1
1 |
UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
|
2 |
and
|
3 |
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
|
4 |
|
5 |
|
6 |
|
7 |
SHERMAN ACT SECTION 2 JOINT HEARING
|
8 |
WELCOME AND OVERVIEW OF HEARINGS
|
9 |
TUESDAY, JUNE 20, 2006
|
10 |
|
11 |
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
HELD AT:
|
15 |
600 PENNSYLVANIA AVENUE, N.W.
|
16 |
WASHINGTON, D.C.
|
17 |
UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
|
18 |
HEADQUARTERS BUILDING, ROOM 432
|
19 |
2:00 P.M. to 4:00 P.M.
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
Reported and transcribed by:
|
25 |
Susanne Bergling, RMR-CLR |
2
1 |
MODERATOR:
|
2 |
WILLIAM BLUMENTHAL
|
3 |
Federal Trade Commission
|
4 |
|
5 |
PANELISTS:
|
6 |
|
7 |
Deborah Platt Majoras
|
8 |
Thomas O. Barnett
|
9 |
Dennis Carlton
|
10 |
Herbert Hovenkamp
|
11 |
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
|
16 |
|
17 |
|
18 |
|
19 |
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
|
3
4
1 |
P R O C E E D I N G S
|
2 |
- - - - -
|
3 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Ladies and gentlemen, good
|
4 |
afternoon. I'm Bill Blumenthal from the FTC, and I'd
|
5 |
like to welcome you to the first of the joint Justice
|
6 |
Department Antitrust Division and Federal Trade
|
7 |
Commission hearings into Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
|
8 |
The purpose of these hearings is to explore how
|
9 |
best to identify anticompetitive exclusionary conduct
|
10 |
for purposes of antitrust enforcement. We are
|
11 |
envisioning a series of hearings that will kick off
|
12 |
today and will continue through December, probably two,
|
13 |
three, four hearings a month, with the exception of
|
14 |
August. After today's kick-off hearing, we are going to
|
15 |
have another hearing on Thursday of this week examining
|
16 |
predatory pricing, we will have a hearing in mid-July
|
17 |
examining refusals to deal, take a little bit of a
|
18 |
breather, and then resume in September with what would
|
19 |
then be a series of examinations.
|
20 |
The agencies are expecting to focus on legal
|
21 |
doctrine, on jurisprudence, economic research, and
|
22 |
business and consumer experience. We have a Federal
|
23 |
Register notice that is outstanding. We invite public
|
24 |
comment on a wide range of topics, and we hope that
|
25 |
those of you who are here, as well as many others, will |
5
1 |
have an opportunity to submit comments on the topics
|
2 |
that we address. We are open to receiving those any
|
3 |
time through the final hearing, that is, through
|
4 |
December, although the earlier the better for our
|
5 |
purposes.
|
6 |
We are honored today to have a special panel to
|
7 |
kick off the hearings. They probably do not need much
|
8 |
introduction, so I am going to be very brief in offering
|
9 |
the introductions. In the order in which they will be
|
10 |
speaking, first we have Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman
|
11 |
of the Federal Trade Commission. Thomas Barnett, the
|
12 |
Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust in the Justice
|
13 |
Department. Herb Hovenkamp, who is probably known to
|
14 |
most of you as -- as many things -- a professor of law
|
15 |
at the University of Iowa, but probably better known as
|
16 |
a co-author and a reviser of the leading treatise in the
|
17 |
antitrust field as well as a prolific author of many,
|
18 |
many other volumes, the most recent of which is recently
|
19 |
out, The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution,
|
20 |
available through Harvard University Press, with an
|
21 |
imprint of this year.
|
22 |
And finally Dennis Carlton, also known to many
|
23 |
of you in many capacities, most notably professor of
|
24 |
economics at the Graduate School of Business at the
|
25 |
University of Chicago, former president and still very |
6
1 |
active in Lexicon, frequent expert witness, author of
|
2 |
many, many articles, author of I guess two of the
|
3 |
leading economics texts in the field. I'll leave it at
|
4 |
that. You all know Dennis Carlton.
|
5 |
I have several preliminary announcements that I
|
6 |
am going to make, one of which is legally mandated. The
|
7 |
first, which is not legally mandated but is a common
|
8 |
courtesy, if any of you have cell phones or
|
9 |
Blackberries, pagers, iPods, things of that nature,
|
10 |
please do as I'm doing right now and set it into silent
|
11 |
or manner mode, although if you do it like I just did,
|
12 |
you just dialed 7. Okay, there we go.
|
13 |
Second, I have been asked to let you know that
|
14 |
the men's room is immediately out these doors and to the
|
15 |
left. The ladies' room is out these doors, to the other
|
16 |
side of the elevator banks, and to the left.
|
17 |
And finally, the legally mandated announcement
|
18 |
is the one that says, as a safety tip for our visitors,
|
19 |
if the building alarms go off, please proceed calmly and
|
20 |
quickly as instructed. If we must leave the building,
|
21 |
take the stairway, which is to the right on the
|
22 |
Pennsylvania Avenue side, and after leaving the
|
23 |
building, please follow the stream of FTC people who are
|
24 |
practiced in this evolution. We will all go to the
|
25 |
Sculpture Garden, catty-cornered across the street at |
7
1 |
7th and Constitution, and we will assemble there, where
|
2 |
noses will be counted.
|
3 |
With that, it gives me great pleasure to turn
|
4 |
the podium over to the Chairman of the Federal Trade
|
5 |
Commission, Debbie Majoras.
|
6 |
(Applause.)
|
7 |
CHAIRMAN MAJORAS: Good afternoon, everyone, and
|
8 |
thank you very much, Bill. Together with my good friend
|
9 |
and colleague, Assistant Attorney General Tom Barnett,
|
10 |
it is my great pleasure to welcome you to these hearings
|
11 |
in which we will be exploring conduct under Section 2,
|
12 |
and we are privileged to have two of our most
|
13 |
distinguished antitrust scholars here, Professors
|
14 |
Hovenkamp and Carlton.
|
15 |
Now, at the start of any new endeavor, it is
|
16 |
important to reflect on why we are undertaking it.
|
17 |
Beginning in 1990, the McKinsey Global Institute, led by
|
18 |
founding director William W. Louis, undertook a 12-year
|
19 |
study of the economic performance of 13 nations seeking
|
20 |
to understand globalization, and more fundamentally, the
|
21 |
disparities between rich and poor. The study showed
|
22 |
that levels of productivity made the difference between
|
23 |
rich and poor nations. What, though, made the
|
24 |
difference in the levels of productivity? The answer
|
25 |
they found was "undistorted competition in product |
8
1 |
markets."
|
2 |
In his book in which he reports the results of
|
3 |
the study, Mr. Lewis says, "Most economic analysis ends
|
4 |
up attributing most of the differences in economic
|
5 |
performance to differences in labor and capital markets.
|
6 |
This conclusion is incorrect. Differences in
|
7 |
competition in product markets are much more important."
|
8 |
McKinsey also asked why the highly productive
|
9 |
United States has higher competitive intensity than
|
10 |
other nations. Mr. Lewis sums up the answer by saying
|
11 |
that, in the United States, "Consumer is king." More
|
12 |
specifically, he says, "[t]he United States adopted the
|
13 |
view that the purpose of an economy was to serve
|
14 |
consumers much earlier than any other society," and we
|
15 |
continue to "hold this view more strongly than almost
|
16 |
any other place." And he concludes that, in fact,
|
17 |
"Consumers are the only political force that can stand
|
18 |
up to producer interest, big government, and the
|
19 |
technocratic, political, business, and intellectual."
|
20 |
This is why we are here. The FTC and the
|
21 |
Antitrust Division have the responsibility to ensure
|
22 |
that competition in U.S. markets is free of distortion
|
23 |
and that consumers are protected not from markets but
|
24 |
through markets unburdened by anticompetitive conduct
|
25 |
and government-imposed restrictions. This work is |
9
1 |
critical, indeed, to the well-being of the American
|
2 |
people. Over the past few decades, the United States
|
3 |
has substantially deregulated critical industries,
|
4 |
including transportation, telecommunication and energy,
|
5 |
to the substantial benefit of the economy and consumers.
|
6 |
As government regulators have given way to free markets,
|
7 |
much of the responsibility for protecting consumers
|
8 |
shifts to competition agencies and courts. While
|
9 |
competition is distorted when governments regulate or
|
10 |
intervene excessively, it also is true that private
|
11 |
actors can and do distort competition.
|
12 |
Breaking up cartels, preventing mergers that
|
13 |
will substantially reduce competition, and halting
|
14 |
conduct that goes beyond aggressive competition to
|
15 |
distorting it is vital to promoting vigorous competition
|
16 |
and maximizing consumer welfare, and we have developed a
|
17 |
great deal of consensus regarding appropriate antitrust
|
18 |
policy, I think, as it relates to cartels and to mergers
|
19 |
and other horizontal conduct, as a result of which our
|
20 |
enforcement has become more transparent and predictable,
|
21 |
which then, in turn, makes it easier for market
|
22 |
participants to make decisions about their own conduct.
|
23 |
Unilateral or "single-firm" conduct, however,
|
24 |
still vexes us. Even though we can find some
|
25 |
respectable measure of consensus around principles that |
10
1 |
should apply, we find a range of opinions from
|
2 |
knowledgeable people about how to apply those principles
|
3 |
to enforcement in the market, and the question of the
|
4 |
proper test that our agencies should apply and that
|
5 |
courts should apply to conduct of the single firm with
|
6 |
market power now has dominated our antitrust debate for
|
7 |
several years.
|
8 |
We are not alone. Across the globe, over the
|
9 |
past quarter century, economic systems in which the
|
10 |
state owns the firms and central planners set out prices
|
11 |
and levels of output have given way to competition where
|
12 |
the forces of supply and demand determine prices and
|
13 |
allocate the resources, and we have worked hard to
|
14 |
promote the economic and political benefits of markets.
|
15 |
With attempts to introduce market economies have come
|
16 |
new competition authorities, today numbering around 100,
|
17 |
when only 15 years ago, we had just 20. And even
|
18 |
countries that for decades have had nearly total state
|
19 |
control over their economies, like China, are now
|
20 |
dedicating substantial resources to drafting competition
|
21 |
laws.
|
22 |
Currently, the issue of how to evaluate
|
23 |
unilateral conduct is the most heavily discussed and
|
24 |
debated area of competition policy in the international
|
25 |
arena. Just to give you a few examples, last week, FTC |
11
1 |
and DOJ officials attended the EC's hearing to review
|
2 |
their policy under Article 82, which addresses conduct
|
3 |
by dominant firms. Officials from both agencies
|
4 |
recently held talks with our colleagues in Japan and
|
5 |
Mexico and Canada on the issue. We recently had panels
|
6 |
on it in the OECD. And since the International
|
7 |
Competition Network established a working group on
|
8 |
unilateral conduct in May, the FTC, which will co-chair
|
9 |
that group, has received expressions of interest from
|
10 |
more countries wanting to be involved than we have ever
|
11 |
had in any other working group in the ICN.
|
12 |
So, why the strong interest? Well, first, many
|
13 |
nations are facing the challenge of converting from
|
14 |
state-owned or supported monopolists to markets with
|
15 |
more than one participant, which is no small challenge,
|
16 |
as we ourselves have learned in trying to deregulate
|
17 |
certain markets like electricity. And, indeed, to
|
18 |
enforcers in those nations, it then becomes companies
|
19 |
with market power, not horizontal competitors, that are
|
20 |
the evil that must be attacked. Second, disagreement
|
21 |
among competition authorities about how to treat
|
22 |
unilateral conduct produces uncertainty in national and
|
23 |
international markets, which reduces the market
|
24 |
efficiency and imposes costs. And third, the analysis
|
25 |
of unilateral conduct in the identification of that |
12
1 |
which is anticompetitive presents unique challenges that
|
2 |
are not present or at least are less present in the core
|
3 |
antitrust concern of conduct between competitors, and by
|
4 |
now, these unique challenges I think are familiar.
|
5 |
First and fundamentally -- and we discuss it all
|
6 |
the time, but that doesn't make it less difficult -- and
|
7 |
that is it is difficult to distinguish between
|
8 |
aggressive procompetitive unilateral conduct and
|
9 |
anticompetitive unilateral conduct. As the D.C. Circuit
|
10 |
said in the Microsoft case, "The challenge for an
|
11 |
antitrust court lies in stating a general rule for
|
12 |
distinguishing between exclusionary acts which reduce
|
13 |
social welfare and competitive acts which increase it,"
|
14 |
and this is tough, because as Judge Diane Wood wrote for
|
15 |
the Seventh Circuit, "distinguishing between legitimate
|
16 |
and unlawful unilateral conduct requires subtle economic
|
17 |
judgments about particular business practices." So,
|
18 |
while it's difficult, it must be done and it must be
|
19 |
done well.
|
20 |
Second, the process of distinguishing between
|
21 |
permissible and impermissible conduct must be relatively
|
22 |
consistent and transparent so that firms are able to
|
23 |
incorporate it into their decision-making. While there
|
24 |
are relatively few findings of Section 2 liability,
|
25 |
there nonetheless are a large number of different types |
13
1 |
of conduct that may raise competition concerns and would
|
2 |
fall under Section 2.
|
3 |
And third, while antitrust practitioners have
|
4 |
had substantial success devising remedies for joint
|
5 |
conduct, devising remedies for single-firm behavior
|
6 |
presents significant difficulties. As Professors Areeda
|
7 |
and Hovenkamp put it, "By contrast with concerted
|
8 |
conduct, unilateral behavior is difficult to evaluate or
|
9 |
remedy by any means short of governmental management of
|
10 |
the enterprise."
