Participant Presentations And Session Transcript For June 20
1
1 | UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION |
2 | and |
3 | UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE |
4 | |
5 | |
6 | |
7 | SHERMAN ACT SECTION 2 JOINT HEARING |
8 | REFUSALS TO DEAL PANEL |
9 | TUESDAY, JULY 18, 2006 |
10 | |
11 | |
12 | |
13 | |
14 | HELD AT: |
15 |
UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION |
16 | CONFERENCE CENTER CONFERENCE ROOM C |
17 | 601 NEW JERSEY AVENUE, N.W. |
18 | WASHINGTON, D.C. |
19 | 1:30 P.M. to 5:13 P.M. |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | Reported and transcribed by: |
25 | Sally Jo Bowling |
2
1 | MODERATOR: |
2 |
ALDEN F. ABBOTT |
3 | Federal Trade Commission |
4 |
J. BRUCE McDONALD |
5 | Department of Justice |
6 | |
7 | PANELISTS: |
8 | |
9 | William J. Kolasky |
10 | R. Hewitt Pate |
11 | Robert Pitofsky |
12 | Steven C. Salop |
13 | Thomas F. Walton |
14 | Mark Whitener |
15 | |
16 | |
17 | |
18 | |
19 | |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
3
1 | C O N T E N T S |
2 | |
3 | Introduction |
4 | |
5 | Presentations: |
6 | William J. Kolasky |
7 | Robert Pitofsky |
8 | R. Hewitt Pate |
9 | Steven C. Salop |
10 | Thomas F. Walton |
11 | Mark Whitener |
12 | |
13 | Moderated Discussion |
14 | |
15 | Adjournment |
16 | |
17 | |
18 | |
19 | |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
4
1 | P R O C E E D I N G S |
2 | - - - - - |
3 | MR. ABBOTT: Good afternoon. I'm Alden Abbott, |
4 | Associate Director of the Bureau of Competition of the |
5 | Federal Trade Commission. I wish to join my |
6 | co-moderator, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for |
7 | Antitrust, Bruce McDonald, to welcome you to today's |
8 | session of the FTC/Justice Department hearings on the |
9 | antitrust implications of single firm conduct. |
10 | This is the fourth session in the ongoing |
11 | hearings. Prior sessions involved an introductory |
12 | overview of the topic, and sessions on predatory pricing |
13 | and buying. |
14 | Before we start, I need to cover a few |
15 | housekeeping matters. First, please turn off cell |
16 | phones, Blackberries and any other electronic devices. |
17 | Second, and most important, the restrooms are outside |
18 | the double doors and across the lobby. There are signs |
19 | to guide you. Third, in the unlikely event building |
20 | alarms go off, please proceed calmly and quickly as |
21 | instructed. If we must leave the building, go out the |
22 | New Jersey Avenue entrance by the guard's desk, follow |
23 | the crowd of FTC employees to a gathering point and |
24 | await further instruction. Finally, we request you not |
25 | make comments or ask questions during the session. |
1 | Thank you. |
2 | Now, before turning the podium over to my |
3 | colleague, Bruce McDonald, I'll briefly mention, prior |
4 | to giving more fullsome introductions, we're honored to |
5 | have six of the most distinguished leading lights of |
6 | antitrust here today. Bill Kolasky, Wilmer Cutler & |
7 | Pickering, former deputy assistant Attorney General; |
8 | professor and former dean and FTC chairman Robert |
9 | Pitofsky of Georgetown University Law Center, and Arnold |
10 | & Porter; Hew Pate, former assistant Attorney General |
11 | and currently partner at Hunton & Williams; Professor |
12 | Steven Salop, Georgetown University Law Center, |
13 | Consultant CRA International, and also an FTC alumnus; |
14 | Thomas Walton, director economic policy analysis, |
15 | General Motors Corporation, and also an FTC alumnus; and |
16 | Mark Whitener, senior counsel, competition law and |
17 | policy, General Electric Company, and also an FTC |
18 | alumnus. So we see there's a certain FTC flavor to the |
19 | distinguished speakers here today, but I won't say |
20 | anything more about that. |
21 | Bruce? |
22 | MR. McDONALD: If counting, there is a distinct |
23 | DOJ flavor on the panel, too. Let me say my welcome to |
24 | the joint DOJ/FTC single firm conduct hearings. The |
25 | hearings opened on June 20 with an overview of the |
1 | issues presented by single firm conduct and the |
2 | enforcement of Sherman Act Section 2. At the opening |
3 | hearings, both FTC Chairman Debbie Majoras and antitrust |
4 | AAG Tom Barnett emphasized the challenges in identifying |
5 | what conduct threatens long-term harm to competition and |
6 | the importance of developing clear rules to guide |
7 | business and that both underdeterrence and |
8 | overenforcement need to be considered. |
9 | Today is our fourth session, and our third day |
10 | of hearings. Our topic today is refusals to deal, which |
11 | is hard fought ground in the single firm conduct debate. |
12 | Our distinguished panel will focus on the circumstances |
13 | in which a firm's unilateral refusal to deal with a |
14 | competitor violates or should or should not violate |
15 | Section 2, addressing issues raised by Colgate, Otter |
16 | Tail, Kodak, Aspen, Microsoft and Trinko. The views of |
17 | our panelists have been influential in this debate, and |
18 | we appreciate the time that they have devoted to these |
19 | hearings. |
20 | Let me outline the agenda for you this |
21 | afternoon. Each of the panelists will take about 15 |
22 | minutes to outline the issues and things critical, then |
23 | we'll take a 15-minute break, and then we'll dig deeper |
24 | into a discussion, giving the panelists an opportunity |
25 | to respond to each other's presentations and to consider |
1 | several propositions and hypotheticals that we hope will |
2 | initiate further discussion. The hearing will end at |
3 | about 5:00. |
4 | Let me turn the podium back to Alden Abbott to |
5 | introduce the presenters. Thank you. |
6 | MR. ABBOTT: Thank you, Bruce. Our first |
7 | speaker, Bill Kolasky, is cochair of Wilmer Hale Cutler |
8 | & Pickering, actually Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale & |
9 | Dorr, it's a problem with all of these law firm mergers. |
10 | He co-chairs the firm's antitrust and competition |
11 | practice group. He's also had a distinguished record of |
12 | public service. From September 2001 through December |
13 | 2002, he served as Deputy Assistant Attorney General for |
14 | International Antitrust at the Justice Department, at |
15 | which time he spoke out vociferously on the benefits of |
16 | an economic approach to antitrust in the international |
17 | forum and was very active in helping launch the |
18 | International Competition Network. His private practice |
19 | covers a full range of antitrust matters and Bill has |
20 | also taught antitrust law at American University, and he |
21 | speaks regularly on antitrust topics. |
22 | Bill? |
23 | MR. KOLASKY: Thank you very much, Alden, and |
24 | thank you, Bruce, as well, for inviting me to |
25 | participate in this. I have to say that it's somewhat |
1 | intimidating to be the first speaker in this afternoon's |
2 | session, especially given that I think all of the other |
3 | members of the panel, and probably most of you in the |
4 | audience, have thought longer and harder about these |
5 | issues than I have. |
6 | The other disadvantage of speaking first, of |
7 | course, is that everyone gets the chance to shoot at |
8 | what I'm about to say. I do think that I have, perhaps, |
9 | one comparative advantage, and only one, I'm going to |
10 | try to take full advantage of that, and that is my age, |
11 | and therefore, in fact, I've been doing this a lot |
12 | longer than most of the people in the room. |
13 | I've titled my talk refusals to deal with |
14 | rivals, because I want to distinguish very clearly |
15 | between refusals to deal with competitors as opposed to |
16 | refusals to deal with customers. |
17 | Refusals to deal with customers, I think involve |
18 | very different competitive concerns. The exclusionary |
19 | effects are more likely to be direct and immediate, and |
20 | there's a long line of cases running from Lorain Journal |
21 | to Dentsply that deal with refusals to deal with |
22 | customers. As I understand it, we're not here to |
23 | discuss those, we're here today to discuss refusals to |
24 | deal with rivals. |
25 | In structuring my remarks, I felt that I made |
1 | one of the classic rookie mistakes, I have far too many |
2 | slides and so I'm going to have to skip around somewhat, |
3 | but I wanted to touch on five basic topics. The first |
4 | is the pre-Trinko refusal to deal cases. Next I want to |
5 | talk briefly about Trinko. Then I want to talk about |
6 | the current dialogue that is going on, among others, |
7 | between Steve Salop and my partner, Doug Melamed over |
8 | the various standards for applying Section 2 generally. |
9 | I then want to stake out my own position as to what |
10 | analytical framework I think should be applied to |
11 | Section 2, and it's basically a step-wise rule reason |
12 | approach, applying the California Dental sliding scale. |
13 | And then I propose to talk about how they apply to |
14 | refusals to deal with rivals. |
15 | Focusing first on the pre-Trinko refusal to deal |
16 | law, there are basically, I think, four distinct lines |
17 | of cases. The first line of cases, and the oldest, are |
18 | the vertical integration cases from the 1970s and early |
19 | 80s. The second line of cases are the essential |
20 | facilities cases, largely from the 1980s and early |
21 | 1990s. The third line of cases are the intellectual |
22 | property cases, most recently the Federal Circuit's |
23 | decision in CSU. And then finally there is Aspen, which |
24 | because it's a Supreme Court case, I think deserves |
25 | particular mention and focus. |
1 | In the debate over refusals to deal, I've been |
2 | surprised in the recent publications how little |
3 | attention has been paid to the vertical integration |
4 | cases, which is really where a lot of the law in this |
5 | area was first developed. And when you go back and read |
6 | those cases, I believe, at least, that the analytical |
7 | framework that they used is a surprisingly sound one, |
8 | given that these cases were decided largely in the 1970s |
9 | and early 80s as we were just emerging from what Doug |
10 | Ginsburg refers to as the dark ages of antitrust. |
11 | Many of the cases, some of which my firm was |
12 | involved in, involved refusals to deal by monopoly |
13 | newspapers that were vertically integrating into |
14 | distribution. The obvious reason why these papers were |
15 | vertically integrating into distribution was to get |
16 | around the problem that was created by Albrecht, by the |
17 | rule that maximum resale price by principles is per se |
18 | unlawful. Since it was obviously efficient to have a |
19 | single delivery person covering each block, newspapers |
20 | found themselves basically with the situation where they |
21 | were dealing with independent dealers, giving those |
22 | dealers a monopoly, and they had no way to prevent those |
23 | dealers from charging monopoly prices higher than what |
24 | the newspaper itself would have charged. |
25 | It's not surprising, therefore, that the cases |
1 | for the most part ended up with the courts ruling in |
2 | favor of the newspapers and upholding their refusal to |
