readily win the requisite volume of sales
    • e.g., hospitals often convert "full house" its purchases of medical supplies from one vendor to another
  • When the buyer's demand is readily contestable, the more likely it is that LR is designed to generate efficiency gains

Slide 16

Competitive Horizon
  • Even if the rival cannot profitably convert the necessary increment in the short-term, it is not necessarily impeded from competing
  • E.g., if the rival can finance its first-period losses with profitable sales to the buyer in subsequent periods, ceteris paribus, the lower is the hurdle created by the LR
  • In fact, ceteris paribus, the closer is the hypothetical exclusionary profit to the monopoly level, the easier it will be for the rival to gain sales against the LR, provided it can retain sales to the customer for a sufficiently long run and commit to a low price

Slide 17

Exclusionary LRs

  • But LRs can lead to exclusion when, for example,
    • rivals cannot profitably convert the necessary increment in the short-term
    • rivals cannot finance first-period losses with profitable sales to the buyer in subsequent periods
    • rivals cannot commit to low future prices over a sufficiently long run
  • These conditions can arise in realistic market settings

Slide 18

Ordover and Shaffer (2006)

  • Two sellers and one buyer and two periods
  • In each period, the buyer wants at most 2 units of the good and prefers one each from each seller
  • The 'incumbent' can supply both units per period. The 'entrant' can supply at most one unit per period
  • In period two, the buyer becomes locked-in to the seller or the sellers from whom it purchased in period one

Slide 19

Ordover and Shaffer (2006)

  • There are no restrictions on the feasible set of contracts that can be offered
  • Key assumption is that the entrant faces a financing constraint (i.e., cap on how much it can borrow against its potential period-two lock-in gains in period one)
  • and the entrant cannot commit to its second period price in period one

Slide 20

Ordover and Shaffer (2006)

  • Then exclusion is possible even though it is efficient for the buyer to purchase one unit from each seller in each period (the sellers' goods are differentiated and the entrant is cost efficient)
  • LRs arise in these equilibria even though the incumbent has no pro-competitive incentive for using them - a monopolist would rely on a simple discount (to induce the buyer to purchase two units)

Slide 21

What must be true in equilibrium

 

Updated January 3, 2024