|
11 |
We have much to work with as we move forward
|
12 |
with these hearings. Already a number of experienced
|
13 |
experts have proposed the adoption of a single test for
|
14 |
evaluating nearly all types of potentially exclusionary
|
15 |
conduct. Some have argued for a test that focuses on
|
16 |
the impact of the conduct on consumer welfare. Others
|
17 |
support analyzing whether the conduct involves the
|
18 |
short-term sacrifice of profits. Others support a
|
19 |
no-economic-sense test, which asks whether the cost of
|
20 |
engaging in the exclusionary conduct makes sense only
|
21 |
because it serves to eliminate competition.
|
22 |
Judge Posner has written that the inquiry should
|
23 |
focus on whether the conduct excludes other equally
|
24 |
efficient rivals, and still other practitioners and
|
25 |
scholars oppose the adoption of any single unilateral |
14
1 |
conduct test and instead favor consideration of
|
2 |
different tests for particular types of exclusionary
|
3 |
conduct. And then, of course, when you go out into the
|
4 |
world, you see that there are many other opinions on the
|
5 |
type of test or framework that should be used.
|
6 |
So, proponents of the various tests and
|
7 |
approaches already have done a very good job of laying
|
8 |
out, I think, the relative merits, and virtually all
|
9 |
have acknowledged that their preferred approach is
|
10 |
probably not perfect. At these hearings, I hope we can
|
11 |
tackle this issue by starting with the conduct itself.
|
12 |
The hearings will have panels that will focus on
|
13 |
specific types of conduct that at least to date we know
|
14 |
can implicate liability. We want the panels to discuss
|
15 |
the conduct from the market perspective, from the ground
|
16 |
up; that is, to examine why and when firms engage in
|
17 |
certain practices, how they do it, what effects it
|
18 |
produces for the firm, for other firms, both customers
|
19 |
and the competition, and for consumers. And we should
|
20 |
look at whether firms in competitive markets also engage
|
21 |
in the same conduct, and if so, examine why that is. We
|
22 |
want these discussions, to the extent possible, to
|
23 |
include knowledgeable businesspeople or at least their
|
24 |
advisers, and from these discussions, we then should
|
25 |
endeavor to develop sign posts for when the conduct may |
15
1 |
harm competition and when it typically does not. From
|
2 |
the sign posts, we hopefully can draw some guiding
|
3 |
principles, and only then should we turn to examining
|
4 |
the current state of the law as it has been applied to
|
5 |
such conduct and then determining what workable rules
|
6 |
can be applied to the specific conduct at issue. That
|
7 |
way, we can then see, can we pull these together into a
|
8 |
single test or a broader set of rules? And even if we
|
9 |
don't produce a consensus on the universal test or
|
10 |
tests, I'm optimistic that we can identify relative
|
11 |
consensus on a number of principles and then on how to
|
12 |
approach at least some fraction, hopefully a significant
|
13 |
fraction, of single-firm conduct we encounter.
|
14 |
In these discussions, we need to be careful not
|
15 |
to permit labels or semantic differences to get in the
|
16 |
way. In some discussions I've heard on these issues, I
|
17 |
have been worried that people are actually talking past
|
18 |
one another. In addition, this debate must not become
|
19 |
so academic that even if it could be resolved, it might
|
20 |
not have much practical application in the marketplace.
|
21 |
Indeed, last week I was speaking with a long-time
|
22 |
antitrust practitioner about these hearings and about
|
23 |
the debate over a proper test, and he said, that while
|
24 |
he thought the Section 2 issues were very important,
|
25 |
nonetheless, the search for the "holy grail" test might |
16
1 |
just be something in which only about 27 people have an
|
2 |
interest. So, we really want to be careful about that.
|
3 |
I do think we start with some substantial
|
4 |
consensus about core underlying principles and factors
|
5 |
that should underlie any evaluation of unilateral
|
6 |
conduct.
|
7 |
First, the only type of unilateral conduct that
|
8 |
should implicate the antitrust laws is conduct that
|
9 |
produces durable harm to competition, leading to higher
|
10 |
prices, reduced output, lower quality or lower rates of
|
11 |
innovation. As much as we may value the success of
|
12 |
particular companies, the health of the companies
|
13 |
themselves is not the concern of antitrust law.
|
14 |
Second, there is consensus that antitrust
|
15 |
standards that govern unilateral conduct must not in
|
16 |
themselves deter competition, efficiency, or innovation,
|
17 |
and this is what we mean when we constantly say that we
|
18 |
worry about false positives. Obviously pervasive and
|
19 |
aggressive competition in which firms consistently try
|
20 |
to better each other by providing higher quality goods
|
21 |
and services at lower cost is crucial to maximizing
|
22 |
consumer welfare. So, the antitrust laws should then
|
23 |
never condemn market power that is obtained through the
|
24 |
development of superior products and services,
|
25 |
regardless of how many competitors are driven from the |
17
1 |
marketplace in the process, and that, of course, has
|
2 |
been accepted by the courts.
|
3 |
Third, there is consensus that the standards for
|
4 |
evaluating unilateral conduct must be clear and
|
5 |
practical to administer or as practical as they can be
|
6 |
to administer. The most analytically sound principles
|
7 |
will provide little value to us if firms can't interpret
|
8 |
them when they are making their business decisions.
|
9 |
And, of course, courts have to be able to interpret and
|
10 |
apply rules as well.
|
11 |
And while I want to emphasize that I am going to
|
12 |
use the hearings to continue developing my own thinking
|
13 |
on these issues, I do approach them, in addition to the
|
14 |
broad principles, with a number of other hypotheses.
|
15 |
First, any legal framework needs to avoid
|
16 |
second-guessing business judgments that were objectively
|
17 |
reasonable at the time they were made. An ex post facto
|
18 |
examination of the hypothetical effects of alternative
|
19 |
courses of conduct is likely to chill legitimate
|
20 |
business behavior. Second, to be practical, any legal
|
21 |
framework must be able to evaluate conduct that both
|
22 |
generates efficiencies and produces anticompetitive
|
23 |
exclusion. If we only had to worry about conduct for
|
24 |
which the effects are obvious, we probably would not be
|
25 |
here today. And third, any test or tests must account |
18
1 |
for the fact that certain types of unilateral conduct
|
2 |
are significantly more likely to cause competitive harm
|
3 |
than others. For example, most would agree that
|
4 |
unilateral above-cost pricing at monopoly levels should
|
5 |
not be condemned under the antitrust laws. Similarly,
|
6 |
behavior that some commentators have termed "cheap
|
7 |
exclusion," such as the use of government processes to
|
8 |
unlawfully extend the life of a patent, is generally
|
9 |
viewed as unlawful exclusionary conduct. And this may
|
10 |
mean that there is no unitary test or that we simply
|
11 |
need a broad framework that can accommodate a spectrum
|
12 |
or perhaps a sliding scale for the levels of harm, and
|
13 |
proposals have been made for how we might think about
|
14 |
the distinctions that could be made, including Deputy
|
15 |
Bureau of Competition Director Ken Glazer's proposal
|
16 |
that we analyze conduct by distinguishing between
|
17 |
conduct that's coercive versus incentivising.
|
18 |
Now, in the Microsoft case, the D.C. Circuit
|
19 |
applied what I view as a sensible weighted balance
|
20 |
approach to Microsoft's conduct that's largely
|
21 |
consistent with the three principles I just discussed.
|
22 |
Some have criticized the framework used in Microsoft as
|
23 |
insufficiently structured or unfocused, and I understand
|
24 |
where that comes from, but I think if we look at how it
|
25 |
was actually applied, it may be a workable framework |
19
1 |
that incorporates the principles on which we have wide
|
2 |
consensus. I mean, perhaps the same criticism about
|
3 |
being unstructured could be applied to the Section 1
|
4 |
rule of reason and, in fact, probably is at times, but
|
5 |
as applied to, for example, joint ventures, the
|
6 |
balancing has been weighted I think in the right
|
7 |
direction.
|
8 |
First, the Microsoft court did not attempt to
|
9 |
substitute ex post facto its judgment for the business
|
10 |
judgments that were made ex ante, or to determine what
|
11 |
actions might have been better overall for consumers.
|
12 |
For example, the Court did not base its findings on an
|
13 |
ex post analysis of the impact of Microsoft's conduct on
|
14 |
the prices charged to consumers.
|
15 |
The Microsoft court also demonstrated that to
|
16 |
evaluate whether certain types of unilateral conduct
|
17 |
violate the antitrust laws does require an examination
|
18 |
of both likely anticompetitive and procompetitive
|
19 |
effects. For example, the Court analyzed the legality
|
20 |
of a Microsoft license provision that prohibited OEMs
|
21 |
from modifying the initial boot sequence. Microsoft did
|
22 |
not dispute that that restriction limited competition
|
23 |
against IE. The Court nonetheless held that the
|
24 |
restriction was not a violation because it concluded
|
25 |
that preventing the Windows desktop from ever being seen |
20
1 |
at all in the boot sequence was a substantial alteration
|
2 |
of Microsoft's copyrighted work that could produce harm
|
3 |
that outweighs the marginal anticompetitive effect of
|
4 |
the prohibition. The Court performed this same analysis
|
5 |
across two dozen types of conduct, examining both the
|
6 |
anticompetitive effects and procompetitive
|
7 |
justifications, taking care, though, to ensure that it
|
8 |
not chill procompetitive behavior.
|
9 |
And finally, the D.C. Circuit made clear that it
|
10 |
did not consider all types of unilateral conduct to
|
11 |
raise equal concerns under the antitrust laws. For
|
12 |
example, the Court stated that courts need to be very
|
13 |
skeptical about claims that a dominant firm's design
|
14 |
changes harm competition and, by implication, violate
|
15 |
the antitrust laws.
|
16 |
One final note about the hearings. I hope that
|
17 |
our latest panels, which we will hold on remedies, will
|
18 |
produce a productive discussion. It simply is not
|
19 |
possible to implement sound competition policy for
|
20 |
single-firm conduct without giving careful thought to
|
21 |
remedies. Despite their importance, though, I think the
|
22 |
issues relating to remedies have not received extensive
|
23 |
attention. Take the Microsoft case, for example, which
|
24 |
although it received and still receives a bit of
|
25 |
notoriety, I have been stricken by how few productive |
21
1 |
discussions of the remedy and the D.C. Circuit decision
|
2 |
that accepted the DOJ remedy while rejecting other
|
3 |
remedies have actually occurred, and while that might
|
4 |
have stemmed from some of the market dissatisfaction
|
5 |
over that remedy, I think these hearings should give the
|
6 |
Section 2 remedy issue the prominence that it deserves
|
7 |
in our analysis. After all, if you have done these
|
8 |
cases, you know that devising and drafting remedial
|
9 |
provisions in monopolization cases can be more difficult
|
10 |
than determining whether a violation has even occurred.
|
11 |
At bottom, through these hearings and through
|
12 |
our work, we need to remember that antitrust is the
|
13 |
means, not the end. Rather, the end is undistorted
|
14 |
competition driven by "king" -- and I would say "and
|
15 |
queen" -- consumer, and the challenge is to keep
|
16 |
competition undistorted while not distorting it
|
17 |
ourselves in the process.
|
18 |
So, I thank you again for attending the opening
|
19 |
of these hearings, and we look forward to all of your
|
20 |
contributions. Thank you very much.
|
21 |
(Applause.)
|
22 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Thank you, Chairman.
|
23 |
General Barnett?
|
24 |
MR. BARNETT: I am going to attempt to be
|
25 |
somewhat high-tech here. We will see if it works. Ah. |
22
1 |
I want to thank, first off, the FTC for hosting
|
2 |
the first of these hearings on Section 2 and for their
|
3 |
help in organizing and planning and discussing the
|
4 |
issues that have brought us together. Both Chairman
|
5 |
Majoras, as well as the other FTC Commissioners and the
|
6 |
FTC staff, have all been extraordinarily helpful, and I
|
7 |
want to thank all of you as well as the Antitrust
|
8 |
Division staff who have worked very hard to prepare for
|
9 |
the session today and who will continue to work hard
|
10 |
over the months ahead.
|
11 |
I also want to thank Herb and Dennis for
|
12 |
agreeing to be with us. I feel very honored to have
|
13 |
such distinguished commentators, and feel that it is a
|
14 |
terrific start to these important hearings.
|
15 |
I am going to start with the same issue that
|
16 |
Debbie started with, which is why are we sponsoring
|
17 |
these hearings? And I can tell you up front, much of
|
18 |
what you are going to hear will echo some of what Debbie
|
19 |
said, but it was done unilaterally and without
|
20 |
consultation, and so I hope you will judge it at least
|
21 |
under the Section 2 standard, not under Section 1.
|
22 |
We do feel that it is important. As Debbie
|
23 |
said, unilateral conduct can harm consumer welfare. I
|
24 |
think there is a consensus that the focus of the
|
25 |
antitrust laws in the United States is to preserve and |
23
1 |
promote or prevent harm to consumer welfare and that
|
2 |
unilateral conduct is an important element of that.
|
3 |
I also agree that this is the area of probably
|
4 |
the least consensus. I think there are large areas of
|
5 |
consensus within Section 2, but there are significant
|
6 |
areas where I think we have room for further
|
7 |
understanding.
|
8 |
These hearings, with the combination of legal,
|
9 |
economic, business and governmental/private
|
10 |
perspectives, provide us with a unique opportunity to
|
11 |
advance our understanding, and I believe that that will
|
12 |
help us to advance the development of the law. It can
|
13 |
provide helpful guidance to the courts, guidance to the
|
14 |
business community, and as Debbie quite eloquently put
|
15 |
it, to the international community that is now focused
|
16 |
on this issue.