3 | continue to deal with independent dealers and vertically |
4 | integrating into the distribution themselves. |
5 | When you go back and read the cases, and most |
6 | notable the Paschall versus Kansas City Star decision, |
7 | in 1984, which was an en banc decision of the Eighth |
8 | Circuit, what you find is that the courts applied |
9 | essentially a Section 1 rule of reason standard in |
10 | evaluating these unilateral refusals to deal. In that |
11 | sense, I would argue that they are in a way ahead of |
12 | their time, because it was really not until the |
13 | Microsoft decision in 2001 that a court of appeals here |
14 | in the D.C. Circuit affirmatively embraced the rule of |
15 | reason as the applicable standard for Section 2. |
16 | Applying that Section 1 rule of reason |
17 | framework, the Eighth Circuit found that the |
18 | anticompetitive effects from the alleged loss of |
19 | potential competition as claimed by the plaintiffs were |
20 | slight, and that the newspaper had offered several |
21 | legitimate business reasons for its decision to |
22 | vertically integrate into distribution. |
23 | One of the most interesting things about the |
24 | case is that the newspaper did not rely on the argument |
25 | that I relied on in my opening remarks about this case, |
1 | namely the need to get around Albrecht. Instead, the |
2 | newspaper focused on the desire to be more responsive to |
3 | subscribers and have more uniform pricing in order to |
4 | facilitate advertising. |
5 | Quite frankly, those are relatively weak |
6 | justifications for what the newspaper was doing, and yet |
7 | nevertheless the court held without scrutinizing those |
8 | justifications very closely, that they outweighed the |
9 | rather minimal showing of anticompetitive injury that |
10 | the plaintiffs had made. |
11 | One of the key factors in causing the court to |
12 | reach that decision was its determination -- and this is |
13 | consistent with what I said earlier on Albrecht -- that |
14 | a vertically integrated newspaper was likely to charge |
15 | lower prices than if you had unintegrated monopolists at |
16 | both the publication level and the distribution level. |
17 | The essential facilities cases, I'm going to |
18 | skip over lightly, because others are going to be |
19 | speaking about those in more detail. There are two |
20 | things that I want to note about them. The mother of |
21 | essential facilities cases, at least with respect to |
22 | unilateral conduct, is of course the Supreme Court's |
23 | decision, Otter Tail. What people often don't comment |
24 | on is that that was a decision in the mid-1970s, again, |
25 | as we were just emerging from the dark ages, it was a |
1 | four to three opinion written by Justice Douglas, who |
2 | probably wrote more decisions that antitrust lawyers now |
3 | try to distance themselves from than almost any other |
4 | Justice. |
5 | The other thing that's important about the key |
6 | essential facilities cases such as Otter Tail and the |
7 | Seventh Circuit's decision in MCI v. AT&T is that these |
8 | cases do not involve just a simple refusal to deal by a |
9 | monopolist. Rather, they were cases in which the |
10 | monopolist had engaged in a whole pattern of conduct |
11 | that was designed to exclude rivals from these monopoly |
12 | markets. |
13 | The next line of cases, as I mentioned, are the |
14 | cases involving intellectual property rights, the First |
15 | Circuit's decision in Data General, the Ninth Circuit's |
16 | decision in Kodak and the Federal Circuit's decision in |
17 | CSU. There's been an enormous amount of ink spilled |
18 | about these decisions, including a very good article by |
19 | Hew Pate, and I'm sure Hew will have something to say |
20 | about this line of cases. |
21 | The important point, I think, that one draws |
22 | from these line of cases is the Second Circuit's |
23 | recognition, which was endorsed even by the Ninth |
24 | Circuit, that an author's or inventor's desire to |
25 | exclude others from the use of copyrighted or patented |
1 | work is a presumptively valid business justification for |
2 | any immediate harm to consumers that might result from a |
3 | refusal to license. |
4 | The debate really, then, is between the Ninth |
5 | Circuit and the Federal Circuit under what's necessary |
6 | to rebut that presumption, with the Federal Circuit |
7 | taking probably the most restrictive view that the |
8 | presumption is virtually irrebuttable unless there is |
9 | additional conduct beyond just the simple refusal to |
10 | license, such as an illegal tie, fraud on the Patent & |
11 | Trademark Office, or sham litigation. And I think that |
12 | is consistent, in fact, with cases like MCI and Otter |
13 | Tail, if you go back and read those decisions. |
14 | That brings me to Aspen Ski, which was the first |
15 | serious effort, I would argue, by the Supreme Court to |
16 | deal with the question of what standards should apply to |
17 | refusals by monopolists to deal with its rivals, and the |
18 | key points here that I want to bring out are that the |
19 | Court focused not just on the impact on the rival, but |
20 | also on the impact of the refusal on consumers, and the |
21 | Court also made it clear that what it was looking at |
22 | under Section 2 was whether the defendant was seeking to |
23 | exclude rivals on some basis other than efficiency, that |
24 | is other than through competition on the merits. And I |
25 | think that's a very important strand that needs to be |
1 | kept in mind as one thinks about these cases. |
2 | The other point that's important to make about |
3 | Aspen requires really looking at the facts of the case |
4 | and what the conduct was. Again, as in Otter Tail and |
5 | MCI, the conduct was not a simple refusal to deal. |
6 | There was a lot of other conduct going on there, |
7 | including to me most significantly the fact that Ski Co. |
8 | discontinued its own three-day, three mountain pass so |
9 | that the only way somebody could get a discount on a |
10 | multi-day, multi-mountain pass was to buy a six-day |
11 | pass, and that meant that if the vacationer wanted to |
12 | ski the Highlands, they almost certainly had to pay |
13 | twice, both for the day ticket to the Highlands and the |
14 | six-day pass to the Highlands. The other thing that's |
15 | important is that, while the court described Ski Co.'s |
16 | justification as pretextual, the court also gave fairly |
17 | close scrutiny to those justifications before reaching |
18 | that conclusion. |
19 | Trinko, I'm not going to spend very much time |
20 | on, because others are going to spend a lot of time on |
21 | it. The key message point, of course, is that the Court |
22 | appeared to adopt a very restrictive view as to when a |
23 | monopolist might have a refusal to deal and cooperate |
24 | with its rivals. |
25 | Because I'm running out of time, I'm going to |
1 | jump ahead to the contending standards. As I say, there |
2 | are basically three sets of contending standards out |
3 | there now, in this area. One is what I would call the |
4 | Section 2 rule of reason approach, taken by the D.C. |
5 | Circuit in Microsoft and by the Eighth Circuit in |
6 | Paschall, the profit sacrifice or no economic sense test |
7 | that Greg Werden from the Justice Department and Doug |
8 | Melamed have been advocating and I think Hew from time |
9 | to time has advocated it as well, and then finally the |
10 | essential facilities doctrine. |
11 | Again, because we're running out of time, I'm |
12 | going to skip ahead to my proposed synthesis. I come |
13 | down, as I think about this, in favor of basically the |
14 | Microsoft step-wise rule of reason test for exclusionary |
15 | conduct. I think that test involves, as the court said, |
16 | basically four steps. First, an examination of whether |
17 | the monopolist's conduct, in this case its refusal to |
18 | deal, had the requisite anticompetitive effect. |
19 | Second, a requirement that the monopolist, if |
20 | the plaintiff establishes a prima facie case, proffer |
21 | some nonpretextual procompetitive justification for its |
22 | action, and if it does so, the burden then slides back |
23 | to the plaintiffs to rebut that justification. And it's |
24 | only if the plaintiff meets that burden that you move on |
25 | to the fourth and final stage, which is balancing. |
1 | That's the reason why I don't particularly like to have |
2 | this test described as the balancing test, because in |
3 | fact, you rarely reach the fourth balancing step in the |
4 | test. |
5 | In applying the step-wise rule of reason under |
6 | Section 2, I would argue that the courts should do just |
7 | as they do in Section 1, and as I believe they do in |
8 | practice under Section 2, and that is apply a sliding |
9 | scale. That is to say, as Justice Souter wrote in |
10 | California Dental, what is required is an enquiry need |
11 | for the case. In other words, the stronger the evidence |
12 | of anticompetitive harm, the closer the scrutiny of |
13 | proper justifications. |
14 | Going back to, I'm not sure how to go to a |
15 | previous slide, I want to go back to Microsoft for a |
16 | second, because -- I'm sorry about this. I hope I get a |
17 | minute for my technological ineptitude. Here we go. |
18 | In Microsoft, if you read the decision closely, |
19 | you will see that the court, in fact, applied exactly |
20 | this kind of a sliding scale. When it came to the |
21 | license restrictions that Microsoft imposed on OEMs, the |
22 | court subjected Microsoft's proposed justifications to |
23 | very close scrutiny. When it came, however, to the |
24 | integration of Internet Explorer and Windows, the court |
25 | expressed at the very outset of that section of its |
1 | opinion a general deference to the dominant firm's |
2 | product design decisions, and the only reason it found |
3 | Microsoft's conduct unlawful, to the extent it did, is |
4 | that Microsoft proffered no justification whatever for |
5 | its decisions. |
6 | What I found interesting, and I credit this to |
7 | one of our summer associates, Tian Mayimin, who is in |
8 | the audience today, is how similar the California Dental |
9 | sliding scale approach to the rule of reason is to what |
10 | the courts do in the constitutional area, both under the |
11 | First Amendment, and under equal protection, where over |
12 | the years, what began back in the 1960s as a balancing |
13 | test, has evolved instead to three different levels of |
14 | review, strict scrutiny, intermediate scrutiny, and weak |
15 | scrutiny, in which the degree to which the court |
16 | subjects the proffered justifications for the |
17 | government's action depends on how objectionable the |
18 | conduct is in terms of First Amendment principles and/or |
19 | equal protection. |
20 | And I would suggest that the analogy in the |
21 | antitrust area is to the test we use for determining |
22 | whether or not the proper justifications justify the |
23 | conduct at issue. We often talk about needing to find |
24 | that the conduct is reasonably necessary, that's a |
25 | relatively tough standard. |
