Health Care Hearings: April Agenda
Hearings Information
Beginning in February 2003, the Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) cohosted hearings on health care and competition law and policy. For more information, consult the hearings information page.
Agenda
April 9, 2003
2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m |
Afternoon Session Hospitals are increasingly affiliating into horizontal networks and entering into vertical arrangements with other health care providers (physicians, nursing homes, home health agencies, and other entities). These arrangements, which occur against the backdrop of other laws and regulatory constraints, have paralleled several transformations in the nature of hospitals, from doctors’ workshops, to the center of integrated delivery networks, to complicated networked affiliates and contractual partners with other entities. Ronald Coase’s theory of the firm suggests that transactions can either be organized inter-firm (in other words, through the market) or intra-firm. The development of these arrangements is one example of the reconceptualization of the boundaries of a Coasean firm. Questions for consideration:
Robert Burns, Wharton School of Business |
April 10, 2003
9:15 a.m.- 12:30 p.m. |
Morning Session Nonprofit hospitals comprise approximately 60% of community hospitals in the United States. Nonprofit insurers comprise/administer a substantial proportion of total premium dollars spent on health care in the United States. Conversely, physicians, nursing homes, and many other health care providers are organized as for-profit operations. Questions for consideration:
William Lynk, Lexecon Inc. |
2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m. |
Afternoon Session Hospital joint ventures and joint operating agreements (JOAs) raise a number of distinct issues for competition law and policy. Because these arrangements fall short of full merger, such collaborations may, even when entered into between rivals, present fewer competitive concerns than a merger would. On the other hand, lack of complete integration may limit the prospect for substantial, pro-competitive efficiencies to be realized. Joint ventures are discussed in the 1996 Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care (Statements) jointly issued by the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice, but JOAs are not. Questions for consideration:
Jeff Miles, Ober Kaler |
April 11, 2003
9:15 a.m.- 12:15 p.m. |
Morning Session - Originally scheduled on February 28. In many geographic markets in the United States there has been a significant amount of market turbulence and varying degrees of consolidation among health care providers and insurers. Boston and Little Rock provide two points on the spectrum of market consolidation. To provide a frame of reference for the balance of the hearings, a day will be spent painting a comprehensive picture of current market conditions in Boston and Little Rock. The full range of competitive issues will be addressed, including the cost and quality of the care rendered, the degree of market concentration among providers and insurers, and the impact of market consolidation on the performance of the payor and provider markets. Jonathan R. Bates, M.D., Arkansas Children’s Hospital |
2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m. |
Afternoon Session Before a hospital merger is consummated, the parties routinely make representations about the pro-competitive benefits of the transaction. Questions for consideration:
William G. Kopit, Epstein Becker & Green |
April 23, 2003
9:15 a.m.– 12:15 p.m. |
Morning Session Framing Presentation: Paul B. Ginsburg, Center For Studying Health System Change Health care coverage is a highly differentiated product, and comes in many varieties, including health maintenance organizations (HMOs), preferred provider organizations (PPOs), point of service plans (POSs), and indemnity plans. Some insurance products are regulated by the state in which the coverage is issued, while other arrangements are subject to partial or exclusive federal regulation. Many firms and individuals self-insure, with the extent of self-insurance influenced by the cost of coverage. Questions for consideration:
Henry R. Desmarais, M.D., Health Insurance Association of America |
2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m. |
Afternoon Session This session will explore the range of potential competitive effects theories that might predict higher prices or diminished quality following a merger. Questions for consideration:
Helen Darling, Washington Business Group on Health |
April 24, 2003
9:15 a.m.- 12:15 p.m. |
Morning Session In most geographic markets in the United States, insurance plans frequently enter and exit. This session will examine entry, expansion, and product repositioning in this industry. Questions for consideration:
A second part of this session will be devoted to possible efficiencies arising out of insurance plan mergers. A variety of empirical research has indicated that economies of scope and scale are exhausted at relatively modest levels in the provision of insurance. When insurance plans merge, however, they often claim that significant efficiencies will stem from the merger. Questions for consideration:
Jay Angoff, Roger G. Brown and Associates |
2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m. |
Afternoon Session Conceptually, monopsony can be viewed as the flip side of monopoly—it is substantial market power being exercised by buyers over sellers. In the health insurance industry, health insurers are both sellers (of insurance to consumers) and buyers (of, for example, hospital and physician services). In this session we examine monopsony product market definition by asking how to apply the hypothetical monopolist paradigm to buyer side/monopsony concerns. We consider whether and how to reverse the standard seller-side formula that asks about the extent to which at-risk consumers can and will shift to other sellers in response to a post-merger small but significant and non-transitory increase in price (SSNIP). Questions for consideration:
Roger D. Blair, University of Florida, Gainesville |
April 25, 2003
9:15 a.m.- 12:15 p.m. and 2:00 p.m.- 5:00 p.m. |
Two Sessions Mergers between health insurers may raise a concern that monopsony power could be exercised against providers. Many providers accuse insurance companies of forcing them to accept unreasonably low rates and unattractive contract terms. When a merger increases the share of a physician’s patients covered by a given insurance plan, the cost to the physician of withdrawing from that plan in response to a lowering of rates increases. Questions for consideration:
Sharon Allen, Arkansas Blue Cross and Blue Shield |