|
17 |
There is a long tradition of the agencies
|
18 |
leading the development of competition law. I need only
|
19 |
point to Don Turner and the 1968 Merger Guidelines and
|
20 |
the formulation by Bill Baxter in 1982 to provide an
|
21 |
example of what has become the standard reference for
|
22 |
analyzing mergers, not only in U.S. courts, but really
|
23 |
around the world in many ways.
|
24 |
With respect to the international community,
|
25 |
again, I do want to both echo and underscore what Debbie |
24
1 |
said. This is an issue that is at the forefront of
|
2 |
people's minds as we talk to officials on every
|
3 |
continent, and one example that sort of helped drive
|
4 |
this point home a bit, I was at a conference a while ago
|
5 |
in Budapest of Southeastern European former Soviet block
|
6 |
countries, and we were talking about a topic that the
|
7 |
Antitrust Division often talks about, which is the
|
8 |
importance of cartel enforcement, and one of the
|
9 |
officials approached me at a break and said, "I agree
|
10 |
with you, cartels are a terrible thing. I just wish
|
11 |
that our markets had enough participants so that they
|
12 |
could collude together. They don't have anyone to
|
13 |
collude with. So, we are focused on this dominant
|
14 |
former state-owned enterprise and how we can introduce
|
15 |
competition into this economy." It just drove home for
|
16 |
me, at least, the importance of this issue. It is
|
17 |
important here, but I think its importance abroad cannot
|
18 |
be over-emphasized.
|
19 |
The Supreme Court, to its credit, addressed the
|
20 |
issue of monopoly 96 years ago. That is when it decided
|
21 |
the Standard Oil case, and while we think of it as a
|
22 |
rule of reason case, it did talk about the three evils
|
23 |
of monopoly. It talked about first the power to fix
|
24 |
price and thereby injure the public; second, the power
|
25 |
of enabling a limitation on production; and third, the |
25
1 |
danger of deterioration in quality of the monopolized
|
2 |
article, which it deemed was the inevitable result of
|
3 |
the monopolistic control of its production. Price
|
4 |
increases, output reductions, quality deterioration,
|
5 |
those are still the same three touchstones that we look
|
6 |
to that you heard Debbie talk about that go all the way
|
7 |
back to the Supreme Court's discussion of the issue in
|
8 |
1910.
|
9 |
As we have talked about it in the 96 years since
|
10 |
that decision, there has emerged I would say sort of a
|
11 |
dichotomy or two different views of monopoly. While we
|
12 |
would all agree that they can have their evils, and this
|
13 |
was articulated in part by John Hicks in 1935, who
|
14 |
talked about the evils of monopoly in the terms of a
|
15 |
quiet life. He talked about the fact that the
|
16 |
monopolist may not be out there trying to get the
|
17 |
highest price he absolutely can get, maximizing in the
|
18 |
short term the most profit that he or she can get, but
|
19 |
really, it is the lack of competitive zeal, the ability
|
20 |
to sit back and relax, to not have to research, develop,
|
21 |
to innovate at a frantic level. That is a major harm of
|
22 |
monopoly, and that is something on which we are very
|
23 |
focused in terms of preventing.
|
24 |
Now, at the same time, the Supreme Court just
|
25 |
last year articulated a different view of monopoly. In |
26
1 |
the Trinko decision, the Court said, "The mere
|
2 |
possession of monopoly power and the concomitant
|
3 |
charging of monopoly prices is not only not unlawful, it
|
4 |
is an important element of the free market system. The
|
5 |
opportunity to charge monopoly prices, at least for a
|
6 |
short period, is what attracts business acumen in the
|
7 |
first place. It induces risk-taking that produces
|
8 |
innovation and economic growth."
|
9 |
All the way back in 1942, in Capitalism,
|
10 |
Socialism and Democracy, Joseph Schumpeter talked about
|
11 |
a similar process called creative destruction or the
|
12 |
gales of creative destruction, and I compliment my staff
|
13 |
who came up with the tornado there, but I have always,
|
14 |
since I read this in college, this -- be careful of the
|
15 |
gale behind you -- I have always liked this image,
|
16 |
because it talks about how the marketplace is a rough
|
17 |
place. It involves vigorous aggressive activity, people
|
18 |
fail, people are driven out of business, but it is
|
19 |
through that destructive process that you get creation.
|
20 |
Indeed, a similar image I was thinking about
|
21 |
recently, when somebody was talking to me about the
|
22 |
National Forest Service, I grew up watching the
|
23 |
commercials about Smokey the Bear and how forest fires
|
24 |
were such a terrible thing. How could we be against
|
25 |
forest fires? It turns out the National Park Service |
27
1 |
realizes that preventing forest fires can be a bad
|
2 |
thing; that if you prevent them for too long, you create
|
3 |
much bigger, larger, hotter fires that cause more
|
4 |
permanent destruction to the ecosystem when they do
|
5 |
occur. Periodic smaller fires are actually a good and
|
6 |
healthy part of the process. That to me is another
|
7 |
illustration of this basic image. Competitive, creative
|
8 |
destruction in the marketplace is something that we want
|
9 |
to preserve and protect, not chill along the lines that
|
10 |
Debbie was talking about.
|
11 |
So, how do we reconcile these two views of a
|
12 |
monopoly, as a bad thing that causes sloth and
|
13 |
relaxation and a lack of competitive drive versus the
|
14 |
benefits of creative destruction, the opportunity to get
|
15 |
to a monopoly? Well, this somewhat conflicting view was
|
16 |
illustrated in a book written in 1964, and this was R.W.
|
17 |
Grant expressing some frustration about the treatment of
|
18 |
monopolies, and I will read this to you in a moment, but
|
19 |
the basic story here is of a man named Tom Smith who
|
20 |
invents a bread machine. It will produce terrific
|
21 |
bread, it will slice it, it will wrap it, all for less
|
22 |
than a penny a loaf, and as you can imagine, he very
|
23 |
shortly owns the market for bread in the United States
|
24 |
and is making large sums of money. He is ultimately,
|
25 |
however, brought low by the men of antitrust who bring |
28
1 |
an antitrust case against him for making too much money
|
2 |
on the backs of consumers and driving everybody else out
|
3 |
of business, and he crafts a poem here to illustrate
|
4 |
this frustration.
|
5 |
"You're gouging on your prices
|
6 |
if you charge more than the rest
|
7 |
But it's unfair competition
|
8 |
if you think you can charge less!
|
9 |
A second point that we would make
|
10 |
to help avoid confusion:
|
11 |
Don't try to charge the same amount!
|
12 |
That would be collusion.
|
13 |
You must compete -- but not too much
|
14 |
for if you do, you see
|
15 |
then the market would be yours -ï½
|
16 |
and that would be monopoly!
|
17 |
It's very similar in many ways to the admonition
|
18 |
of Learned Hand in the Alcoa case who said that the
|
19 |
successful competitor, having been urged to compete,
|
20 |
must not be turned upon when he or she succeeds.
|
21 |
So, having expressed that frustration back in
|
22 |
the 1940s and 1960s, where are we today? One of our
|
23 |
esteemed both I would say academics and judicial members
|
24 |
of the antitrust community, Richard Posner, Judge
|
25 |
Posner, remarked just last year, "Antitrust policy |
29
1 |
toward 'unilateral abuses of market power' is 'the
|
2 |
biggest substantive issue facing antitrust today.'"
|
3 |
And if I can, if you will excuse me, preempt
|
4 |
Herb possibly, last year Herb is quoted or wrote,
|
5 |
"Notwithstanding a century of litigation," 96 years
|
6 |
since the Standard Oil decision, "the scope and the
|
7 |
meaning of exclusionary conduct under the Sherman Act
|
8 |
remain poorly defined."
|
9 |
Now, there are areas where I think there are
|
10 |
relatively easy answers. Doug Melamed has written about
|
11 |
the concept of naked exclusionary practices. I mean, if
|
12 |
you blow up your competitor's factory, few of us would
|
13 |
find that to be defensible conduct. That's a fairly
|
14 |
easy case for not finding liability. I also think there
|
15 |
are some fairly easy candidates for safe harbor
|
16 |
provisions. If you engage in conduct that merely
|
17 |
reduces your cost of production, that seems to me
|
18 |
beneficial to consumer welfare.
|
19 |
The difficulty lies in cases, as Debbie
|
20 |
referenced, that have the potential for both beneficial
|
21 |
cost reductions, innovation, development, integration,
|
22 |
and at the same time potentially anticompetitive
|
23 |
exclusion. How do we deal with those situations?
|
24 |
Well, some relatively recent Supreme Court
|
25 |
decisions have shown progress in this direction. In the |
30
1 |
Brooke Group case, which is, of course, a predatory
|
2 |
pricing case, it dealt specifically with the issue of
|
3 |
recoupment and holding that Liggett in that case had not
|
4 |
shown the opportunity or the ability to recoup, but the
|
5 |
case in my view, at least, stands for more than that and
|
6 |
discusses, for example, specifically how harm to a
|
7 |
competitor does not demonstrate harm to competition.
|
8 |
There was little doubt in that case that there were
|
9 |
discount programs aimed at and/or that had a harmful
|
10 |
effect on Liggett, but the Court was quite clear that as
|
11 |
long as that does not harm competition, that is not an
|
12 |
antitrust problem.
|
13 |
Second, the Court also talked about the
|
14 |
practical ability of a judicial tribunal to regulate a
|
15 |
problem and avoid chilling legitimate price cutting.
|
16 |
It's recognizing the limitations of the body that is
|
17 |
administering the law. I would expand that to include
|
18 |
the limitations of agencies as well as courts, but it's
|
19 |
certainly a relevant consideration, and recognizing that
|
20 |
aggressive price cutting can be beneficial for consumers
|
21 |
and we do not want to chill it. Thus, it created
|
22 |
effectively a safe harbor against predatory pricing
|
23 |
claims where the prices were above some appropriate
|
24 |
measure of cost.
|
25 |
And the Court expressly acknowledged in creating |
31
1 |
the safe harbor that there was at least the theoretical
|
2 |
possibility that there could be harm to consumers, harm
|
3 |
to consumer welfare, from some above-cost pricing, but
|
4 |
recognizing it was likely to do more harm than good to
|
5 |
try to ferret out those individual cases.
|
6 |
More recently, in the Trinko decision, the Court
|
7 |
obviously had a somewhat more limited holding but
|
8 |
discussed on a broader basis some of these same similar
|
9 |
Section 2 issues. It underscored the need for
|
10 |
administrable rules, clear objective standards. It
|
11 |
talked about the fact that being able to craft a remedy
|
12 |
that is both clear and administrable by the Court is
|
13 |
very important, endorsing Professor Areeda, in that no
|
14 |
court should impose a duty to deal that it cannot
|
15 |
explain or adequately and reasonably supervise, and
|
16 |
implicitly, at least, that not all problems may have
|
17 |
antitrust solutions.
|
18 |
While I think there are many areas of consensus,
|
19 |
there are many areas where we have a lot to learn. As
|
20 |
Debbie indicated, our panels are going to focus on
|
21 |
different aspects of conduct. We will start on Thursday
|
22 |
with a panel discussing predatory pricing and predatory
|
23 |
buying. Brooke Group answered a lot of questions. It
|
24 |
did not answer, among other things, what is the
|
25 |
appropriate measure of cost? Is it marginal cost? Is |
32
1 |
it average cost? Is it average avoidable cost? Is it
|
2 |
average total cost? There has been a lot of discussion
|
3 |
about that, and we are looking forward to hearing
|
4 |
people's views on that.
|
5 |
The question on predatory pricing or remedy, are
|
6 |
you going to enjoin lower pricing? Weyerhaeuser is a
|
7 |
case with which you may be familiar. There's a cert
|
8 |
petition pending before the Supreme Court right now. It
|
9 |
involves a predatory bidding situation. The Solicitor
|
10 |
General's Office has filed an amicus brief on this front
|
11 |
encouraging the Court to take cert and to examine it. I
|
12 |
view it, at least, as an opportunity for the Court to
|
13 |
reaffirm in the Section 2 context that clear and
|
14 |
objective standards are extraordinarily important.
|
15 |
There's a jury instruction at issue in this case that
|
16 |
talks about prices that are unfair or unnecessarily
|
17 |
high. This is an opportunity for the Court to make
|
18 |
clear that a jury's post hoc determination of what it
|
19 |
believes was unfair is not the appropriate criteria for
|
20 |
determining whether or not there should be Section 2
|
21 |
liability.
|
22 |
Refusals to deal will follow. Again, this
|
23 |
raises very significant issues. When, if ever, should a
|
24 |
firm be compelled to deal with a competitor? If you are
|
25 |
compelled to deal, under what terms and conditions? |
33
1 |
Will the Court be able to administer it? A range of
|
2 |
issues which we are, again, looking forward to hearing
|
3 |
the experts' views on it.
|
4 |
Loyalty discounts, another area that we will be
|
5 |
looking at. A couple of years ago, the United States
|
6 |
urged the Supreme Court not to take cert in the LePage's
|
7 |
case. That involved bundled discounts. That was not
|
8 |
because we necessarily agreed with the Third Circuit's
|
9 |
decision or analysis. Indeed, if you parse that
|
10 |
decision, I think it is very difficult to come up with a
|
11 |
clear standard of liability. There has been, in the
|
12 |
wake of LePage's, a flurry of attention by academics, by
|
13 |
legal scholars, on this issue of bundled discounts,
|
14 |
loyalty discounts, and we are looking and hoping to see
|
15 |
whether or not any consensus has developed on any of
|
16 |
these issues.