1 | A more relaxed standard would be to find that |
2 | it's reasonably related, and an even more relaxed |
3 | standard would be that it's plausibly related, which is |
4 | the standard the Supreme Court adopted in Broadcast |
5 | Music in determining whether or not the per se rule |
6 | should be applied. I would argue that you could use |
7 | that same sliding scale under Section 2, where the |
8 | degree of scrutiny depends on the nature of the conduct |
9 | in question. |
10 | Why do I prefer the rule of reason approach to |
11 | the profit sacrifice test? I think basically four |
12 | simple reasons. One is that it focuses directly on |
13 | competitive effects, whereas the profit sacrifice test |
14 | focuses more on the effect on the monopolist, rather |
15 | than the effect on consumers. Second, because, as Steve |
16 | Salop has pointed out quite persuasively, exclusionary |
17 | conduct can be profitable, even in the short-term, and |
18 | in fact, if you read the facts of Aspen Ski, I suspect |
19 | that even there, Aspen's conduct was profitable in the |
20 | short-term, even though it degraded the attractiveness |
21 | of its product to the skiers, and that's because it |
22 | would have shifted skiers from Highlands to the Aspen |
23 | mountains, thereby increasing its revenues, i.e., even |
24 | if the total number of skiers coming to the Aspen area |
25 | generally declined. |
1 | Third, at least as I have read the articles, the |
2 | profit sacrifice test, as it has been articulated, |
3 | doesn't acknowledge the need to calibrate the degree of |
4 | scrutiny of the business justifications based on the |
5 | strength of the evidence of competitive injury. Doug |
6 | Melamed, for example, has argued that one can look at a |
7 | refusal to deal as basically a make-or-buy decision, and |
8 | that it should be unlawful if it would be more |
9 | profitable for the monopolist to buy the downstream |
10 | services than to vertically integrate them. I would |
11 | argue that that is too high a degree of scrutiny for the |
12 | courts to impose on those kinds of decisions. |
13 | And then finally, there is no obvious reason why |
14 | courts should be any less able to evaluate competitive |
15 | injury and business justifications in a Section 2 versus |
16 | a Section 1 setting. What should differ is how strictly |
17 | they scrutinize the justifications, not the test that |
18 | they apply. |
19 | Thank you. |
20 | (Applause.) |
21 | MR. ABBOTT: Thank you, Bill. Now I have the |
22 | honor of introducing Robert Pitofsky, a name known |
23 | certainly to all of you and throughout the antitrust |
24 | world, former FTC Chairman, Commissioner and Bureau of |
25 | Consumer Protection Director, distinguished background |
1 | in private practice, currently of counsel at Arnold & |
2 | Porter, and of course very distinguished academic, |
3 | former NYU law professor, then dean of Georgetown Law |
4 | School, currently Sheehy Professor in Antitrust and |
5 | Trade Regulation Law at Georgetown University Law |
6 | Center. His writings are many. He has co-authored, |
7 | Cases and Materials on Trade Regulations, which is in |
8 | its fifth edition, one of the most widely used antitrust |
9 | and trade regulation case books. |
10 | Bob Pitofsky. |
11 | (Applause.) |
12 | MR. PITOFSKY: Thank you all and good afternoon. |
13 | It's great to be back at the FTC, and to see that the |
14 | DOJ and the FTC are continuing the tradition of taking |
15 | on the toughest issues and addressing them not |
16 | necessarily by litigation, but by hearings like this. |
17 | And I do regard the definition of exclusion under |
18 | Section 2, and refusals to deal in particular, as about |
19 | the toughest issues that an antitrust lawyer is required |
20 | to face today. |
21 | I'm going to do three things here. One, I want |
22 | to put refusals to deal in a broader context, and I |
23 | believe that's what Trinko's majority opinion was |
24 | designed to do. Secondly, I want to say a little bit |
25 | about the general universal test that Bill talked about |
1 | in such an interesting way. I just have one question, |
2 | because I agree with virtually all that he had to say. |
3 | And then I'm going to discuss, the antitrust concept of |
4 | essential facilities and whether essential facilities is |
5 | such an unwise doctrine that it ought to be abolished. |
6 | Let's start with Trinko, because I don't think |
7 | Trinko is just about the facts of that particular case. |
8 | It was a unanimous opinion. I would have voted to |
9 | reverse the Second Circuit, too. I had no problem with |
10 | the holding. It's the dicta in Trinko that went on and |
11 | on and on, and I'm disappointed that other judges on the |
12 | court didn't concur separately, and write that they were |
13 | not ready to go along with all this additional talk. |
14 | More broadly, I think Justice Scalia was saying, very |
15 | directly, that he's uncomfortable, he's skeptical about |
16 | enforcement of Section 2, and thinks that Section 2, |
17 | certainly compared to Section 1 of the Sherman Act, |
18 | causes more harm than good. His reasons were that there |
19 | are too many false positives, as he put it, in Section |
20 | 2, that Section 2 enforcement tends to chill the |
21 | incentives of aggressive and innovative companies, that |
22 | he's uncomfortable with a generalist antitrust court |
23 | taking on issues like those raised by Section 2 |
24 | enforcement, and the remedy, especially with refusal to |
25 | deal, is at least difficult and may be impossible. |
1 | Let me just go through these. First of all, |
2 | what is this false positives thing? I didn't agree with |
3 | the Second Circuit either, but I didn't conclude that |
4 | Section 2 raised many false positives as a result of |
5 | that wrong decision. Is the meaning that lots of |
6 | Section 2 cases have been brought by the government and |
7 | private parties and have been thrown out on motions to |
8 | dismiss, not stating a legitimate case? Well, let's go |
9 | back and review the record: Lorain Journal, Walker |
10 | Process, Otter Tail, Kodak, Xerox, Aspen, and Intel. |
11 | The plaintiff won every one of those Section 2 cases. |
12 | Now you might say yes, but they were false positives, |
13 | Otter Tail should have been decided the other way. But |
14 | the Supreme Court decided Otter Tail in favor of the |
15 | plaintiff, and the Court has not subsequently overruled |
16 | the decision. |
17 | Now there have been mistakes that have been |
18 | made, but the idea that there's just constant false |
19 | positives in Section 2 enforcement, I don't know where |
20 | that's coming from. |
21 | Second, Section 2 enforcement chills incentives |
22 | for innovative companies. I'm agnostic on that. Maybe |
23 | that's true. Just show me the data. Show me anyone who |
24 | has done a study which demonstrates that once a company |
25 | is aware that it may have to engage in mandatory |
1 | licensing, at a reasonable royalty, they cut back on |
2 | their investment in innovation. I haven't seen it. But |
3 | I'm uncomfortable with all these ex cathedra statements |
4 | that that would occur. |
5 | Third, uncomfortable because generalist |
6 | antitrust judges are deciding these cases? Well, who |
7 | are the judges deciding joint venture cases? Merger |
8 | cases? Rule of reason cases? They all involve |
9 | trade-offs, just like Section 2; they all involve |
10 | generalist judges. Up until now, I thought U.S. |
11 | antitrust was doing a pretty good job, and I'm not |
12 | troubled that district judges are making a botch out of |
13 | these trials. |
14 | On refusal to deal, if you mandate disclosure, |
15 | you have not just the decision about mandating, you have |
16 | a decision about at what royalty, what terms, what |
17 | timing, and so forth. And there's no question, that |
18 | complicates this issue immensely. It was worked out in |
19 | Aspen Ski, it was worked out in Otter Tail, although |
20 | there was a Federal Power Commission at the time Otter |
21 | Tail was decided to help to work out the remedy. The |
22 | question for me is, given the fact that the remedies in |
23 | these cases are difficult, do you throw up your hands |
24 | and say, impossible, therefore the monopolist can do |
25 | anything it wants, or do you try to work out the best |
1 | remedy you can? Sometimes the remedy is easy. Perhaps |
2 | the monopolist has already been licensing other people, |
3 | but refuses to license potential competitors. It's not |
4 | common, but it happens. |
5 | Sometimes the monopolist has been selling in |
6 | other markets at a price it was comfortable with. |
7 | That's the beginning of negotiation for this remedy. I |
8 | grant immediately, it's difficult, the question is, does |
9 | that mean free reign for the monopolist? |
10 | Second, on proposals for a general rule, first |
11 | of all, I want to compliment Hew Pate, now Bill Kolasky, |
12 | Steve Salop, Doug Melamed, Greg Werden, all of whom are |
13 | trying to come up with a rule that lends certainty and |
14 | predictability to Section 2 generally and refusals to |
15 | deal specifically. But in the end, I think the |
16 | balancing test as advocated in Aspen and Microsoft is |
17 | where you have to end up. I'm uncomfortable with the |
18 | universal rule that focuses on the welfare of the |
19 | monopolist. That's the profit sacrifice test. I'm more |
20 | concerned about the consumer, not whether the monopolist |
21 | sacrificed profits. |
22 | On the approach that asks if there was any |
23 | plausible economic reason for doing something, you know, |
24 | I think lawyers can always come up with a plausible |
25 | economic reason. That's not the issue. The issue is |
1 | whether that reason is good enough to outweigh the |
2 | anticompetitive effects. And that, it seems to me, is |
3 | what you have to do. |
4 | I would welcome a clearer rule, but in the end, |
5 | you have to take into account the redeeming virtues, the |
6 | business reasons, the justification, but if the |
7 | anticompetitive effects are large and the efficiencies |
8 | small, you can't stop with step one, you have to get to |
9 | as many steps as you can, and that's the question that I |
10 | would like to address to Bill. His third step is: what |
11 | was your justification? Suppose the defendant states |
12 | it, and then the other side comes in and let's say fails |
13 | to show that your justification was not plausible, |
14 | substantial, significant -- that is, there was some |
15 | justification. Do we stop there? Or do we go on to the |
16 | question of maybe you had a good justification, but it |
17 | didn't outweigh the anticompetitive effects? |
18 | Let me return finally return to the issues |
19 | relating to essential facilities. Let me start with the |
20 | proposition that the general rule is and must be no |
21 | general duty to deal. You don't have to disclose these |
22 | kinds of information except under a very rare exception, |
23 | and the exception is where a monopolist has a bottleneck |
24 | monopoly. The scholars are suppose to all say let's get |
25 | rid of the doctrine. That's really not what they say. |
1 | They say it should be rare and extremely narrow, that's |
