Skip to main content

This is archived content from the U.S. Department of Justice website. The information here may be outdated and links may no longer function. Please contact webmaster@usdoj.gov if you have any questions about the archive site.

Market Power and Market Definition in Monopolization Cases: A Paradigm Is Missing

Slide 1

Market Power and Market Definition in Monopolization Cases: A Paradigm is Missing

Lawrence J. White
Stern School of Business
New York University
Lwhite@stern.nyu.edu

Presentation at the DOJ/FTC
Hearings on Single-Firm Conduct,
Washington, DC, March 7, 2007


Slide 2

Overview

  • The issue
  • The standard monopoly model
  • Implications of the model
  • Some loose language
  • The danger of the loose language
  • The Cellophane fallacy
  • The ongoing dilemma
  • What is to be done?
  • Conclusion

Slide 3

The issue

  • A seller can exercise market power
    • Sell at P > MC, and earn rents
  • A seller can create/enhance market power
    • Exclusionary/predatory behavior
  • If a seller is exercising/enhancing marketpower, a likely pre-condition is that theseller has a large share of its market
  • A threshold (safe harbor) issue: What is“the market”?
    • There is no standard paradigm for this determination

Slide 4

The standard monopoly model

Graph depicting the competitive and monopoly prices and quantities for the standard monopoly model[D]


Slide 5

Implications of the standard monopoly model

  • The monopolist maintains its price at a level above the competitive price
  • At the monopoly price, the monopolist would find it unprofitable to raise its price further (unless the demand curve and/or costs changed)
    • The monopolist would lose too many customers to other sellers of something
  • If a market changes from a competitive structure to a monopoly (because of cartelization or exclusion), the price increases

Slide 6

But some loose language (1)

  • By economists (who do know better)(emphasis added)
    • "It is the ability of a firm to raise prices or market inferior products while excluding competition that constitutes monopoly power." (Fisher et al.)
    • "... substantial evidence was presented at trial that [OEMs] would not shift to another operating system, even if the price of Windows rose significantly." (Fisher & Rubinfeld)
    • "Economists usually define market power as the power to raise price above competitive levels." (Evans & Schmalensee)

Slide 7

More loose language

  • By judges (who ought to know better?) (emphasis added)
    • "Market power is usually stated to be the ability of a single seller to raise price and restrict output..." Fortner Enterprises, Inc. v. United States Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969)
    • "Market power comes from the ability to cut back the market's total output and so raise price." Ball Memorial Hospital, Inc. v. Mutual Hospital Insurance, Inc., 784 F.2d 1325, 1335 (1986)
    • "More precisely, a firm is a monopolist if it can profitably raise prices substantially above the competitive level." U.S. v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 22 (2001)

Slide 8

The danger of the loose language

  • Suppose that the “test” of the presence ofmarket power is whether the candidate sellerhas the ability profitably to raise prices above currently observed levels; conversely, is the seller constrained from raising prices becauseof its fears of losing too many customers to other sellers (of something)?
  • All sellers should be found to be so constrained
    • All sellers will be deemed to be part of a “large” market in which they have only a minor market share

Slide 9

The Cellophane fallacy (1)

  • U.S. v. du Pont, 351 U.S. 377 (1956)
  • Was the market narrow: “cellophane”?
    • If so, Du Pont had market power
  • Was the market broad: “flexible wrapping materials”?
    • If so, Du Pont had only a 17.9% share of that market and didn’t have market power

Slide 10

The Cellophane fallacy (2)

  • The Supreme Court majority:
    • "cellophane's interchangeability with the other materials mentioned suffices to make it a part of this flexible packaging material market"
  • The Supreme Court minority (and Stocking &Mueller (1955))
    • Du Pont's profits in cellophane were much higher than in rayon, where it faced 15-18 other producers of the same item and had about the same market share (less than 20%) as in cellophane
    • Du Pont’s price of cellophane didn’t vary when the prices of other packaging materials changed

Slide 11

The ongoing dilemma

  • Profit data are often unreliable
  • The relevant market definition paradigm of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines (HMG) is a forward-looking price increase test (SSNIP) and thus is generally not useful for complaints involving the existence of market power
    • Exception: If a complaint is about a prospective exclusionary practice, then the SSNIP test can be used
  • Estimates of the elasticity of demand for the seller’s product are unlikely to be helpful
    • A true monopolist and a Chamberlin/Robinson “monopolistic competitor” could have similar elasticities

Slide 12

What is to be done? (1)

  • Sometimes a complaint will involve a prospective practice
  • Sometimes there are cross-section and/or time series data on seller concentration and price that can help delineate markets
    • Local markets: retail services; transportation services; low value-to-weight commodities
  • Sometimes profit data can be useful – Microsoft…?
  • But what if none of these possibilities are available?

Slide 13

What is to be done? (2)

  • Nelson & White (2003) proposal (similar to but expanding beyond Krattenmaker et al. (1987) and Werden (2000)): If a plaintiff alleges exclusion, would the (counter-factual) absence of exclusion have led to a “small but significant decrease in price” (SSNDP)?
    • What would the plaintiff’s sales have been in the absence of the exclusion?
    • What would have been the consequences of those sales for the defendant’s prices?
  • This focuses directly on effect and implicitly delineates a market
    • Similar in this respect to the “unilateral effects” analysis under the HMG

Slide 14

What is to be done? (3)

  • Develop a market definition paradigm for monopolization cases that is comparable in analytic power to the HMG market definition paradigm
    • Remember what pre-1982 market definition analysis for mergers was like?

Slide 15

Conclusion

  • Market definition for monopolization cases remains in an unsatisfactory state
    • Comparable to the pre-1982 state of market definition for merger cases
  • There are some potential/partial remedies; but
  • The best remedy would be a new paradigm

 

Updated January 3, 2024