|
17 |
Should it be viewed as a predatory pricing
|
18 |
tactic, as exclusive dealing, as a tying tactic? Are
|
19 |
there safe harbors that can be developed even if we
|
20 |
cannot develop a single, clear answer for all cases?
|
21 |
Tying and exclusive dealing, Debbie mentioned that you
|
22 |
sometimes, when you see things in a competitive market,
|
23 |
that ought to make you question whether or not there are
|
24 |
benefits associated with it. Tying and exclusive
|
25 |
dealing can have anticompetitive effects. Look at our |
34
1 |
Dentsply case as a recent example. By the same token,
|
2 |
we see these practices in competitive markets, and we
|
3 |
need to better understand what benefits there are and
|
4 |
when there are not.
|
5 |
Towards the end of the year, we expect to turn
|
6 |
toward some more general principles. Is there an
|
7 |
overarching standard for Section 2 cases and liability?
|
8 |
We all agree that consumer welfare is an appropriate
|
9 |
standard. Trying to operationalize that in a particular
|
10 |
case with particular conduct is more challenging, and
|
11 |
there is less agreement on that. Debbie outlined the
|
12 |
range of potential tests. The Antitrust Division in a
|
13 |
number of recent cases looked to the no-economic-sense
|
14 |
test. As I have talked with people about that, one
|
15 |
issue that I find is that people have different ideas of
|
16 |
what the test is. So, over and above discussing what
|
17 |
the appropriate test ought to be, there is some
|
18 |
confusion about what is meant in terms of what are you
|
19 |
going to look at and what the rules are. That may be
|
20 |
part of the semantic difference that Debbie was
|
21 |
referencing. Clarifying some of those things as well as
|
22 |
the underlying substantive issues I think can be
|
23 |
beneficial.
|
24 |
We may look at the issue of whether there are
|
25 |
different duties or different criteria for tying claims |
35
1 |
under Section 3 of the Clayton Act versus Section 1 or
|
2 |
Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
|
3 |
Here, I have two reasons for putting this up.
|
4 |
As you can see, this associate is responding to a
|
5 |
request, "I'll be happy to give you innovative thinking.
|
6 |
What are your guidelines?" An example of having too
|
7 |
cabined an approach, too narrow a guidelines can be the
|
8 |
antithesis of innovative thinking, can restrain the
|
9 |
benefits that you may achieve through your innovation
|
10 |
and development. That is part of the creative
|
11 |
destruction that we want to encourage, not discourage,
|
12 |
as this cartoon suggests may be happening. So, I raise
|
13 |
that to say that while I am now going to talk about six
|
14 |
possible principles to inform our discussions, I do not
|
15 |
mean them to cabin or prevent a wide-ranging, open and
|
16 |
frank exchange of ideas.
|
17 |
So, first off, individual firms with market
|
18 |
monopoly power can act anticompetitively and harm
|
19 |
consumer welfare, and we should seek to identify and
|
20 |
prosecute such conduct. This is an important first
|
21 |
principle. If it were not true, we could just abolish
|
22 |
Section 2. That is not what we are here to do. We are
|
23 |
here to better focus and identify those instances where
|
24 |
there really is harm to consumer welfare.
|
25 |
Second, mere size, mere market share, does not |
36
1 |
necessarily demonstrate competitive harm. It can
|
2 |
demonstrate superior acumen, effort, zeal, et cetera.
|
3 |
Third, injury to competitors does not
|
4 |
demonstrate competitive harm, a point that has been
|
5 |
talked about in a number of contexts.
|
6 |
Fourth, the need for clear, objective and
|
7 |
administrable rules, so that businesses, at the time
|
8 |
they are taking actions, can understand where the lines
|
9 |
are and can conform their behavior so they are not
|
10 |
deterred from engaging in procompetitive activity, so
|
11 |
that courts are not asked to do things that are beyond
|
12 |
their competence, and that agencies can do the same.
|
13 |
Fifth, avoid chilling procompetitive conduct,
|
14 |
and certainly an interrelated point, self-explanatory.
|
15 |
And finally, the remedy must promote
|
16 |
competition. A remedy that harms competition can be
|
17 |
worse than no remedy at all, an important point worthy
|
18 |
of bearing in mind.
|
19 |
Again, I want to thank the FTC, our panelists
|
20 |
for agreeing to kick off these hearings. We will
|
21 |
continue again on Thursday. We very much are interested
|
22 |
in a free, open and wide-ranging discussion of these
|
23 |
issues and are excited about the prospect.
|
24 |
With that, I will turn it over to Herb.
|
25 |
(Applause.) |
37
1 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: Thank you. I am very grateful
|
2 |
and appreciative of being invited here, with particular
|
3 |
thanks to Chairperson Majoras and General Barnett for
|
4 |
extending this invitation.
|
5 |
In keeping with the thrust of this opening
|
6 |
meeting, which I believe is quite general, what I would
|
7 |
like to do is give kind of an overview of where I think
|
8 |
the fault lines and concerns in Section 2 lie. In the
|
9 |
future, future hearings, you are going to hear about
|
10 |
specific practices such as predatory pricing or refusals
|
11 |
to deal in considerable detail, and I am not going to do
|
12 |
that today. I am going to go through them rather
|
13 |
quickly and just point out where I think work needs to
|
14 |
be done and where the FTC and the Antitrust Division and
|
15 |
private litigants can use some clarification and
|
16 |
understanding.
|
17 |
I am going to divide my talk into three parts,
|
18 |
though the parts are not equal in size. First, a very
|
19 |
short one on market power or monopoly power, then a
|
20 |
rather long one on conduct issues, and then finally, a
|
21 |
much shorter one again on remedies.
|
22 |
With respect to power, the Merger Guidelines, in
|
23 |
particular the 1992 Merger Guidelines, the series of
|
24 |
guidelines that began with 1984, did a remarkable job of
|
25 |
rationalizing and simplifying the approach to market |
38
1 |
delineation and assessment of the potential for
|
2 |
collusion or other types of anticompetitive behavior
|
3 |
that grow out of mergers. Some portions of the Merger
|
4 |
Guidelines market delineation sections are relevant to
|
5 |
Section 2 enforcement, but many are not, because the
|
6 |
question that one asks in a Section 2 case is
|
7 |
fundamentally different from the one that one asks in a
|
8 |
merger case.
|
9 |
In a merger case, we generally start out with
|
10 |
the presumption that a market is more or less
|
11 |
competitive, it may be oligopolistic or moderately
|
12 |
competitive prior to the merger, and what we really want
|
13 |
to know is whether the quality of competition is going
|
14 |
to deteriorate as a consequence of the merger. In
|
15 |
keeping with that, the SSNIP test, small but significant
|
16 |
nontransitory increase in price test, considers whether
|
17 |
a further increase in price would cause new entry or
|
18 |
other situations that would make this future price
|
19 |
increase unsustainable.
|
20 |
In a Section 2 case, by contrast, the opening
|
21 |
presumption is that the defendant or the firm under
|
22 |
examination is already a monopolist, is already charging
|
23 |
monopoly prices, and as a result, the SSNIP test is
|
24 |
really not the appropriate one in most circumstances,
|
25 |
although it certainly could be relevant in certain cases |
39
1 |
like those involving an attempt to monopolize where the
|
2 |
defendant is not a monopolist at the time the conduct is
|
3 |
being assessed.
|
4 |
I do not have a solution to propose here. Those
|
5 |
of you who are familiar with this area know that this
|
6 |
involves something that in monopolization law we call
|
7 |
the Cellophane fallacy or the fallacy of inferring that
|
8 |
a firm lacks power because there is high
|
9 |
cross-elasticity of demand with the products of others
|
10 |
at current market prices, and, of course, if you
|
11 |
multiply that examination by asking what the response
|
12 |
would be to a yet further increase by a firm that is
|
13 |
already a monopolist, you might very well conclude that
|
14 |
the firm lacks this type of market power, because in
|
15 |
response to a yet further price increase, there would be
|
16 |
so much substitution away from the dominant firm's
|
17 |
product that the price increase would be unprofitable.
|
18 |
Well, if you took that approach, you would be
|
19 |
committing an error; namely, you would be ignoring the
|
20 |
fact that that firm is already a monopolist and
|
21 |
presumably already charging its profit-maximizing price.
|
22 |
So, I think one of the things that ought to be of
|
23 |
concern to the agencies as they go through these
|
24 |
hearings is to pay some special attention to the
|
25 |
formulation of usable presumptions that single firms can |
40
1 |
use for assessing whether they have individual market
|
2 |
power and thus can be made liable to a Section 2
|
3 |
inquiry.
|
4 |
Let me just add to that, that that may involve
|
5 |
certain approaches that we have more or less given short
|
6 |
shrift to or rejected in the past. For example, it may
|
7 |
mean that we will not look at residual elasticity of
|
8 |
demand, which looks at the existing power that firms
|
9 |
have. We may have to look at things like price-cost
|
10 |
margins or rates of return. Some of these approaches
|
11 |
have been discredited in the past, but that does not
|
12 |
mean that they cannot be rehabilitated.
|
13 |
Okay, I want to spend a little more time on
|
14 |
monopolizing conduct. I am going to open by giving the
|
15 |
definition of monopolizing conduct from The Antitrust
|
16 |
Law Treatise that I am privileged to write, because it
|
17 |
is very general, has a number of flaws, but
|
18 |
nevertheless, I happen to like it for reasons I will
|
19 |
explain in a little while. The Antitrust Law Treatise
|
20 |
defines exclusionary conduct as conduct that is, number
|
21 |
one, reasonably capable of creating, enlarging or
|
22 |
prolonging monopoly power by impairing the opportunities
|
23 |
of rivals; and two, that either does not benefit
|
24 |
consumers at all or is unnecessary for the particular
|
25 |
consumer benefits that the acts produce; or three, |
41
1 |
produces harms that are disproportionate to the
|
2 |
benefits; and finally, the assessment of the conduct
|
3 |
must be within the administrative capacity of the
|
4 |
antitrust tribunal.
|
5 |
Like I say, that test is very general. It is
|
6 |
not particularly helpful to assessing particular
|
7 |
instances of exclusionary conduct if it is the only
|
8 |
thing you have. You certainly would not want to give a
|
9 |
jury that test as an instruction and shut them up with
|
10 |
no further instruction and ask whether the defendant's
|
11 |
conduct was exclusionary, but the test was never
|
12 |
intended that way. It was, in fact, designed to be a
|
13 |
basic principle to be used in conjunction with specific
|
14 |
rules for specific types of antitrust cases, and it is
|
15 |
my view that that is fundamentally what Section 2
|
16 |
conduct jurisprudence needs to do.
|
17 |
I think there are very, very helpful general
|
18 |
tests. I like Greg Werden's no-economic-sense test. I
|
19 |
think there is much to be said for it. I think it
|
20 |
produces a few false negatives. Nevertheless, it's a
|
21 |
very, very good starting point. I like Judge Posner's
|
22 |
test that Chairperson Majoras mentioned in her talk,
|
23 |
which is conduct which under the circumstances is
|
24 |
capable of excluding an equally efficient rival. Once
|
25 |
again, I think it produces a few too many false |
42
1 |
negatives, but they are good starting places.
|
2 |
However, none of them is a substitute for the
|
3 |
formulation of good technical rules covering individual
|
4 |
types of conduct; namely, pricing, abuses of the
|
5 |
intellectual property system, refusals to deal and so
|
6 |
on, okay?
|
7 |
In the few minutes I have, I cannot do any more
|
8 |
than scratch the surface, but I would like to give you
|
9 |
just a few observations about where we are in various
|
10 |
areas involving specific exclusionary practices and
|
11 |
where I think some of the problems lie.
|
12 |
With respect to predatory pricing, I believe
|
13 |
that both the Areeda-Turner test, as it was formulated
|
14 |
in 1975 and has later been incorporated into The
|
15 |
Antitrust Law Treatise, plus the elaboration of the
|
16 |
recoupment requirement in the Brooke Group case in 1993,
|
17 |
fundamentally set predatory pricing law on the right
|
18 |
track. I am a strong believer in the view that prices
|
19 |
must be below some measure of cost. Furthermore, they
|
20 |
must be below some measure of incremental cost; that is,
|
21 |
pricing is driven by concerns for variable costs, not
|
22 |
principally by fixed costs. That does not mean that
|
23 |
there are not a few problems.
|
24 |
One problem that I think needs to be assessed is
|
25 |
the problem of predatory pricing in oligopoly industries |
43
1 |
by nondominant firms. That was, in fact, the facts of
|
2 |
Brooke Group. Strictly speaking, that may not be a
|
3 |
Section 2 issue. In fact, it may be an issue where the
|
4 |
Justice Department might reconsider its long-standing
|
5 |
opposition to bringing Robinson-Patman Act suits since
|
6 |
the late 1970s report on the Robinson-Patman Act and
|
7 |
create an exception for primary line enforcement given
|
8 |
the premise that with respect to primary line
|
9 |
enforcement, the principles that the Court follows are
|
10 |
basically the principles that are laid out in the
|
11 |
Sherman Act, and as a result, all of the overreaching
|
12 |
that applies to secondary line enforcement of the
|
13 |
Robinson-Patman Act need not apply here.
|
14 |
The problem with predatory pricing and oligopoly
|
15 |
is that victims have a different set of incentives than
|
16 |
they do in monopoly. Predatory pricing as a Section 2
|
17 |
problem involves predatory pricing designed to destroy a
|
18 |
rival. That is a very, very difficult thing to do. The
|
19 |
rival clearly has incentives to resist.