2 | Areeda, that's Hovenkamp. I say the same thing. It |
3 | should be very rare, and very narrow. |
4 | But I think it should be an exception to the |
5 | general rule. I think the best summary of the |
6 | limitations on essential facility claims is in the MCI |
7 | case, which I notice virtually every lower court that |
8 | either sustains or overrules the essential facilities |
9 | claim, they all use the MCI test. The test is as |
10 | follows: one, it only applies to a monopolist; two, |
11 | other potential rivals cannot duplicate the facility or |
12 | the service. It's not just that it would be hard to |
13 | duplicate it, it's they can't do it at all. Three, the |
14 | monopolist denies access to the service or the facility; |
15 | and four, that it's feasible to make use of the facility |
16 | available. |
17 | I remember there was a throw-away line in Otter |
18 | Tail, and that's not my favorite case in this area, but |
19 | there's a throw-away line saying, you know, if you had |
20 | said that there's an engineering reason why you couldn't |
21 | wheel power to those municipalities, this would be a |
22 | different case. The problem with Otter Tail is there |
23 | was no plausible explanation except anticompetitive |
24 | purpose for refusing to wheel the power. |
25 | The EU has added a few additional |
1 | qualifications: The refusal to deal must eliminate all |
2 | competition, and that the product that the person |
3 | seeking access would make is not just a clone of the |
4 | first product, I don't think you need those two |
5 | additional restrictions, although they do narrow the |
6 | doctrine. |
7 | I think with the general qualifications stated |
8 | in MCI, we're in good shape. And I do want to emphasize |
9 | here -- the idea is not that the monopolist is giving |
10 | anything away, it's receiving reasonable royalties that |
11 | a court or an expert witness figured out was acceptable. |
12 | Finally, it has been said that there's Terminal |
13 | Railways, there's Otter Tail, there's Associated Press, |
14 | and there aren't many cases that address the essential |
15 | facility issue. That's just not true. There are scores |
16 | of lower court cases, including lower court cases since |
17 | Trinko kicked a lot of mud on the essential facilities |
18 | doctrine, which have addressed the claim of essential |
19 | facilities. |
20 | Let me conclude by saying that while Section 2 |
21 | enforcement is an area that deserves to be addressed, at |
22 | least for the time being, I think Aspen Ski is the best |
23 | approach to it. It applies a rule of reason, and the |
24 | Court looked at and rejected any plausible business |
25 | justification. It seems to me a monopolist ought to |
1 | have some reason for refusing to do business with a |
2 | potential rival. I just don't think of antitrust as |
3 | being so narrowly confined when it comes to the market |
4 | power of a monopolist. I look forward to the |
5 | discussion. Thank you. |
6 | (Applause. ) |
7 | MR. ABBOTT: Well, so far we've heard one |
8 | endorsement of the Cal Dental sliding scale approach and |
9 | an endorsement of an approach based on Aspen Ski, |
10 | variations on balancing approaches, and it will be |
11 | interesting to see what our next speaker has to say |
12 | about such approaches. |
13 | Hew Pate, partner and head of Hunton & Williams' |
14 | Global Competition Practice Group, is a former Assistant |
15 | Attorney General for antitrust, until relatively |
16 | recently. Hew's practice involves all aspects of |
17 | competition law, counseling and litigation. Hew has |
18 | served as Ewald Distinguished Visiting Professor of Law |
19 | at Virginia, from which he graduated first in his class. |
20 | Hew clerked for two Supreme Court Justices, Justice |
21 | Powell and Justice Kennedy. |
22 | Hew? |
23 | (Applause.) |
24 | MR. PATE: Thank you very much, Alden. It is |
25 | great to be here at the Commission's conference facility |
1 | for these hearings. I appreciate the opportunity to |
2 | take a part in them. I have submitted some written |
3 | testimony, which I have prepared on behalf of the United |
4 | States Telecom Association. That, as I understand it, |
5 | will be available on the website for these hearings. As |
6 | to my elaborations on that and what I say in the |
7 | exchange, you've just got me, and all the views I |
8 | express, both in the written testimony and here, are my |
9 | own. |
10 | The general point of the testimony I'm going to |
11 | give is that independent competition among competitors |
12 | who are not relying upon one another for assistance or |
13 | even for pulled punches in the competitive process is |
14 | what best produces innovative products at low prices. |
15 | Government-imposed duties to assist competitors force |
16 | courts into setting prices, a task for which they are |
17 | not very well equipped, particularly in capital |
18 | intensive or high technology fields. The uncertainty |
19 | that is caused by indeterminate liability rules and |
20 | duties to assist competitors are likely to retard |
21 | desirable investment. |
22 | And the U.S. system of private litigation, which |
23 | uniquely puts decisions on these types of issues in the |
24 | hands of general judges, as has been mentioned, and in |
25 | the hands of juries, sometimes with very vague |
1 | instructions, exacerbates the problem. And I would |
2 | suggest that recent experience in the telecommunications |
3 | field provides a good illustration of this point. |
4 | This testimony, my testimony is first going to |
5 | talk about refusals to deal and essential facilities. |
6 | The question is where after Trinko these doctrines |
7 | should go in the future, and my suggestion is not much |
8 | of anywhere. These doctrines inherently generate |
9 | uncertainty, they threaten returns on investment, and by |
10 | doing so, they discourage investment from taking place. |
11 | With respect to refusals to deal, or as I prefer |
12 | to think of it, duties to assist competitors, all have |
13 | the right to take a different tack. I think in the wake |
14 | of Trinko, as we have seen lower courts try to make |
15 | sense of, and cabin the Aspen decision, that the time |
16 | has come for Aspen to be overruled, and that the law |
17 | would be better with it off the books, and that the |
18 | Commission and the Division would do a service to the |
19 | law by advocating that in their report from these |
20 | hearings. |
21 | The second major point I want to make, while I |
22 | don't at least in this presentation want to debate the |
23 | variety of standards, as has been mentioned, I think the |
24 | no economic sense test has a good deal to be commended. |
25 | At the Antitrust Modernization Commission, I have |
1 | responded to some criticisms and made a general defense |
2 | of that test, but for today, I simply want to suggest |
3 | that the agencies would do a service by continuing to |
4 | push for more objective standards in this area. And to |
5 | my mind, while a general balancing test is flexible, |
6 | because it can apply in a wide variety of circumstances, |
7 | it is inherently lacking in any objective content that |
8 | businesses can apply in a predictable manner to make |
9 | their decisions. And while there may be different |
10 | formulations of it, some variation of a price-cost |
11 | comparison in my judgment is going to be necessary if |
12 | objectivity is going to be brought to the inquiry. |
13 | With respect to the telecommunications industry |
14 | experience, I think it does shed some light on whether |
15 | duties with forced sharing are likely to produce |
16 | desirable results. Telecommunications is an area where |
17 | huge capital expenditures and great risk need to be |
18 | undertaken to provide the product, and before any |
19 | profits can be made. I had a good deal of experience in |
20 | this industry in working on DOJ's implementation of the |
21 | 1996 Act. And my experience there was that the DOJ |
22 | staff worked tremendously hard to try to implement that |
23 | act. But my experience in that process also left me |
24 | convinced that forced sharing of assets with competitors |
25 | is not a sound foundation for promoting competition. |
1 | As you all you are aware, the unbundling |
2 | obligations of the 1996 Act were premised on a so-called |
3 | stepping stone theory, the idea that if competitive |
4 | local exchange providers were given mandated wholesale |
5 | price access to incumbent local exchange providers' |
6 | facilities, this would allow so-called CLACs to enter |
7 | these markets officially without building facilities, |
8 | without undergoing that inherent risk. This would bring |
9 | immediate competition of a sort, and importantly, it |
10 | would then allow CLACs to build their own facilities so |
11 | that facility-based competition could follow thereafter. |
12 | A lot of water has gone under the bridge since |
13 | the passage of that Act in attempts to administer it. I |
14 | think the basic lessons are difficult to deny at this |
15 | point. Rather than provide a stepping stone to |
16 | independent competition, sharing obligations led to |
17 | demands for ever greater and more complicated sharing |
18 | obligations, many of which were found unlawful by the |
19 | courts in ensuing litigation. |
20 | One writer who has actually supported forced |
21 | sharing as a part of the antitrust laws recently summed |
22 | it up this way: "The 1996 Act is arguably a good |
23 | example of the questionable effectiveness of legally |
24 | mandated sharing. After eight years, the FCC has failed |
25 | to produce a legal system of access, and has instead |
1 | furthered a disastrous $50 billion Telecom boom and bust |
2 | in local telecommunications." |
3 | The experience there, I would suggest, is |
4 | illustrative of what happens when -- even when an |
5 | agency, but when an agency and parties who can be |
6 | protected want to litigate over the agency's rulings and |
7 | what the forced sharing obligation will mean, I think |
8 | provides an illustration of what is likely to ensue. |
9 | I think it also appears clear at this point that |
10 | the Act's forced sharing obligation has in many |
11 | instances slowed investment that otherwise would have |
12 | been made. Bob asked, and other speakers wonder what is |
13 | the empirical case for suggesting that incentives would |
14 | be chilled. Among one collection of studies, I would |
15 | point you to one by Scott Wallsten at the AEI-Brookings |
16 | Joint Center For Regulatory Studies, which can be found |
17 | on their website, and in summarizing the work in this |
18 | area, he suggests that although there are a few |
19 | dissenting voices, most economists and most studies |
20 | conclude that unbundling obligations in the U.S. reduced |
21 | incentives to invest in high-speed Internet |
22 | infrastructure. Cable companies which weren't bound by |
23 | these sort of unbundling obligations deployed more |
24 | quickly. DSL has lagged behind cable in terms of |
25 | deployment. That's the opposite situation we see in |
1 | many other countries. |
2 | The telecommunications industry recently has |