|
20 |
On the other hand, predatory pricing and
|
21 |
oligopoly frequently is used simply to enforce or bring
|
22 |
the oligopoly back into order so that the noncompliant
|
23 |
firm will once again raise its price to the oligopoly
|
24 |
levels; that is, the set of incentives that the target
|
25 |
of predatory pricing and oligopoly has are incentives to |
44
1 |
rejoin, start making profits once again. As a result, I
|
2 |
believe predatory pricing in oligopoly industries is
|
3 |
fundamentally a more plausible strategy than strict
|
4 |
monopoly predatory pricing, and I think it needs to be
|
5 |
given somewhat closer scrutiny.
|
6 |
The other problem has to do with the measurement
|
7 |
of relevant costs. As I said before, I think the proper
|
8 |
measure of cost is incremental cost, which can mean
|
9 |
short-run marginal cost, short-run marginal cost with
|
10 |
some kind of additional factor for depreciable long-term
|
11 |
assets. It can mean average variable cost, as it was in
|
12 |
the Areeda-Turner formulation. The average variable
|
13 |
cost tests or the marginal cost tests simply don't work
|
14 |
very well in certain kinds of markets that have very
|
15 |
high fixed cost components and particularly in markets
|
16 |
that are characterized by a lot of intellectual property
|
17 |
or certain kinds of public utility or transportation
|
18 |
markets, such as the airline industry.
|
19 |
I think Ken Elzinga's analysis in the Spirit
|
20 |
Airlines case last year in the Sixth Circuit was a very
|
21 |
good first step, but the Government shouldn't be losing
|
22 |
predatory pricing cases in the airline industry. It is
|
23 |
the one industry where predatory pricing claims seem
|
24 |
plausible, and some attention needs to be paid to
|
25 |
modifying or, if necessary, rejecting and adopting a |
45
1 |
different cost test for such industries.
|
2 |
On the Weyerhaeuser case and predatory buying, I
|
3 |
am one of the critics. I hope the Supreme Court sees
|
4 |
fit to follow the SG and grant cert. I think the
|
5 |
instruction that General Barnett described that
|
6 |
permitted a jury to find simply that predatory buying
|
7 |
occurs when the defendant pays too much or more than a
|
8 |
fair price is an atrocity. I think few people fully
|
9 |
appreciate how frequently such situations can come up;
|
10 |
that is, buying of inputs during times of scarcity.
|
11 |
This is not going to be an idiosyncratic situation.
|
12 |
This kind of case will come up a lot if the Ninth
|
13 |
Circuit's decision is permitted to stand.
|
14 |
Now, having said that, the question is what kind
|
15 |
of test to come up with. Well, in the Weyerhaeuser
|
16 |
case, where first of all the timber at issue accounted
|
17 |
for some 60 or 70 percent of the value of the finished
|
18 |
hardwood, and secondly, where at least according to the
|
19 |
jury, the hardwood was resold in a competitive market, I
|
20 |
think an average variable cost test might work quite
|
21 |
well; that is, buying is predatory if it forces the
|
22 |
defendant's resale prices to below its costs.
|
23 |
I am a little troubled by the use of an average
|
24 |
variable cost or marginal cost test, however, in a
|
25 |
situation where, number one, the defendant may sell in |
46
1 |
an oligopoly, and number two, where the input on which
|
2 |
predatory buying is claimed is a relatively low
|
3 |
proportion of the value of the finished product, because
|
4 |
in that case, the variation in purchase might actually
|
5 |
fall within the margins that the firm charges, that it
|
6 |
is going to be too hard to detect predatory buying in
|
7 |
cases where the value of the purchased input is only a
|
8 |
tiny proportion of the value of the finished product.
|
9 |
In all cases, however, I believe that there
|
10 |
should be a recoupment requirement equivalent to that in
|
11 |
Brooke Group and that the Ninth Circuit erred not only
|
12 |
in its failure to require a showing of prices below
|
13 |
cost, but also in its failure to require a fairly strict
|
14 |
showing of recoupment.
|
15 |
With respect to patents, there is too much to
|
16 |
say and too little time. I just want to make one fairly
|
17 |
general observation. Mr. Barnett mentioned Joseph
|
18 |
Schumpeter's Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, this
|
19 |
very, very important book in 1942 which opined in the
|
20 |
chapter on creative destruction that the amount of
|
21 |
welfare contributed to the economy through innovation is
|
22 |
far, far greater than the amount contributed by moderate
|
23 |
movements from oligopoly to competitive industries. I
|
24 |
mean, Schumpeter basically looked at the prior half
|
25 |
century or so of development as a result of the second |
47
1 |
industrial revolution, of the theorizing of economists
|
2 |
like Edward Chamberlin and Joan Robinson, who were very
|
3 |
upset about oligopoly and imperfections in the economy,
|
4 |
and said, "You'd think to listen to these people that
|
5 |
American consumers were much, much impoverished compared
|
6 |
to their position in the 1870s, and, in fact, nothing
|
7 |
could be further from the truth."
|
8 |
Well, where do all those gains come from if we
|
9 |
are now in this oligopolistic era? And one of the
|
10 |
things Schumpeter concluded is that they came from
|
11 |
innovation. Schumpeter's premises were formalized and
|
12 |
given empirical support in Robert Solo's work in the
|
13 |
1950s in which Solo himself concluded that as much as 80
|
14 |
percent of economic gain comes from innovation rather
|
15 |
than simple improvements in price-cost relationships.
|
16 |
Now, neither Schumpeter nor Solo was talking
|
17 |
about IP law. They were talking about innovation, and,
|
18 |
of course, there is this enormous lingering question out
|
19 |
there of whether the IP laws we have are sufficient to
|
20 |
facilitate the optimal amount of innovation or whether
|
21 |
they, in fact, may hinder innovation. Fundamentally,
|
22 |
that is not antitrust's problem. The antitrust laws
|
23 |
need to accept the existing IP laws, warts and all, and
|
24 |
I personally believe there are a fair number of warts.
|
25 |
One thing, however, that that work suggests is |
48
1 |
that antitrust needs to be much more concerned with
|
2 |
restraints on innovation. We have generally measured
|
3 |
harm in the antitrust laws by looking at price-cost
|
4 |
relationships, deviations from marginal cost pricing.
|
5 |
Harm to innovation is always included kind of as an
|
6 |
afterthought, but it has never been very well formalized
|
7 |
into our models of harm, and actually, there are pretty
|
8 |
good reasons for that. We have very good rules for
|
9 |
determining when prices deviate from marginal costs and
|
10 |
what the price elasticities facing firms are.
|
11 |
Predicting the consequences of restraints on innovation
|
12 |
is far more difficult, because innovation always takes
|
13 |
us by surprise.
|
14 |
We will never know, for example, what the
|
15 |
consequences were of Microsoft's successful attempts to
|
16 |
get Intel to stop developing a Java-enabled chip. How
|
17 |
good would it have been? Would it have done all the
|
18 |
things that Bill Gates feared in commoditizing the
|
19 |
platform market and so on? Those are very hard things
|
20 |
to predict, and for that reason, I believe courts are
|
21 |
rightfully skeptical when they turn away private
|
22 |
plaintiffs who claim that the injury that they suffer is
|
23 |
an injury caused by a lack of innovation.
|
24 |
So, I believe this is one area where the
|
25 |
Government should move into the fore, because they do |
49
1 |
not need to prove damages, they do not need to prove
|
2 |
causation in the strict private plaintiff sense. I
|
3 |
think restraints on innovation are something that need
|
4 |
far more development in Section 2 law than they have
|
5 |
received in the past.
|
6 |
With respect to vertical exclusion, I just have
|
7 |
a couple of comments. First of all, there has been a
|
8 |
not so subtle move over the last four or five years in
|
9 |
government enforcement to move away from Section 1 of
|
10 |
the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act and
|
11 |
towards Section 2 of the Sherman Act as a device for
|
12 |
enforcing laws against tying or tying-like practices and
|
13 |
exclusive dealing, and I believe that is the correct
|
14 |
movement. Fundamentally, tying and exclusive dealing
|
15 |
ought to be regarded as dominant firm exclusionary
|
16 |
practices. They are rarely anticompetitive at
|
17 |
nondominant levels, and fundamentally, they do not
|
18 |
depend on agreement in any meaningful sense of the word.
|
19 |
Unlike resale price maintenance or Sylvania-style
|
20 |
restraints, they are typically not the product of
|
21 |
bargaining and traditional agreement between dealers and
|
22 |
manufacturers.
|
23 |
No, most tying and most exclusive dealing is
|
24 |
imposed by manufacturers unilaterally on dealers. The
|
25 |
dealers generally do not like it, but they accept it as |
50
1 |
the price of a dealership. It ought to be treated as an
|
2 |
exclusionary practice, number one. The agreement
|
3 |
requirements really get in the way of appropriate
|
4 |
analysis of tying and exclusive dealing in most
|
5 |
situations. And finally, the market power requirement
|
6 |
should be equivalent to those that we assess in
|
7 |
monopolization cases.
|
8 |
So, I laud the increased scrutiny of tying and
|
9 |
exclusive dealing under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
|
10 |
Microsoft included both, but the Government won on its
|
11 |
Section 2 tying claims. Dentsply, of course, the
|
12 |
exclusive dealing case that the Government won a year or
|
13 |
two ago, was a Section 2 case.
|
14 |
On bundled discount -- you are going to have a
|
15 |
big hearing on these, right? You are going to talk
|
16 |
about bundled discounts a lot? Are they predatory
|
17 |
pricing or are they tying? I think they are a little
|
18 |
bit of both, and I think the way to analyze them is by
|
19 |
asking two questions in two different stages.
|
20 |
The first question you ask is, are two goods
|
21 |
subject to a bundled discount bundled together? Well,
|
22 |
what does that mean? Well, it means that an equally
|
23 |
efficient firm that offered only one of them could not
|
24 |
match the bundled offer. How do you get there? Well,
|
25 |
as several papers have shown, you basically attribute |
51
1 |
the entire discount to the product upon which exclusion
|
2 |
is claimed, and then you ask whether the price of that
|
3 |
product, subject to the full discount, has fallen below
|
4 |
a relevant measure of cost, whatever cost measure you
|
5 |
would use in a predatory pricing case, okay?
|
6 |
That gets you to bundling; that is, that
|
7 |
predatory pricing test gets you an answer to the
|
8 |
question, are the two firms -- are the two products
|
9 |
bundled together? And if the answer is that no equally
|
10 |
efficient firm that offered only one of the products can
|
11 |
match the price, then they are bundled together, but
|
12 |
that is only the beginning rather than the end of the
|
13 |
inquiry. Tying is explicit bundling of products
|
14 |
together, and yet most tying is perfectly legal. So,
|
15 |
once we have decided that two products are bundled
|
16 |
together, we have yet a further set of questions to ask
|
17 |
about whether there is foreclosure, whether the
|
18 |
foreclosure is justified under the circumstances by cost
|
19 |
reductions, improvements in consumer satisfaction,
|
20 |
quality control, in many instances price discrimination,
|
21 |
and so on.
|
22 |
Finally, on conduct, on refusals to deal, my
|
23 |
suggestion is that the Government simply get out of the
|
24 |
business of enforcing the law against simple refusals to
|
25 |
deal. Now, conditional refusals are something else. |
52
1 |
Conditions usually mean exclusive dealing or tying.
|
2 |
Lots of things, including price fixing, can amount to
|
3 |
conditional refusals to deal, but if we are talking
|
4 |
about simple refusals to deal in the Trinko or Aspen
|
5 |
sense, I think the administrative problems are so
|
6 |
horrific, the disincentives created to competitive
|
7 |
behavior are so substantial, that the best thing that
|
8 |
the Government can do is stay away, and, in fact, that
|
9 |
is pretty much what they have been doing, even going so
|
10 |
far as to support the defendants in the Trinko case.
|
11 |
Okay, then let me turn finally and very briefly
|
12 |
to the subject of remedies. Both General Barnett and
|
13 |
Debbie Majoras spoke at some length about the importance
|
14 |
of remedy. I simply want to underscore what they said.
|
15 |
In fact, I would go a little bit further and say that
|
16 |
every Section 2 action that the Government brings ought
|
17 |
to begin with an exit strategy, right? We have talked
|
18 |
about Iraq, we have talked about exit strategies, and
|
19 |
now we have discovered that whatever exit strategy we
|
20 |
have, we probably could have had a better one, and the
|
21 |
same thing applies to Section 2.
|
22 |
Section 2 has no moral content. The only
|
23 |
purpose in bringing these cases is to make the economy
|
24 |
work better, and if you do not have a clear picture of
|
25 |
the kind of remedy you want when you go in, then you |
53
1 |
really have to wonder whether it is worth bringing the
|
2 |
action to begin with.
|
3 |
For a long, long period of our history,
|
4 |
beginning with Standard Oil and through the 1960s, the
|
5 |
preferred remedies were structural or mandatory breakup
|
6 |
of firms. For relatively good reasons, those kinds of
|
7 |
remedies have fallen into some disrepute. Many of them
|
8 |
were very, very poorly designed. For example, the
|
9 |
remedy in the United Machinery case, which may have
|
10 |
ruined the firm, although there was some good evidence
|
11 |
that USM's technology in its Beverly, Massachusetts
|
12 |
plant was pretty obsolete already to begin with, or
|
13 |
remedies like the one in Grinnell, which didn't really
|
14 |
break up the monopoly at all, but just divided up the
|
15 |
market into a whole bunch of little monopolies.
|
16 |
Today, we operate in a regime in which
|
17 |
structural remedies in Section 2 cases appear to be
|
18 |
disfavored; conduct remedies are preferred.
|
19 |
Unfortunately, I think the record that we are developing
|
20 |
with respect to conduct remedies is not much better than
|
21 |
the record we developed with respect to structural
|
22 |
remedies in the 1960s and earlier. I think the verdict
|
23 |
is still out on the Microsoft remedy, largely because of
|
24 |
the two-year extension, but once that time period has
|
25 |
run, we have to look back and say, "Well, exactly what |
54
1 |
did we accomplish here in terms of making this market
|
2 |
more competitive? And to the extent the market is more
|
3 |
competitive, to what extent was it owed to the remedy?"
|
4 |
I would like to see some more serious attention
|
5 |
be paid once again to structural remedies or at least
|
6 |
modified structural remedies, things like compulsory
|
7 |
licensing, as mechanisms for restoring competition.
|
8 |
Compulsory licensing is a dirty word in the United
|
9 |
States when we are talking about general forcing of
|
10 |
firms to share their patents, but that is not what we
|
11 |
are talking about here. We are talking about proven
|
12 |
antitrust violators who are frequently forced to give up
|
13 |
their plants and other kinds of hardware. Compulsory
|
14 |
licensing under that set of circumstances is a perfectly
|
15 |
viable remedy, and I would like to see us use it much
|
16 |
more seriously than we have in the past.
|
17 |
I am afraid I have gone over my time, and so I
|
18 |
will turn the floor over to Professor Carlton. Thank
|
19 |
you.
|
20 |
(Applause.)
|
21 |
DR. CARLTON: Okay, thank you. It is a pleasure
|
22 |
to be here, and I express my appreciation to the
|
23 |
organizers for inviting me, and I am honored to sit with
|
24 |
such distinguished panelists.
|
25 |
Exclusionary conduct is an important policy |
55
1 |
topic. There is a great amount of debate as to what is
|
2 |
an exclusionary act and how to deal with it. There is
|
3 |
much less consensus on what bad acts are and how to
|
4 |
adjudicate them in the context of Section 2 claims,
|
5 |
than, for example, what cartel behavior is or how to
|
6 |
handle cartl claims. The real problem is that
|
7 |
competition harms rivals just like exclusionary
|
8 |
behavior, and it is sometimes easy to confuse the two.
|
9 |
As a general matter, it is very hard to study
|
10 |
what should be the optimal policy for exclusionary
|
11 |
conduct. The reason, one reason, is that the biggest
|
12 |
effect of any antitrust policy is likely to be, not on
|
13 |
litigants in litigated cases, but rather, on firms that
|
14 |
are not involved in litigation at all but are forced to
|
15 |
change their business behavior in contemplation of legal
|
16 |
rules. That means that although it is definitely
|
17 |
informative for economists and lawyers to study the
|
18 |
outcome of individual cases and you can learn a lot -ï½
|
19 |
did the court get it right, did they get it wrong -ï½
|
20 |
that is not really a study of antitrust policy.
|
21 |
To appropriately do a study of antitrust policy,
|
22 |
you have to look at either times when the antitrust laws
|
23 |
were adjudicated differently, that is, there was a
|
24 |
different policy, or perhaps you have to look at
|
25 |
different countries, and that is hard to do. Looking at |
56
1 |
litigated cases will give you a biased view. They are
|
2 |
very self-selected cases and really will not allow you
|
3 |
to focus on what may well be the biggest costs of an
|
4 |
antitrust policy, and that is, the chilling effect it
|
5 |
has on the behavior of nonlitigants.
|
6 |
Since this is an introductory panel, one of the
|
7 |
advantages you get is you can yell out these hard
|
8 |
questions, and then when they are not answered by the
|
9 |
end, you can say, "See, you didn't answer my question,"
|
10 |
so I am not suggesting I have a simple answer. I am
|
11 |
just saying here that this is actually a quite important
|
12 |
problem and definitely deserves some research time.
|
13 |
What I will talk about today and on which I
|
14 |
think I do have some answers are two topics. One has to
|
15 |
do with the profit sacrifice test, or its variant, the
|
16 |
no-economic-sense test, and the other has to do with
|
17 |
market definition. Each of those is used or proposed to
|
18 |
be used as a tool to uncover Section 2 violations.
|
19 |
Now, it is important to distinguish a tool from
|
20 |
an objective. The objective is to maximize consumer
|
21 |
welfare, and whether when I say consumer welfare, I mean
|
22 |
consumer plus producer surplus or just consumer surplus,
|
23 |
that is a debate we can hold for another time. It does
|
24 |
not matter to the remarks I am going to make.
|
25 |
The tools you choose are used to identify acts |
57
1 |
that harm welfare. Now, the use of tools necessarily
|
2 |
entails errors. You are going to have false negatives
|
3 |
and false positives. It is going to happen because,
|
4 |
one, you do not always have perfect information. Even
|
5 |
if you are the smartest economist, you make errors, and
|
6 |
if you are a juror who knows no economics, you might
|
7 |
make errors, and second, the tools are not quite the
|
8 |
same as the objective. So, the tools will differ from
|
9 |
the objectives sometimes, so there definitely will be
|
10 |
errors, and the real question is whether and when tools
|
11 |
should be used.
|
12 |
From an economic point of view, the question of
|
13 |
whether a particular act harmed consumers is a very
|
14 |
well-posed question that I could, for example, assign to
|
15 |
a Ph.D. student writing his thesis, and that person
|
16 |
could go about trying to answer it with economic tools
|
17 |
and econometric tools. Now, it is true it sometimes may
|
18 |
be hard for that person to reach an answer, especially
|
19 |
if there is both an efficiency effect and an
|
20 |
exclusionary effect on rivals, but sometimes it will not
|
21 |
be so hard, okay, but it is a well-posed question.
|
22 |
Now, from a policy perspective, the DOJ and the
|
23 |
FTC, with their staffs of knowledgeable economists and
|
24 |
attorneys, should be focusing on answering the direct
|
25 |
question, is there harm to welfare, and not on the use |
58
1 |
of possible tools, though obviously they need,
|
2 |
especially if they are going to think about litigation,
|
3 |
they need to worry how judges and juries will use
|
4 |
whatever tools they are told to use when a case is
|
5 |
litigated.
|
6 |
Now, matters change as the inquiry shifts away
|
7 |
from the government agencies to courts with judges and
|
8 |
juries who may have less economic sophistication, and
|
9 |
their simple but imperfect rules may be better than an
|
10 |
unstructured inquiry, but simple rules should not be
|
11 |
viewed as anything but simple rules, crude guides that
|
12 |
sometimes work for some acts, but not all. It can be
|
13 |
dangerous to use a simple rule that could ultimately
|
14 |
subvert the goal of maximizing welfare.
|
15 |
Now, let me turn to first the profit sacrifice
|
16 |
test and then to market definition. The profit
|
17 |
sacrifice test, or a close relative, the
|
18 |
no-economic-sense test, asks would the act make sense
|
19 |
but for its exclusionary effect? And that test may work
|
20 |
fine in the hands of some of its accomplished
|
21 |
proponents, and in particular, I have in mind Greg
|
22 |
Werden, who is sitting here in the audience. My hunch
|
23 |
is if I sit down with Greg and we are talking about an
|
24 |
exclusionary act, we are going to reach agreement nine
|
25 |
times out of ten, and he is aware of the limitations of |
59
1 |
the test and would carve out exceptions so it would not
|
2 |
be misused.
|
3 |
What I worry about is when there is someone
|
4 |
implementing the test who is not as smart as Greg.
|
5 |
Suppose they have a judge or a jury who is not an
|
6 |
economist? What worries me about the test is that it
|
7 |
raises all the danger signs associated with possibly
|
8 |
confusing competition with exclusionary conduct. Let me
|
9 |
try and explain why, and I will give you two or three
|
10 |
reasons.
|
11 |
First, all strategic behavior -- and every
|
12 |
business school teaches this -- all strategic behavior
|
13 |
is designed to improve one firm's position relative to
|
14 |
the other one. It is relative position that matters,
|
15 |
and that is what is going to often determine the outcome
|
16 |
of a competitive battle. Investments in advertising,
|
17 |
investments in R&D, price discounts, all of these could
|
18 |
mistakenly and easily be condemned by jurors convinced
|
19 |
that the firm engaged in the act could have been more
|
20 |
accommodating, less exclusionary. That "but for"
|
21 |
standard -- that is, would the act make sense but for
|
22 |
the exclusionary effect -- that hypothetical thought
|
23 |
experiment is actually quite a difficult one to
|
24 |
implement. That does not mean if you are measuring harm
|
25 |
to consumer welfare that you can necessarily get around |
60
1 |
it. Maybe it is unavoidable sometimes, but I am worried
|
2 |
when you are postulating the "but for" the exclusionary
|
3 |
conduct, what hypothetical world will you be proposing,
|
4 |
and what worries me is there could be a very high error
|
5 |
rate associated with application of that rule.
|
6 |
The second reason I am worried about it is
|
7 |
because of the way it is formulated: Does it make
|
8 |
economic sense to engage in this behavior? Now, Ronald
|
9 |
Coase, one of my colleagues at the University of
|
10 |
Chicago, always fond of explaining how little economists
|
11 |
know about business and that businessmen really know a
|
12 |
lot about business, and just because an economist cannot
|
13 |
understand an action or a jury cannot understand an
|
14 |
action, he said why should that create antitrust
|
15 |
liability for the poor firm? And that I think is a
|
16 |
serious concern.
|
17 |
The profit sacrifice test may sometimes work and
|
18 |
may be appropriate for some actions, but I think it is
|
19 |
dangerous to enshrine it as a general proposition. It
|
20 |
strikes me as much more appropriate to devise tests and
|
21 |
screens that fit particular exclusionary acts,
|
22 |
especially because under Section 2 we have a range of
|
23 |
such widely different behavior that people have attacked
|
24 |
as exclusionary, so many different acts fall under
|
25 |
Section 2, and with each act, I would be concerned as to |
61
1 |
how the legal treatment of the act is creating special
|
2 |
risks for chilling competitive behavior, and that is
|
3 |
going to differ from act to act to act.
|
4 |
So, for example, to pick up on what Herb was
|
5 |
saying, let us suppose you are looking at an industry
|
6 |
that is undergoing rapid technological change, and there
|
7 |
is an exclusionary claim that the way the product was
|
8 |
designed is a problem. Well, you have to worry in that
|
9 |
instance whether you are depriving consumers of a new
|
10 |
product if you attack the firm for its product design,
|
11 |
and that can lead to large losses. So, in that
|
12 |
situation, I might want to give more weight to the
|
13 |
firm's efficiency claim for fear of causing a large dead
|
14 |
weight loss than in other situations.
|
15 |
Let me give you a second example. Let's talk
|
16 |
about the Areeda-Turner test for predatory pricing.
|
17 |
Basically that's a test that says if your price is below
|
18 |
some measure of cost, unless it is, I am not going to
|
19 |
worry. So, the implicit idea is that if you see price
|
20 |
below some measure of cost, that is a big enough
|
21 |
deviation from what we usually think of as profit
|
22 |
maximization that there is something fishy, and the
|
23 |
reason they chose price below a cost as the predation
|
24 |
standard rather than above-cost pricing is because they
|
25 |
were very worried about chilling competition that drives |
62
1 |
price down. So, they were specifically worried in the
|
2 |
context of predatory pricing of erroneous behavior, of
|
3 |
erroneous condemnation, which then would chill
|
4 |
competition, very specialized to the predatory act,
|
5 |
okay? Not a general principle.
|
6 |
If you misread it, what the Areeda-Turner test
|
7 |
said, you could misread it as follows: You could say,
|
8 |
ah, price below cost, the firm is not profit-maximizing.
|
9 |
If the firm is not profit-maximizing, there is something
|
10 |
fishy going on, that's a violation. Now, if you read it
|
11 |
that way, which would be an incorrect way to read it,
|
12 |
that is saying that any deviation from profit-maximizing
|
13 |
behavior would be an antitrust violation, and that would
|
14 |
make me nervous. That is the concern I have about a
|
15 |
profit sacrifice test, because if you are not maximizing
|
16 |
profit, your failure to maximize profit is a sacrifice
|
17 |
of profit, and I do not want get into the situation in
|
18 |
which I claim that firms must be maximizing profit as I
|
19 |
see it or it is an antitrust violation.
|
20 |
Now, you could remedy that. You could say, all
|
21 |
right, I will not say you have to be exactly, I will
|
22 |
give you a margin of error, but that is really my
|
23 |
concern with the test, not that it is not in some
|
24 |
situations useful, but that I would not want to enshrine
|
25 |
it as a general principle. |
63
1 |
Let me now turn to a market definition, which I
|
2 |
was going to say I am sure you have heard a lot about
|
3 |
and probably do not want to hear more about, and I was
|
4 |
glad, though, that Herb did talk about it, because at
|
5 |
least it confirmed in my view that someone else thinks
|
6 |
it deserves still more thought.
|
7 |
But for the antitrust laws, industrial
|
8 |
organization economists would not pay all that much
|
9 |
attention as to how you define a market. I think it is
|
10 |
fair to say that the reason it receives so much
|
11 |
attention is precisely because it has been used as a
|
12 |
screen or a requirement under our antitrust laws, and
|
13 |
that is what gives it prominence.