3 | rebounded, perhaps not coincidentally, with a diminution |
4 | of forced sharing obligations, and where reform of the |
5 | 1996 Act is headed, is not entirely clear. But I do |
6 | think that antitrust generally can learn some lessons |
7 | from the experience, and the most important is that |
8 | forced sharing discourages and slows innovation. |
9 | Second, I certainly do believe that the many |
10 | complex and unforeseeable consequences of a forced |
11 | sharing regime are extremely difficult to administer. |
12 | It may be that in certain circumstances a regulatory |
13 | framework can administer forced sharing obligations in |
14 | some circumstances, or that a regulatory judgment will |
15 | be made that it should, but as a general matter, as a |
16 | general antitrust principle, and this is a point Justice |
17 | Stewart made in his dissent in Otter Tail, the rare |
18 | situations where that would be necessarily are not very |
19 | easily translated into a general duty of antitrust to be |
20 | applied across all industries. So, certainly in my |
21 | judgment, the transaction costs that come with a broad |
22 | sharing obligation are likely to outweigh the benefits. |
23 | Let me turn to refusals to deal and essential |
24 | facilities under the antitrust laws. We've heard some |
25 | comment about Trinko, and Aspen, already, and the three |
1 | rationales that the Court in Trinko offered for |
2 | limiting, very severely, any duty to assist competitors. |
3 | The Court did that in granting a motion to dismiss, |
4 | holding that the plaintiff's claim in Trinko was so |
5 | lacking in traditional antitrust merit that it does not |
6 | even require discovery before dismissal of the case. |
7 | And the three rationales, as you know, were the |
8 | negative incentive effects, both on the incumbent, the |
9 | high-market share incumbent, and on potential new |
10 | entrants from a sharing rule. Yes, skepticism of |
11 | generalist courts and juries' ability to manage sharing |
12 | obligations to set terms and prices. And then finally, |
13 | this idea of false positives. I think false positives |
14 | doesn't necessarily mean that we go to the Supreme Court |
15 | or even to lower courts and figure out whether the |
16 | defendants or the plaintiffs were winning, or whether |
17 | cases were rightly decided, but it does require some |
18 | consideration of the duties of those who are charged |
19 | with risking capital and conducting business, about |
20 | whether, in fact, their potential competitive activities |
21 | are chilled by the fear of being embroiled in litigation |
22 | under sharing duty types of rules, and for that reason, |
23 | I think that the risk of false positives is significant. |
24 | As to Aspen, while I think Aspen, as I have said |
25 | elsewhere, can be reconciled with a no economic sense |
1 | approach to the law and as consistent with it, since |
2 | Trinko, a number of courts, and some commentators have |
3 | come to view Aspen as standing for the proposition that |
4 | once a course of sharing conduct begins, that it |
5 | shouldn't be stopped. And if that's what Aspen is going |
6 | to stand for, then I think we would all be better off if |
7 | the case were overruled. |
8 | The reason for that, I think is pretty simple, |
9 | that while it is a way to distinguish the fact pattern |
10 | in Aspen from the fact pattern in Trinko, there's |
11 | nothing in economics that would suggest that the facts |
12 | are not likely to change in a pre-existing relationship. |
13 | There's no particular reason to believe that a course of |
14 | conduct that was once entered into remains efficient |
15 | forever. |
16 | So, it may be true that a voluntary course of |
17 | dealing provides an initial benchmark to set a price |
18 | that presumably the parties wouldn't have entered into |
19 | the relationship unless it were mutually profitable, all |
20 | that's true, and mitigates to some extent the concerns |
21 | that were in existence in Trinko, but it does not |
22 | eliminate them. |
23 | The other serious problem I think with a duty of |
24 | continued sharing is that it can prevent voluntary |
25 | sharing from taking place in the first place. This is a |
1 | point Judge Posner made in the Olympia Equipment Leasing |
2 | Company case, a case where Western Union had initially |
3 | assisted Olympia, decided to stop, got sued for doing |
4 | so, and as Judge Posner put it, if Western Union had |
5 | known that it was undertaking a journey from which there |
6 | could be no turning back, a journey it could not even |
7 | interrupt momentarily, it would have been foolish to |
8 | have embarked. And I think that's the real risk of a |
9 | developing idea that Aspen stands for the proposition |
10 | that you just can't stop sharing if you ever start. |
11 | Essential facilities, I won't spend too much |
12 | time on. I certainly do not think it adds anything as a |
13 | stand-alone theory of liability. I think Professors |
14 | Areeda and Hoenkamp said it well, the doctrine is |
15 | harmful because, I quote, "Forcing a firm to share its |
16 | monopoly is inconsistent with antitrust basic goals for |
17 | two reasons. First, consumers are no better off when a |
18 | monopoly is shared. Ordinarily a price and output are |
19 | the same as they were when one monopolist used the input |
20 | alone. And second, the right to share monopoly |
21 | discourages firms from developing their own alternative |
22 | inputs." |
23 | I will conclude, and time is running out, simply |
24 | by renewing a call for the agencies to participate in |
25 | advocating more objective standards. I think we're at a |
1 | high water mark now of criticisms leveled at the |
2 | standard-less nature of Section 2 generally. The OECD |
3 | competition committee recently issued a background note |
4 | that collects a number of these. I recall Elhauge has |
5 | described the exclusionary conduct law that exists today |
6 | as using a barrage of conclusory labels to cover for a |
7 | lack of any well-defined -- for any well-defined |
8 | criteria for sorting out desirable from undesirable |
9 | conduct. Even Eleanor Fox, with whom I often disagree |
10 | on panels like this, states that a number of the |
11 | contemporary cases tend to be noncommittal and rely on |
12 | obfuscatory language in their use of terms, such as |
13 | anticompetitive. |
14 | So, I think uncertain legal and regulatory |
15 | regimes, like limits on investment, are likely to prove |
16 | strong deterrents to investment, and innovation. |
17 | Certainly the continued reliance in some cases on intent |
18 | is one example of the type of subjective standards that |
19 | can lead to uncertainty and retard investment. |
20 | There is some positive sign, I think, on the |
21 | horizon that the Supreme Court may continue to look into |
22 | this area in the Weyerhaeuser case that they've granted |
23 | recently, where liability was imposed on the basis of |
24 | purchasing more saw logs than were needed. I would |
25 | suggest that we're really not going to do very well in a |
1 | regime where juries make a determination based on what |
2 | is right and wrong in log buying, without any more |
3 | objective basis for decision. |
4 | I'll stop there. As to the empirical basis for |
5 | all this, I would simply suggest that if the government |
6 | is going to intervene, if it's going to decide to |
7 | require sharing of a facility, if it's going to decide |
8 | not to use a property rule for determining how assets |
9 | are going to be used, but instead use a liability rule |
10 | to take from the Doug Melamed paradigm from the famous |
11 | law review article he authored with Judge Calabresi a |
12 | long time ago, that it ought to have some pretty serious |
13 | grounding for believing that the situation is going to |
14 | be made better. I don't think right now that an |
15 | empirical case can be made that forced sharing, that |
16 | this aspect of antitrust used to assist competitors is |
17 | going to leave consumers better off. I suggested some |
18 | time before I left government that the Modernization |
19 | Commission could do a study by trying to look into the |
20 | empirical basis for different areas of antitrust. |
21 | That's a hard thing to do, as they quickly decided, but |
22 | without it, in an area where the economics don't produce |
23 | a real consensus, I think the basis for government |
24 | intervention is lacking. |
25 | Bob asked whether we should just throw up our |
1 | hands because it's so difficult. Emil Paulis, who works |
2 | at the European Commission, used to make the same |
3 | comment after he heard me speak, and he would always |
4 | say, well, Hew, you just want to throw the baby out with |
5 | the bath water, because the standards are so difficult. |
6 | And I always would respond by saying, well, Emil, if |
7 | I've got a baby, and I've got to dip it into some bath |
8 | water, I would like to have some reason to believe that |
9 | the baby is going to be cleaner after I take it out than |
10 | it was before I put it in. And I don't think in this |
11 | area of the law that we have that. |
12 | Thanks, I look forward to the discussion. |
13 | (Applause.) |
14 | MR. ABBOTT: The people who are standing in the |
15 | back, there are some seats up front, so don't be shy, |
16 | there are seats. Thanks, Hew. |
17 | So, now we have two rational balancers and one |
18 | antitrust skeptic, and now we're going to turn to our |
19 | first academically trained economist on the panel, Steve |
20 | Salop, professor of economics and law at Georgetown |
21 | University Law Center, where he teaches antitrust law |
22 | and economics, economic reasoning for lawyers, and in |
23 | addition maintains an active consulting practice at CRA |
24 | International. Steve is no stranger to government, |
25 | having worked at the Civil Aeronautics Board, the |
1 | Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Trade Commission. |
2 | Now I remember him giving tutorials to young staffers on |
3 | economics at the FTC, young bright staffers, I was one |
4 | of them. And he did a very impressive job in that |
5 | regard. Steve has written widely in leading antitrust |
6 | journals, on this topic of Section 2, and I, for one, |
7 | look forward eagerly to hear his comments. |
8 | Steve? |
9 | (Applause. ) |
10 | MR. SALOP: Thank you. I'm really pleased to be |
11 | here. I'm thrilled that Bill Kolasky seems to agree |
12 | with me. That's one down at Wilmer Cutler and several |
13 | to go I guess. |
14 | I want to talk a little bit about the general |
15 | exclusion standards, but just for a moment, and then go |
16 | on and talk about the application of refusals to deal. |
17 | As you know, there are two standards that people |
18 | have been talking about, what I call the consumer |
19 | welfare effects standard, I just want to focus on the |
20 | fact that that's really the effective price and quantity |
21 | effect, not some complicated balancing, and then the |
22 | profit and no economic sense test. I favor the consumer |
23 | welfare effect test. You know, it's focused on the goal |
24 | of antitrust, it's flexible, it is an enquiry meet for |