|
14 |
Now, my own view is it is a very good but crude
|
15 |
tool, and it has this intuition behind it that if there
|
16 |
are lots of rivals, do not worry, and I think that is a
|
17 |
very good common sense rule, but it is hard to apply in
|
18 |
the non-merger context, and there have been attempts to
|
19 |
apply it in the nonmerger context that at least
|
20 |
sometimes strike me as odd. So, what I have seen in a
|
21 |
number of cases is the application of the Merger
|
22 |
Guidelines, and it goes something like this.
|
23 |
Define a market so that a hypothetical
|
24 |
monopolist of those products can raise price 5 percent
|
25 |
above the competitive level, the competitive price. In |
64
1 |
a merger case, it would be the current price, but since
|
2 |
this is not a merger case, we say above the competitive
|
3 |
price. Well, that is a very well-posed question, and in
|
4 |
order to answer it, I have to say, "Okay, well, what is
|
5 |
that competitive price?" Well, I do not know what the
|
6 |
competitive price is. If I knew what the competitive
|
7 |
price is, I could look and see, is the current price
|
8 |
above the competitive price? And if it was, I would
|
9 |
say, yes, it is above. I would not then have to define
|
10 |
a market, take market shares and say, "Ah, you know,
|
11 |
based on all this analysis, you know, 10 is above 5 when
|
12 |
I started, and still, the market shares are so high now,
|
13 |
I conclude 10 is above 5." So, there is a circularity
|
14 |
to it that I find a little troubling. So, you cannot
|
15 |
really directly answer the question, because the
|
16 |
competitive price is not available. So, then, what do
|
17 |
you do?
|
18 |
I think there are several alternatives. Herb
|
19 |
mentioned some of them, and none of them I would say are
|
20 |
completely satisfying. One alternative is to ignore the
|
21 |
problem and simply say, "I am not going to use the
|
22 |
competitive price, I am going to use the existing
|
23 |
price," and Herb sort of indicated that this leads to
|
24 |
the well-known what is called Cellophane fallacy in
|
25 |
which it is possible that you will not find any market |
65
1 |
power at the current price, but you do have market power
|
2 |
because you have already raised the price above the
|
3 |
competitive level. That is one thing you can do, with
|
4 |
its problems.
|
5 |
The second thing you can do is you could say,
|
6 |
"Okay, let me ask the following: Is price above
|
7 |
marginal cost where marginal cost I will use as my proxy
|
8 |
for the competitive price?" Of course, that kind of
|
9 |
replaces one question with the other, what is marginal
|
10 |
cost? Well, maybe you can go out and try and measure
|
11 |
marginal cost. If you had access to firm information,
|
12 |
you could try and sift through accounting information,
|
13 |
you could econometrically try and estimate a cost curve.
|
14 |
It's difficult, okay?
|
15 |
Moreover, suppose you do find prices above
|
16 |
marginal cost. You have to face the realistic
|
17 |
possibility that most markets are not perfectly
|
18 |
competitive. In most markets, price will not equal
|
19 |
marginal cost; therefore, and what you presumably must
|
20 |
mean, is that price deviates a lot from marginal cost if
|
21 |
you are worried about such a deviation. The amount of
|
22 |
deviation, the deviating a lot from marginal cost, has
|
23 |
actually never been articulated that I have seen in a
|
24 |
quantitative way.
|
25 |
Okay, suppose you do not like marginal cost. Is |
66
1 |
there something else you can do? Well, I think there
|
2 |
is. Another thing you can do is you can ask, "Is the
|
3 |
rate of return a firm is earning above the competitive
|
4 |
rate?" We know what the competitive rate of return is.
|
5 |
Is the rate of return the firm is earning above the
|
6 |
competitive rate? This can be a difficult accounting
|
7 |
exercise, or better put, this can be a difficult
|
8 |
economic exercise using accounting data. You would have
|
9 |
to ask over what period of time, how does my answer
|
10 |
change depending on risk, not easy to do necessarily,
|
11 |
likely to create a lot of controversy.
|
12 |
Finally, you could estimate the demand curve
|
13 |
facing the firm, and the benefit of estimating the
|
14 |
demand curve is you could determine the elasticity and
|
15 |
the cross-elasticities that the firm is facing, and that
|
16 |
I think gives you useful information about certain types
|
17 |
of competition. It raises issues over what time period
|
18 |
you estimate the demand curve, but all of those strike
|
19 |
me as things you might be forced to do because the
|
20 |
question you are trying to answer is really a very
|
21 |
difficult one and does not admit a very simple answer.
|
22 |
Since time is running a little short, and I know
|
23 |
we want to leave time for discussion, I will just
|
24 |
mention two topics, and maybe we can come back to it in
|
25 |
the panel discussion. What is the distinction between |
67
1 |
market power and monopoly power? And then second, what
|
2 |
does it mean to have individual market power in an
|
3 |
oligopoly?
|
4 |
Well, let me just conclude, screens can help but
|
5 |
can also become a danger if one loses sight of the
|
6 |
ultimate goal of maximizing consumer welfare. You
|
7 |
should create rules to fit the act, paying special
|
8 |
attention to how the rules applied to this particular
|
9 |
act will chill competition.
|
10 |
The profit sacrifice test worries me a bit for
|
11 |
the reasons I have explained, and I would use it
|
12 |
sometimes but certainly not regard it as a general
|
13 |
principle. With regard to market definition, I still
|
14 |
think it is a useful discipline, especially when you get
|
15 |
to court, for judges and juries to go through, because
|
16 |
it helps structure the analysis, but there is an
|
17 |
inherent lack of precision in its application in Section
|
18 |
2 cases that might be worrisome, and there may well be
|
19 |
cases where its use could be misleading.
|
20 |
Thank you.
|
21 |
(Applause.)
|
22 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Well, thank you to the panel
|
23 |
for very, very interesting perspectives. We have about
|
24 |
20 minutes for panel discussion, and because of airline
|
25 |
schedules, we are going to have to end promptly at the |
68
1 |
appointed hour of 4:00, but I guess let me turn to the
|
2 |
first two speakers, who are agency speakers, and ask
|
3 |
whether you have any comments you would care to offer on
|
4 |
the thoughts from either of the two professors.
|
5 |
CHAIRMAN MAJORAS: Wow, I have a lot that I
|
6 |
could comment on. I thank both of them, because those
|
7 |
were very thoughtful presentations, as we expected, and
|
8 |
I very much appreciate that.
|
9 |
One thing that I was curious about is Herb's
|
10 |
advice that the agencies should step in a bit more in
|
11 |
looking at restraints on innovation, and I was
|
12 |
wondering, Herb, if you had any particular hypothetical
|
13 |
or context involved or if you can be even more critical
|
14 |
of what we have not done in the past, if that is easier
|
15 |
for you, in terms of where we could be looking for such
|
16 |
a thing, because it is true that we constantly talk
|
17 |
about promoting innovation and how important that is to
|
18 |
our work and how important it is that we not inhibit it,
|
19 |
but I find not only in enforcement but in forming policy
|
20 |
and explaining to courts, it is very difficult for
|
21 |
people to get their arms around it, because it is such
|
22 |
an amorphous concept, and I am not sure we are very good
|
23 |
at it.
|
24 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: It is an amorphous concept. In
|
25 |
part, though -- and I think this is an important |
69
1 |
principle -- it is the one place where the IP laws and
|
2 |
the antitrust laws tell the same story. We always talk
|
3 |
about this tension between innovation and competition.
|
4 |
It is hard to defend restraints on innovation when they
|
5 |
are defined properly, and the fact is that the
|
6 |
enforcement record has not given us cause for much hope.
|
7 |
I can think of -- right now, off the top of my head, I
|
8 |
can think of three situations.
|
9 |
One is the air pollution cartel cases of the
|
10 |
1970s. I suspect some of you have not been around long
|
11 |
enough to remember those, but those were challenges by
|
12 |
farmers, class action, brought by agricultural groups to
|
13 |
an alleged agreement among the major automobile
|
14 |
producers for restraining the development of engines
|
15 |
that produce less pollution, and what they wanted to
|
16 |
collect as damages was harm to their crops that accrued
|
17 |
as a result.
|
18 |
Well, just stating it tells you why that
|
19 |
antitrust case is not going to go anywhere, right? You
|
20 |
would have to determine what was lost, you would have to
|
21 |
determine what the impact of these more fuel-efficient
|
22 |
engines would have been, how the farmers might have
|
23 |
evaded it. It would be totally impossible for private
|
24 |
plaintiffs to collect damages in such a case.
|
25 |
Another one is the series of cases, a fairly |
70
1 |
large number of cases, that made it to the circuits
|
2 |
against the cigarette companies in the late 1990s
|
3 |
alleging various cartels to refrain from developing
|
4 |
healthier cigarettes. To the best of my knowledge,
|
5 |
every single one of those cases was dismissed, at least
|
6 |
the ones that went to the circuits, were dismissed on
|
7 |
grounds of standing, causation, provable injury, maybe a
|
8 |
couple of other reasons, but they all had to do with
|
9 |
ability to prove injury.
|
10 |
Then, of course, there is the conclusion in
|
11 |
Judge Jackson's Microsoft opinions, affirmed by the D.C.
|
12 |
Circuit, that Microsoft's attempts to force Intel not to
|
13 |
develop a Java-enabled chip, a chip that could have
|
14 |
spoken multiple-processor languages, something that Bill
|
15 |
Gates feared at the time, was unlawful, and that
|
16 |
complaint allegation has actually been included in a few
|
17 |
of the indirect purchaser cases against Microsoft, and
|
18 |
to the best of my knowledge, not a single plaintiff has
|
19 |
ever collected a dollar for those failures of
|
20 |
innovation.
|
21 |
So, one of the problems is that restraints on
|
22 |
innovation are very likely extraordinarily harmful if
|
23 |
they occur. If so much of our economic growth comes
|
24 |
from innovation, then restraints on innovation could, in
|
25 |
fact, be very harmful. |
71
1 |
Number two, because of the nature of innovation,
|
2 |
because you can never predict where it will go, how much
|
3 |
value it will produce, how much people would be injured
|
4 |
by such a restraint, it is not good grist for private
|
5 |
damages actions under Section 4 of the Clayton Act.
|
6 |
I do not know if that is a satisfactory answer,
|
7 |
but it is just an area where I would like to see more
|
8 |
attention paid.
|
9 |
CHAIRMAN MAJORAS: Well, it does help, because
|
10 |
the other difficulty we have, not only in antitrust but
|
11 |
in forming just good economic policy, is how you balance
|
12 |
innovation incentives generally. I mean, this is the
|
13 |
classic case that I was just discussing earlier with
|
14 |
some folks in the consumer protection arena about
|
15 |
pharmaceutical companies and their incentives to
|
16 |
innovate and how this group of folks just came back from
|
17 |
Europe and said, "Okay, now we need to push in the
|
18 |
United States what other countries are doing," and I
|
19 |
said, "Well, what is going to happen to the incentives
|
20 |
to innovate if every country in the world put caps on
|
21 |
pharmaceutical prices?" But because the harm to
|
22 |
innovation from that is so hard to measure in the policy
|
23 |
arena, people do not necessarily, I think, take it into
|
24 |
account.
|
25 |
MR. BARNETT: Well, I guess a couple of |
72
1 |
reactions. First, I am extraordinarily pleased with the
|
2 |
contributions that the two of you made. They not only
|
3 |
frame some interesting issues and pose some hard
|
4 |
questions, but in some instances, also provided
|
5 |
suggested answers or even policy directions, which is a
|
6 |
great way to start off the hearings, and we very much
|
7 |
appreciate hearing it.
|
8 |
I think, Herb, it is interesting to hear your
|
9 |
views on refusals to deal, whether we should be involved
|
10 |
in that or not, and I guess I was going to ask you, you
|
11 |
have touched on a little bit the issue of innovation,
|
12 |
and given its importance, does that mean we should be
|
13 |
more or less aggressive in intervening in the sense that
|
14 |
is there a greater risk of deterring innovation if you
|
15 |
get involved in some of these areas? I do not know the
|
16 |
answer to that. I just raise it as a thought.
|
17 |
Let me, if I can, pause and ask a -- well, I
|
18 |
will ask you one question, though, before I get to that.
|
19 |
I have always been of slightly two minds. I mean, I
|
20 |
quoted Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, the Joseph
|
21 |
Schumpeter discussion of monopolies, and I have been
|
22 |
taken with this gales of creative destruction imagery.
|
23 |
Now, there is a lot in there that sort of apologizes for
|
24 |
and/or justifies monopolies as good in and of
|
25 |
themselves, and I guess some of hearing your remarks and |
73
1 |
all caused me to want to clarify that I do not agree
|
2 |
with everything that is in that book in terms of
|
3 |
monopoly, but I do agree with the importance of
|
4 |
innovation and not losing sight of that.
|
5 |
But talking about this, you just made a comment
|
6 |
about remedies and a distinction, I think, between
|
7 |
damages and the Government. I would be interested to
|
8 |
hear more of your views on that point, if you think that
|
9 |
would be a good idea, to draw such a distinction.
|
10 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: The distinction between?
|
11 |
MR. BARNETT: Different remedies for
|
12 |
governmental ver -- well, for I would say maybe
|
13 |
injunctive versus damages type relief.
|
14 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: It has always been my opinion,
|
15 |
which the Supreme Court has rejected in California
|
16 |
versus American Stores, that structural remedies should
|
17 |
be the prerogative of the Government. That is not the
|
18 |
law, let's make sure everybody's clear about that. In
|
19 |
California versus American Stores, where the plaintiff
|
20 |
was the Federal Trade Commission, so it's a private -ï½
|
21 |
I'm sorry, was the State -- was the Attorney General of
|
22 |
the State of California, so it was a private party in
|
23 |
this rather unusual way we treat states attorneys
|
24 |
general in antitrust, but I believe structural remedies
|
25 |
ought to be something that only the Government ought to |
74
1 |
do, because they have such extraordinary spillovers.