25 | the case, I agree with Bill on that. It implies a |
1 | tailored structural enquiry for each type of |
2 | exclusionary conduct. |
3 | It's not an open-ended balancing of the sort |
4 | that was suggested in Chicago Board of Trade, but rather |
5 | there's a series of steps that one must go through and |
6 | those series of steps differ for different types of |
7 | exclusionary conduct. |
8 | For example, I spoke at the -- at this panel the |
9 | FTC had last month on timber overbuying and so on, and I |
10 | distinguished between predatory overbuying and raising |
11 | rivals costs overbuying and depending on the |
12 | characterization of the conduct, there was a different |
13 | test that was used. |
14 | Should be still a different test for predatory |
15 | pricing, still a different test for refusals to deal, |
16 | still a different set of tests for exclusive dealing, |
17 | but all within the umbrella of a focus on consumer |
18 | welfare and this consumer welfare approach. |
19 | So, I don't think that the consumer welfare |
20 | standard leads to balancing. I also don't think it |
21 | leads to false positives. Indeed the sacrifice test is |
22 | usually criticized for causing false negatives, but as I |
23 | discuss in my article, it also causes false positives, |
24 | and indeed I'll argue that with refusals to deal, the |
25 | sacrifice standard would be more likely to cause false |
1 | positives than would the consumer welfare test. |
2 | We've talked a little bit about whether the |
3 | innovation incentives are a reason to cut back Section |
4 | 2. I'm going to talk about this before we get to |
5 | refusals to deal, but just basically, you know, firms |
6 | have incentives to compete, incentives to innovate in |
7 | competitive markets. I believe it's the consensus of |
8 | economists that innovation incentives are greater in |
9 | competitive markets than in monopoly markets, |
10 | monopolists have weaker innovation incentives than |
11 | competitors. I would cite you to Mike Scherer's |
12 | article, which is cited in my antitrust law journal |
13 | article. And of course, you know, if a monopolist, if |
14 | the dominant firm knocks the entrants out of business, |
15 | then it will, of course, reduce the innovation |
16 | incentives of the entrants as well. |
17 | Well, now, how would you apply this to refusals |
18 | to deal? Well, here, you've got the consumer welfare |
19 | test, we've got the first -- the profit sacrifice, or |
20 | NES test, and then of course per se legality. What I |
21 | want to say about this is that the consumer welfare test |
22 | and the sacrifice test actually have a lot of |
23 | similarities. They both require a price benchmark, and |
24 | a lot of people say the price benchmark is the fatal |
25 | flaw in anything other than per se legality. I'm going |
1 | to explain why I don't think that's true. And I'll also |
2 | talk about why I think the sacrifice test is more likely |
3 | to lead to false positives, because it does not have any |
4 | or may not have any anticompetitive effects prong. And |
5 | of course I say legality leads to false negatives. |
6 | Okay, so what should the rule be under the |
7 | consumer welfare test? I'm going to talk about the |
8 | rule. I have a hand-out, which you can pick up at the |
9 | break, which sets out the rule I've composed in detail, |
10 | but we can talk a little bit about that now. |
11 | There will be basically three pieces to it. |
12 | First of all you have to show that the defendant has |
13 | monopoly power, and that would be monopoly power in the |
14 | input market and actual or likely monopoly power in the |
15 | output market, so we're talking about a vertically |
16 | integrated monopolist. |
17 | You would have to show that the plaintiff has |
18 | made a genuine offer to buy at or above some benchmark |
19 | price, and I'll talk in a bit about how you determine |
20 | that benchmark price. So, this is not a matter of |
21 | saying that the monopolist has to sell at cost, I'm |
22 | going to come up with a benchmark that's going to |
23 | compensate the monopolist adequately, and the plaintiff |
24 | would have the burden of showing that it made an offer. |
25 | So, the plaintiff can't go to the court first, the |
1 | plaintiff has to go to the monopolist and try to get the |
2 | product, and if it fails, and the defendant, you know, |
3 | refuses to deal, then there is at least potential for a |
4 | case. |
5 | This test I use, which I call a compensation |
6 | test, is going to compensate the monopolist for its lost |
7 | profits for the customers that it loses to the entrant, |
8 | and this is very much a sacrifice test, a no economic |
9 | sense test. But under the consumer welfare analysis, |
10 | you also require the plaintiff to prove anticompetitive |
11 | harm. And that would be during the output market, or |
12 | the input market, or some other -- some other market |
13 | where the firms are actual or potential competitors. |
14 | It's not clear to me that the sacrifice standard |
15 | requires this third step, and that's why I think it's |
16 | going to lead to false positives. I think it only |
17 | requires the first two. Now, if you actually parse the |
18 | literature, Greg Werden probably does not have this |
19 | third step. He has some type of incipiency standard for |
20 | the third step. I think Doug Melamed, I think, adds |
21 | this third prong. |
22 | In which market do I have to show |
23 | anticompetitive effects? Well, that's going to depend |
24 | on the case. But, you know, a refusal to deal could |
25 | cover up, you know, a naked noncompete. For example, |
1 | you know, a contemporary example might be suppose |
2 | Halliburton, which has a monopoly over certain |
3 | transportation services in Iraq, suppose it says to a |
4 | firm, I will only provide you transportation services in |
5 | Iraq which you need in order to sell other commodities |
6 | to the armed forces, I will only provide that input to |
7 | you if you promise not to compete with me in providing |
8 | oil field services in Louisiana. |
9 | Well, that's a refusal to deal, the harm would |
10 | not be in the geographic market in whatever Halliburton |
11 | competes in in Iraq, but rather some other unrelated |
12 | market. So, it's possible that this litigation could be |
13 | brought here. |
14 | Or, you know, more generally, if it's not the |
15 | input or output market, it's going to be a complementary |
16 | product, it's going to be a complementary product |
17 | market. |
18 | So, notice, this consumer welfare test, it's not |
19 | an open-ended Chicago Board of Trade inquiry, have to |
20 | show market power, have to show anticompetitive effects |
21 | in a particularized way, and you have to show that the |
22 | price offered by the plaintiff meets the compensation |
23 | test. |
24 | Okay. Well, the real issue is, what about this |
25 | price benchmark? This is where the controversy is. And |
1 | there are several candidates, as Hew pointed out. |
2 | There's the prior price paid by the plaintiff, as in the |
3 | case of Aspen. It could be the price charged to other |
4 | buyers, which also was an issue in Aspen, where they |
5 | were willing to deal with other mountains in other ski |
6 | resorts. Or there could be some benchmark, if the first |
7 | two don't work, either because there's no course of -- |
8 | previous course of dealing, or because of some reason |
9 | they're not appropriate, and I agree with you that they |
10 | may not be appropriate, then you need another benchmark |
11 | and the benchmark that I've come up with is a benchmark |
12 | I call protected profits benchmark, and it's a price |
13 | that compensates the defendant for the monopoly profits |
14 | lost to plaintiff from losing -- from customers that |
15 | shift from the defendant to the plaintiff. |
16 | I'll give you an example. So, it is a sacrifice |
17 | test, it is giving the defendant the monopoly profits |
18 | that it's earned, and I think that's a key issue. You |
19 | might want to adjust this benchmark. For example, |
20 | suppose dealing with the plaintiff raises the |
21 | defendant's production costs. Well then you would have |
22 | to take that into account in setting the benchmark. |
23 | Suppose the plaintiff creates real reputational |
24 | free-riding, you know, suppose it says, well, we've |
25 | used -- we've used this input that we got from GE, and |
1 | suppose their product is no good, and that hurts GE's |
2 | reputation, well that could would be a reason why GE |
3 | should be permitted not to deal with them or charge them |
4 | a higher price. |
5 | And lastly, suppose the monopoly, we've been |
6 | acting up until now that these monopolies are attained |
7 | legitimately. If they're not obtained legitimately, |
8 | then it's not clear that you want to give someone |
9 | protection from the monopolist. Not clear that you |
10 | would worry so much about protecting those monopoly |
11 | profits or protecting the incentives. |
12 | Finally, the other adjustment I would make is |
13 | this is a rule intended to generate negotiation, so if |
14 | the defendant just has a flat refusal to deal, a |
15 | non-negotiable refusal to deal, or only makes sham |
16 | offers, as they did in Aspen, then the burden is going |
17 | to shift to the defendant to show that the plaintiff's |
18 | price offer was good. |
19 | So, for example, in Aspen, it's not as if |
20 | Highlands said, I'll pay you ten cents for the daily |
21 | tickets, and Ski Co. said, no, no, no, I want $44, |
22 | that's much more reasonable, and Highlands said, I'm |
23 | going to sue you. It wasn't like that at all. In fact, |
24 | Highlands made an offer, in fact the retail price, but |
25 | Ski Co. made a counteroffer designed for Highlands to |
1 | turn down. I mean, it was not a real counteroffer, it |
2 | was one that Highlands would be forced to reject. So, I |
3 | place some burden on the defendant in those |
4 | circumstances. |
5 | Okay, so how do you calculate this? Well, this |
6 | is the part with the math, but as I tell my law |
7 | students, this is not really math, it's just shorthand, |
8 | it's just abbreviations. So, my benchmark has two |
9 | important properties to it. One is it compensates the |
10 | defendant for the monopoly profits that it loses on the |
11 | customers that it loses to the plaintiff. However, it |
12 | does not get compensation for price competition that's |
13 | induced by entry by a firm that has lower costs or |
14 | superior product. |
15 | So, I'm compensating them for their monopoly |
16 | profits they have, but I'm not allowing them to deter |
17 | entry by a more efficient competitor, one that has lower |
18 | costs or a better product. Where did I get the standard |
19 | from? Well, I didn't invent it. This goes way back. |
20 | It's called the efficient components pricing standard, |
21 | first started in the late 70s or early 80s. It's been |
22 | referred to in the context and there's been a lot of |
23 | commentary on this basic standard by people, among |
24 | others, John Vickers, who just left heading up the OFT |
25 | in Europe. |
1 | The way you calculate this, this benchmark |