|
2 |
I mean, we have some confidence that the federal
|
3 |
antitrust agencies, because of their diversity, the
|
4 |
diversity of the industries that they represent, and
|
5 |
because of the high quality of the people that run them,
|
6 |
they are not captured industries, by and large, that we
|
7 |
may not have that level of confidence about
|
8 |
industry-specific agencies.
|
9 |
The one thing we know about private plaintiffs
|
10 |
is that they are always captured, right? Private
|
11 |
lawyers serve their clients. Their clients are
|
12 |
completely self-interested, and as a result, they do not
|
13 |
take overall effects into account, and as a result, my
|
14 |
own view is that structural relief, such as divestiture,
|
15 |
should simply be denied to private plaintiffs.
|
16 |
Is that an answer to your question?
|
17 |
MR. BARNETT: I just was interested in your
|
18 |
perspectives, so thanks.
|
19 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Herb, Dennis had spoken after
|
20 |
you did, so I guess I would ask whether you had any
|
21 |
rejoinder to any of Dennis' comments.
|
22 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: No, and I mean, Dennis knows a
|
23 |
million times more about this market definition stuff
|
24 |
than I do, and so I am very elated that he actually
|
25 |
agreed with me about most of it. I think you can |
75
1 |
develop a few presumptive rules for dealing with market
|
2 |
power issues. For example, where the defendant, the
|
3 |
firm under investigation, faces competition from other
|
4 |
firms that use the same technology and apparently have
|
5 |
the same cost structure, then I think the inference of
|
6 |
competition, competitive pricing, is higher than in a
|
7 |
case like Cellophane. I think what makes the Cellophane
|
8 |
case so extraordinary is that the defendants, DuPont,
|
9 |
plus Sylvania as its licensee, produced Cellophane, but
|
10 |
the stuff that the Government ended up throwing into the
|
11 |
market was brown wrapping paper, tin foil, glassine -ï½
|
12 |
I'm not even sure I know what glassine is -- but these
|
13 |
were things that used different raw materials, they
|
14 |
almost certainly used different technologies for
|
15 |
producing them, and simply to conclude that such things
|
16 |
are in the same market simply because of high observed
|
17 |
cross-elasticity of demand is a very serious error.
|
18 |
It's an error courts continue to make.
|
19 |
There are several cases, for example, that have
|
20 |
concluded that rental videos, films shown in movie
|
21 |
theaters, and films shown on television are all in one
|
22 |
relevant market simply because they make the obvious
|
23 |
observation that if you look at any particular person,
|
24 |
sometimes she goes and rents a video, sometimes she goes
|
25 |
to a theater, sometimes she watches a movie on |
76
1 |
television, without asking the question whether any one
|
2 |
of those technologies is sufficient to hold the other
|
3 |
ones to cost.
|
4 |
I would rather hear Dennis talk about this.
|
5 |
DR. CARLTON: I agree, but I will talk about
|
6 |
something about innovation, if that is all right,
|
7 |
because I think that is an important topic.
|
8 |
It is absolutely right, our standard of living
|
9 |
has increased because of technological change. The
|
10 |
question about what the implication of that is for
|
11 |
antitrust I think is easy to state. It is very hard to
|
12 |
implement. Part of the reason it is hard to implement
|
13 |
is because what we know about innovation and the market
|
14 |
structure that induces innovation is a lot less than
|
15 |
what we know about concentration and the effect of
|
16 |
concentration on raising price.
|
17 |
The evidence, I think most economists would say,
|
18 |
that competition is good for innovation. On the other
|
19 |
hand, if you pushed them and said, "Do you think four to
|
20 |
three makes a big difference when firms are innovating,"
|
21 |
you know, it is pretty hard to find evidence, I think,
|
22 |
and moreover, innovating in what? The idea of, for
|
23 |
example, an innovation market I think is not
|
24 |
particularly helpful except maybe in rare exceptions
|
25 |
like drugs where you can redefine it to be not an |
77
1 |
innovation market, but rather, a future product market.
|
2 |
In drugs, you can look at the pipeline, and you know
|
3 |
what is coming out. So, it is not really an innovation
|
4 |
market as much as it is a prediction of future products.
|
5 |
It is much harder when you are looking at just
|
6 |
firms doing R&D in a general area to say, "What are they
|
7 |
doing R&D on? Is it even on similar products?" And if
|
8 |
you ever go back and do an experiment, like if you look
|
9 |
at major product introductions, who did them, sometimes
|
10 |
the people doing them are often outside the industry,
|
11 |
and no one predicted they would come in. So, I think
|
12 |
the difficulty in this area, when antitrust tries to
|
13 |
deal with it, is the difficulty that you have -- that
|
14 |
anyone would have -- in predicting who is going to be
|
15 |
the innovator. That is why I think it is very hard.
|
16 |
The other reason why I think it is very hard is
|
17 |
innovation markets inherently involve intellectual
|
18 |
property. People want to protect their intellectual
|
19 |
property. There are a lot -- if you look at, you know,
|
20 |
just -- there are some very interesting articles on the
|
21 |
Internet, who has exclusivity rights on certain types of
|
22 |
information that is generated. Restrictions, vertical
|
23 |
restrictions on intellectual property, who can use them,
|
24 |
who cannot use them, are very widespread, and therefore,
|
25 |
if you do have a big success, that will complicate some |
78
1 |
antitrust enforcer's life, because they will say, "Well,
|
2 |
look, a big hit in the vertical restrictions, I am a
|
3 |
little worried," but you have got to go back and step
|
4 |
back and say, "Well, the whole idea of innovating was to
|
5 |
get the returns from this intellectual property, and
|
6 |
they would not have done it if they could not put the
|
7 |
restrictions on it."
|
8 |
So, I think it is a very difficult area. I
|
9 |
think it is made more difficult by our intellectual
|
10 |
property laws, and the problem that I really see arising
|
11 |
is that because so many patents are given for products
|
12 |
that may not be all that valuable, you create the
|
13 |
problem that the property right in a truly valuable
|
14 |
innovation is not that valuable, because now you have to
|
15 |
get cross-licenses from lots of other people, and that
|
16 |
is I think creating a lot of the antitrust problems, and
|
17 |
maybe the best way to fix it is not just through
|
18 |
antitrust but through reforming IP.
|
19 |
CHAIRMAN MAJORAS: As long as we are on the
|
20 |
subject of innovation, in the two minutes we have left,
|
21 |
does either of you have an opinion on the recent
|
22 |
phenomenon that we are seeing in the patent area known
|
23 |
as patent trolls, people who go out and buy up what some
|
24 |
people might term useless patents -- I don't know if you
|
25 |
can go that far -- and some of those people doing it, in |
79
1 |
fact, as I understand it are plaintiff's lawyers, and
|
2 |
then wait until somebody creates an invention, and that
|
3 |
bundle of patents might look, you know, like it could
|
4 |
have been infringed, maybe it is, maybe it isn't, and
|
5 |
then pounce and say, "Okay, now you owe me really high
|
6 |
royalties."
|
7 |
And there are obviously many different
|
8 |
variations on this theme, you know, those that have zero
|
9 |
interest in ever making anything or innovating I think
|
10 |
are the ones that people refer to as patent trolls. Do
|
11 |
you have any comment on whether that is injuring
|
12 |
competition or something that any of us should be
|
13 |
worried about?
|
14 |
DR. HOVENKAMP: Well, my reaction to that is
|
15 |
that whether it's good or bad, it is fundamentally not
|
16 |
an antitrust problem. I mean, in order to be an
|
17 |
antitrust problem, it either has to monopolize the
|
18 |
market or create a dangerous probability of doing so or
|
19 |
else it has to be an agreement that restrains trade, and
|
20 |
simply surprising people with a patent and claiming high
|
21 |
royalties in and of itself does not do that.
|
22 |
Now, that does not mean if it were not used in
|
23 |
conjunction with some other practice, it couldn't sum up
|
24 |
to an antitrust violation.
|
25 |
DR. CARLTON: I would just add, I basically |
80
1 |
agree with what Herb said. I think that it is a problem
|
2 |
for reform of the patent laws, and there are at least
|
3 |
two thoughts I have. The first is that one of the
|
4 |
things that gives a troll great power is the ability to
|
5 |
get an exclusion right, and you might want to encourage
|
6 |
the courts to give the surprised infringer time to
|
7 |
invent around the patent if that is possible, and that
|
8 |
can get rid of sometimes a lot of the pressure.
|
9 |
The other question you can ask is, are they ever
|
10 |
intending to use this themselves and implement it, and
|
11 |
that may influence how you treat them.
|
12 |
Having said that, you know, an economist always
|
13 |
has two sides to a story. A patent -- you may call them
|
14 |
a patent troll, but the flip side is I'm an inventor,
|
15 |
maybe I want to give my invention to someone else to
|
16 |
figure out, you know, all the licensing problems. So, I
|
17 |
mean, there is a flip side.
|
18 |
CHAIRMAN MAJORAS: Yes.
|
19 |
MR. BARNETT: Can I just ask quickly if based on
|
20 |
your remarks, Dennis, if you would be willing to get
|
21 |
into a locked room with Greg Werden for a session with a
|
22 |
tape recorder and we could solve nine out of every ten
|
23 |
Section 2 problems.
|
24 |
DR. CARLTON: I would be delighted.
|
25 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Dennis, if I could I guess ask |
81
1 |
one last question in the two minutes we have, you had
|
2 |
thrown out a teaser at the end about the distinction
|
3 |
between market power and monopoly power, an issue that
|
4 |
was of some interest to the staff, although we had not
|
5 |
quite posed it, and I might add, it was something I
|
6 |
recalled George Stigler having denied as a distinction
|
7 |
in the Data General case about 20 years ago, although
|
8 |
the Ninth Circuit disagreed with that view. So, perhaps
|
9 |
there is a distinction after all.
|
10 |
Did you have in mind something more than just
|
11 |
quantum? Is it a character of the difference or -ï½
|
12 |
DR. CARLTON: Yes, actually, it is in my
|
13 |
textbook, so I know it very well. One definition of
|
14 |
market power could simply be that price is in excess of
|
15 |
marginal cost. That is a logical definition. Whether
|
16 |
you want to use it in a court, you know, I think that is
|
17 |
a different question. You might want to define it by
|
18 |
how much before you say it is something that triggers
|
19 |
some action, but you can distinguish market power from
|
20 |
monopoly power by saying monopoly power is not just
|
21 |
price in excess of marginal cost, but also, profits in
|
22 |
excess of the competitive rate of return. So, that is
|
23 |
at least a logical distinction.
|
24 |
I should say in the third edition of my book, I
|
25 |
dropped that paragraph, because no one seemed to pay |
82
1 |
attention to it. Now, I change a lot of things when I
|
2 |
revise my book, and most people never comment, but on
|
3 |
this, I did get some comments, and people said, "We
|
4 |
thought it was useful," even though I had never seen
|
5 |
anyone -- I was unaware anyone had cited it, and I think
|
6 |
it is useful, so I have put it back in. Now, so, that
|
7 |
is an answer.
|
8 |
Now, whether that should be what courts use when
|
9 |
they are deciding on an exclusionary act is a slightly
|
10 |
different question, because I think courts really should
|
11 |
be asking a slightly different question, which is, let
|
12 |
us suppose you are talking about exclusive dealing. I
|
13 |
don't really care about what the rate of return is, I
|
14 |
don't think. I think what a court is saying is if you
|
15 |
are engaged in an act and there are other
|
16 |
characteristics of the market that make that act have a
|
17 |
greater effect than if you didn't, say, have as large a
|
18 |
market share, then I am going to be worried about that,
|
19 |
and that really does not have to do with rates of
|
20 |
return.
|
21 |
So, you know, I can see why courts could be
|
22 |
asking are the characteristics of the market that make
|
23 |
the exclusionary act under discussion much more a
|
24 |
competitive concern than not, whether that -- I don't
|
25 |
know that that necessarily corresponds to the |
83
1 |
distinction I gave you. The distinction I gave you does
|
2 |
strike me as a sensible economic distinction.
|
3 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: Well, thank you, and with that,
|
4 |
we are out of time. Let me ask you to join me in
|
5 |
thanking the panel for a great presentation.
|
6 |
(Applause.)
|
7 |
MR. BLUMENTHAL: We look forward to receiving
|
8 |
your comments in the months ahead. We hope to see you
|
9 |
Thursday and in the hearings to come. Thank you all.
|
10 |
(Whereupon, at 4:00 p.m., the hearing was
|
11 |
concluded.)
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
|
16 |
|
17 |
|
18 |
|
19 |
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
|
84
1 |
C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F R E P O R T E R
|
2 |
DOCKET/FILE NUMBER: P062106
|
3 |
CASE TITLE: SECTION 2 HEARING
|
4 |
DATE: JUNE 20, 2006
|
5 |
|
6 |
I HEREBY CERTIFY that the transcript contained
|
7 |
herein is a full and accurate transcript of the notes
|
8 |
taken by me at the hearing on the above cause before the
|
9 |
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION to the best of my knowledge and
|
10 |
belief.
|
11 |
|
12 |
DATED: 7/5/06
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
|
16 |
SUSANNE BERGLING, RMR-CLR
|
17 |
|
18 |
C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F P R O O F R E A D E R
|
19 |
|
20 |
I HEREBY CERTIFY that I proofread the transcript
|
21 |
for accuracy in spelling, hyphenation, punctuation and
|
22 |
format.
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
DIANE QUADE |
|