2 | price, is the monopolist's input cost, plus it gets its |
3 | margin, plus its margin times the fraction of the |
4 | plaintiff's customers that get diverted from the |
5 | monopolist. This is not -- it's not a lot of letters, |
6 | it looks like algebra, but it's not really so |
7 | complicated. |
8 | So, let me give you an example to show that, and |
9 | I'll use -- suppose the Trinko case were not in the |
10 | context of regulation, how would you, you know, how |
11 | would you use this protected profit standard? Well, |
12 | here's the data. Suppose Verizon's incremental cost of |
13 | providing DSL, wholesale DSL, suppose that were $10. |
14 | Suppose Verizon's margin on retail DSL, their monopoly |
15 | margin, suppose that were $50. And suppose that if |
16 | Verizon sells wholesale DSL to AT&T, half the customers |
17 | AT&T gets will come out of the hide of Verizon, and the |
18 | other half will come from cable and dial-up. And yes, I |
19 | know Verizon provides dial-up in its own territory, but |
20 | they probably don't make much money there, so I am just |
21 | leaving that out for now. But if you will, you could |
22 | make it more complicated to take into account the |
23 | dial-up margin, but I think Verizon probably sells at a |
24 | negative margin on dial-up anyway. |
25 | So, under these circumstances, half of AT&T's |
1 | retail DSL customers are going to come out of Verizon, |
2 | half are going to come out of the hide of Comcast, Time |
3 | Warner and so on. So, this diversion rate would be 50 |
4 | percent. Diversion rate, you know, it's something we |
5 | use in mergers all the time. |
6 | What would be the benchmark price? It would be |
7 | $35. Verizon's $10 cost, plus they get a monopoly |
8 | margin of $50, they lose that monopoly margin on half |
9 | their customers, so half of $50 is $25, you have to |
10 | compensate them for those expected losses, that gives us |
11 | $35. Okay? |
12 | If AT&T were going to get all its customers out |
13 | of the hide of Verizon, then the benchmark would be a |
14 | lot higher, it would be $60, Verizon would have to be |
15 | compensated for its costs, plus the margin that it lost. |
16 | Okay? Not so difficult to do this at all. |
17 | Under this standard, and this is another sort of |
18 | key aspect, I probably should have put it on the |
19 | previous slide. The entrant will not be able to succeed |
20 | in the market under this standard, unless it has lower |
21 | costs or a superior product for at least some consumers. |
22 | So, this is not a prescription for inducing inefficient |
23 | entry, the only kind of entry that gets induced as a |
24 | result of this test is efficient entry, and therefore I |
25 | think it meets the -- I think it meets the standard. |
1 | So, for that reason, I think this, you know, |
2 | this consumer welfare standard, look at how much the |
3 | plaintiff has to prove. Monopoly power in the input |
4 | market, you know, if the entrant's got an alternative, |
5 | then they're out. The defendant has to have actual or |
6 | potential monopoly power in the output market, or else |
7 | the plaintiff loses. |
8 | A lot of things for plaintiffs to prove. It's |
9 | got to prove that the price offered exceeds the test, a |
10 | test that I don't think is very difficult for a firm, |
11 | certainly not a firm like Verizon, to calculate. I |
12 | don't think it's hard for any firm. |
13 | This is the same sort of data we routinely use |
14 | for merger analysis, and that a firm needs to run its |
15 | own business. A firm needs to know its margin. And in |
16 | fact, it can look up its margin, it can ask the CFO for |
17 | their margin, it's on the profit and loss statement and |
18 | should be on the profit and loss statement for each |
19 | division. And they just need to know the extent to |
20 | which they compete with the plaintiff. |
21 | And the plaintiff here also has to prove |
22 | anticompetitive effects. So, there's big barriers for |
23 | the plaintiff here. So, this is not -- this is not a |
24 | standard that's going to lead to overwhelming amount of |
25 | litigation. |
1 | Now, this is the standard, how do we deal, what |
2 | do we have to say about Trinko? Well, Trinko raises a |
3 | number of cautions that have been discussed by the |
4 | earlier speakers. They pointed out that there's no |
5 | general Sherman Act duty to deal, and they said forced |
6 | share, I guess red flags is my term, the justice |
7 | division did not use the term red flags, but it raises a |
8 | number of red flags. Lessens investment incentives, |
9 | requires courts to act as central planners, that's the |
10 | red flag. And the compelling negotiation can facilitate |
11 | collusion. All of this adds up to the concern with |
12 | false positives. |
13 | Well, let me go through these and look at these |
14 | in a little more detail. Well, first of all, the no |
15 | general Sherman Act duty to deal, that's true. I teach |
16 | antitrust, every antitrust professor knows that. I wish |
17 | that in the Trinko opinion, however, they had quoted |
18 | Colgate correctly. They said Colgate stands for no duty |
19 | to deal. The proper quote says, i.e., in the absence of |
20 | any purpose to create a monopoly, there's no duty to |
21 | deal. So, Colgate is limited and in that Justice Scalia |
22 | tried to change the meaning of Colgate. |
23 | So, what about these more detailed questions? |
24 | Well, first is this investment incentives, this has been |
25 | alluded to by several speakers. I think the first |
1 | point, the key point is the benchmark price compensates |
2 | the defendant for the monopoly profits that it loses on |
3 | customers that it loses to the plaintiff. So, in terms |
4 | of reducing their investment incentives, we're making, |
5 | and I thought Hew was exactly right, it is a liability |
6 | standard. It's making them whole on the profits they |
7 | lose, on the customers that they would lose to the |
8 | plaintiff. |
9 | But there's other reasons why I think it will |
10 | not reduce investment incentive. First of all, Scalia |
11 | worries about reducing the entrant's investment |
12 | standards, that the entrant would otherwise enter the |
13 | input market on its own. But that is a very weak |
14 | statement. I mean, you don't get into one of these |
15 | cases unless the defendant's got monopoly power in the |
16 | input market, and what we mean by monopoly power is |
17 | durable monopoly power. What we mean by durable |
18 | monopoly power is that there are high barriers to entry. |
19 | So, unlikely that the plaintiff otherwise would |
20 | have entered the input market. It also means you can't |
21 | get into the -- you can't enter one market at a time, |
22 | you're unlikely to see leapfrog competition. Secondly, |
23 | we know the competitive markets increase the defendant's |
24 | innovation incentives. Monopolists have weaker |
25 | innovation incentives than do competitors and, you know, |
1 | I mean, the telephone companies have a million excuses |
2 | for why they never innovate, and we have just heard some |
3 | others. |
4 | I think that -- but I think if they had faced |
5 | more competition, they would have stronger innovation. |
6 | They are certainly innovated in trying to come in to |
7 | compete with cable, where they don't have -- where |
8 | Telecom is not -- where telephone companies do not have |
9 | a monopoly. |
10 | Of course entering the output market will |
11 | increase the entrant's innovation incentives. And |
12 | finally, and this is I think a key point, and I think in |
13 | Bill Kolasky's list of cases, Kodak was conveniently |
14 | left out. In Trinko, Kodak doesn't get mentioned. |
15 | Well, one very important point that was made in the |
16 | Kodak opinion is that you can't call the entrant a free |
17 | -rider if they only enter one market rather than all of |
18 | them. |
19 | Kodak says that this understanding of |
20 | free-riding is an argument made by -- made by Kodak, and |
21 | the Supreme Court said, this understanding of |
22 | free-riding has no support in the case law. So, you |
23 | know, I think that argument just does not add up. |
24 | The courts as central planners, I'm running out |
25 | of time, so let me go quickly. You know, I guess the |
1 | point I've been making all along is this isn't so hard. |
2 | Market prices often provide a good benchmark. I think |
3 | this protected profits compensation benchmark is not too |
4 | difficult to evaluate, and then the other point I want |
5 | to make here is, you know, if antitrust withdraws, it's |
6 | not clear that we're going to have laissez faire. This |
7 | has not been the way the United States economy has |
8 | worked. |
9 | When antitrust fails, we often get real formal |
10 | public utility commission regulation, real central |
11 | benefits, and so I just want to raise the question about |
12 | whether we're really going to get ourselves into the |
13 | federal operating system commission if antitrust drops |
14 | out. And of course the essential facility doctrine fits |
15 | in here. |
16 | Okay, finally is this issue about facilitating |
17 | collusion. I think that one is really silly. You know, |
18 | if you believed -- if you believed this argument that |
19 | letting people negotiate is going to facilitate |
20 | collusion, well then we also prohibit voluntary dealing, |
21 | we also prohibit joint ventures, we also prohibit patent |
22 | settlements, which we know from the FTC experience are |
23 | sometimes used to strike noncompetition agreements. |
24 | It's also, you know, the refusal to deal can be |
25 | used, if it's a threatened refusal to deal, can be used |
1 | to facilitate collusion. I'll sell to you, but only if |
2 | you promise not to compete with me. So, I think that |
3 | the -- that effect put out that dicta by the Trinko |
4 | court was really they -- it's either insignificant or |
5 | goes the other way. |
6 | Finally, I want to raise the question of if we |
7 | go down Hew's route for per se legality, where are we |
8 | going to stop? I note that's perhaps not a question |
9 | that Hew is worried about, but it's a question that I'm |
10 | worried about. If it's per se illegal -- per se legal |
11 | to refuse to deal with firms that compete with you, then |
12 | what about exclusive dealing? Why isn't that, per se, |
13 | legal, either with respect to whether if the firm wants |
14 | to buy stuff from you, sell it to your competitors, or |
15 | if they want to buy from your competitors? What about |
16 | the tie-in? Why doesn't it make tie-in per se legal, |
17 | because that's just basically refusal to deal. What |
18 | about noncompetition agreements? What if a firm says, |
19 | like in my little Halliburton example, we're going to |
20 | compete with you in some unrelated market, and they say, |
21 | well, in that case, I'm not going to sell to you. Well, |
22 | that would be -- that would be per se legal. |
23 | And finally, what if they use a refusal to deal |
24 | in order to force the firm to raise prices, either in |
25 | the market -- the output market that we're talking about |
1 | or some other market. Would that also be per se legal |
2 | for them to make that argument? So, I would be quite |
3 | concerned about that. |
4 | I'm out of time, thank you very much. |
5 | (Applause.) |
6 | MR. ABBOTT: Thank you, Steve, for presenting an |
7 | attempt to establish an administrative rule that will |
8 | undoubtedly bring forth some more discussion about the |
9 | rule that might apply in evaluations under the rule of |
10 | reason. |
11 | Now we have another economist who is going to |
12 | take a crack at this difficult set of topics. Tom |
13 | Walton, director of economic policy analysis, General |
14 | Motors Corporation, in which position he oversees the |
15 | analysis of costs, current and prospective governmental |
16 | policies and regulations, and their implications for |
17 | General Motors. Tom Walton received a Ph.D. in |
18 | economics from UCLA, was assistant professor at NYU, |
19 | before joining GM, and served briefly as special advisor |
20 | for regulatory affairs at the FTC. He's vice chair of |
21 | the Business Research Advisory Counsel for the U.S. |
22 | Bureau of Labor Statistics in Washington, D.C. |
23 | Tom? |
24 | (Applause.) |
25 | MR. WALTON: Thank you very much. I'm going to |
1 | try a little bit of a change of pace to give you an idea |
2 | of what it's like to be inside the fish bowl of |
3 | competition. |
4 | Well, it all began back in 1963 when the Federal |
5 | Trade Commission launched its first investigation into |
6 | the manufacturing and distribution practices of the |
7 | major auto makers with regard to the production and sale |
8 | of their single source crash parts. Now, these are the |
9 | parts that are most frequently damaged in the event of |
10 | auto accidents, and which also happen to be single |
11 | source. They include radiators, bumpers, fenders, |
12 | grills, all the sheet metal. They don't include glass, |
13 | because glass is multiple source. |
14 | At that time, Chrysler, Ford and GM, the major |
15 | manufacturers at that time, distributed these parts |
16 | exclusively through our franchised auto dealers. Our |
17 | franchised line-make auto dealers. That's an important |
18 | distinction. For example, Chevrolet parts we |
19 | distributed exclusively through Chevrolet. If an |
20 | independent body shop wanted to buy a part, it could |
21 | only get a Chevrolet brand part at Chevrolet, they could |
22 | not get it at Pontiac, for example. |
23 | Insurance companies instigated the |
24 | investigations. Congressional investigators had been |
25 | constantly pressing them to reduce their auto insurance |
1 | premiums. Insurance had a pretty good handle on the |
2 | labor rate at the auto shops, both at the auto dealers |
3 | and the independents, but they wanted to set up |
4 | independent warehouse distributors or wholesale |
5 | distributors so they could get similar concessions on |
6 | parts. They brought along with them the lobbying arm of |
7 | the independent body shops, or IBSs, as they called |
8 | themselves. They complained that GM and other auto |
9 | manufacturers, everyone used the same system at the |
10 | time, were discriminating against them because they -- |
11 | because in the case of the independent body shop, they |
12 | had to buy the part from the dealer at a mark-up, or |
13 | have the dealer provide the part directly from the |
14 | manufacturer, General Motors or another manufacturer at |
15 | wholesale. |
16 | Of course, the auto dealers, like any other |
17 | retailer, have the wholesaling cost. They have the cost |
18 | of ordering, carrying, insuring and financing the |
19 | distribution of the parts. And of course they charge |
20 | for those wholesaling services. So, the IBSs, the |
21 | independent body shops and insurers went to the Congress |
22 | and went to the Federal Trade Commission to try to force |
23 | us to directly sell those parts, those single-sourced |
24 | crash parts to the body shops and to the independent |
25 | wholesalers. |
1 | Little interest was expressed by the large |
2 | warehouse distributors, and later they would testify |
3 | that they had no interest in taking on the business. |
4 | They also believed that there was no need to take on |
5 | additional wholesalers, additional customers. There was |
6 | no shortage of GM dealers to handle the business. |
7 | There's something like 12,000 dealers spread out in |
8 | every area of the country. They thought they could do |
9 | the best job of handling the bulky and complex repair |
10 | parts because in part, they shared our incentive to keep |
11 | the customer happy and make sure that the owner of a |
12 | Chevrolet vehicle was put quickly and efficiently back |
13 | on the road. |
14 | Sure, they shared our interest in the integrity |
15 | of the brand name. We believe that opening up the |
16 | system to tens of thousands of independent body shops |
17 | would reduce the availability of the parts and increase |
18 | the time necessary to get them to the customer. We knew |
19 | it would impose substantial additional administrative |
20 | and monitoring costs. We didn't feel we could derive |
21 | the monopoly profits from pricing the parts, because we |
22 | would be jeopardizing 95 percent of our business, that's |
23 | the vehicle business, by trying to achieve a monopoly on |
24 | the parts. |
25 | Higher priced parts would have meant driving up |
1 | the repair costs for our customers, and would have |
2 | reduced the likelihood that a Chevrolet vehicle owner |
3 | would become a repeat customer. We knew that one |
4 | company, Renault, had recently ceased doing business in |
5 | this country because of a faulty service repair system. |
6 | Another company, another competitor, Chrysler, had spent |
7 | something like $350 million to convert from the system |
8 | the FTC was proposing, this open warehousing, open |
9 | distribution system, back to the system of distributing |
10 | the parts exclusively through its franchised dealers. |
11 | We did offer subsidies for GM dealers to sell |
12 | the parts to the independent body shops at reduced |
13 | prices. In order to pacify them and to pacify the |
14 | Federal Trade Commission, in September 1967, we proposed |
15 | a plan in which we would offer a 12 percent discount on |
16 | the parts resold through the independents. A program we |
17 | then called wholesale compensation. |
18 | In February of 1968, the Commission, though, |
19 | told us that they intended to file a lawsuit in order to |
20 | bring about price parody between the GM dealer body |
21 | shops and the independent repair shops. Further |
22 | negotiations ensued and in the fall of 1968, the |
23 | Commission accepted our proposal to raise that subsidy, |
24 | that incentive for reselling to 23 percent. Accordingly |
25 | we increased our prices on all crash parts in order to |
1 | try to recoup the cost of the program, including those |
2 | costs of administration and monitoring. |
3 | Later, the Commission would estimate the total |
4 | costs at $70 million per year, that's almost half of a |
5 | billion dollars per year in today's dollars. Now, we |
6 | knew the promo would be expensive, but we thought that |
7 | opening up our warehouses would be still more expensive. |
8 | Well, the arrangement did not satisfy our critics for |
9 | long. |
10 | In the early 1970s, in the era of wage and price |
11 | controls, the President's Council on Wage and Price |
12 | Stability raised its own pricing investigation into |
13 | crash part pricing. The investigation provided an |
14 | extended period of full employment for an economist like |
15 | myself at the auto companies and in the President's |
16 | Office of Management and Budget. It turned out that |
17 | much of the increase in prices was by the newly |
18 | installed auto pricing regulations, especially by the |
19 | bumper standards that were being -- that had been |
20 | suggested by the insurance companies, and that in that |
21 | case, not being to enhance safety, but substantially |
22 | increase the price of our bumpers, which accounted for |
23 | 40 percent of any kind of a crash parts price index. |
24 | As you can see, the relations between us and the |
25 | insurance companies wasn't the best at that time. In |
1 | 1970, the Commission launched yet another investigation. |
2 | What did the Commission want this time? Nothing less |
3 | than a remedy at the manufacturing level. That we be |
4 | required to make a unique and extremely expensive |
5 | tooling for these crash parts available to outside |
6 | manufacturers. |
7 | Fortunately, they later dropped this proposal. |
8 | We heard that their Office of Policy and Planning |
9 | Evaluation had estimated that if successfully |
10 | implemented, the proposal would increase crashed parts |
11 | prices by somewhere between 150 and 580 percent. But |
12 | the Commission still wanted GM to sell its GM-branded |
13 | crash parts "to all vehicle dealers, independent body |
14 | shops, and independent wholesalers at the same prices, |
15 | terms and conditions of sale, said prices to be subject |
16 | to reasonable cost-justified quantity discounts and |
17 | stocking allowances." And I would disagree with my |
18 | friend, Steve Salop, on the simplicity of arriving at |
19 | that kind of price. |
20 | We made one final effort to stave off |
21 | litigation. In early October 1975, we raised our |
22 | wholesaling discount to 30 percent of the dealer price |
23 | on the crash part resale to independents. In early 1976 |
24 | we announced that we would broaden the plan to allow all |
25 | GM dealers to distribute all GM crash parts to anyone. |
1 | This meant that independent body shops could now buy |
2 | that Chevrolet crash part from a Pontiac dealer or from |
3 | any other General Motors dealer. The program never took |
4 | hold. The independents stayed with their existing |
5 | dealer suppliers. Chevrolet for Chevrolet parts, |
6 | Pontiac for Pontiac, so forth. This confirmed our |
7 | belief, at least to us, that the existing system was an |
8 | efficient way of getting our parts to the independents. |
9 | None of it worked. |
10 | By March 22nd, 1976, the Commission issued a |
11 | complaint charging GM with unfair methods of competition |
12 | for refusing to deal with everyone on the same terms we |
13 | gave anyone. It said that the wholesaling parts |
14 | discount had not achieved price parody between us and |
15 | the independents -- between our dealers and the |
16 | independents, and that "the consumer was being asked to |
17 | subsidize the wholesaling profits of the dealer," which |
18 | it was, "and that eliminating the program resulted in an |
19 | estimated drop of 10 percent in consumer prices." |
20 | So, some 13 years after the initial |
21 | investigation had begun, we were in litigation over our |
22 | right to choose the customers with whom we would deal. |
23 | The Commission extended freight upon us for what they |
24 | called a "duty to deal." As an economist, I was the |
25 | economist assigned the case. Did we consider settling? |
1 | Yes. But Frank Dunne, our lead General Motors counsel |
2 | in the case, and his superior, Tom Leary, the recently |
3 | retired FTC commissioner, and Bob's former colleague, |
4 | pressed management to stay the course because in their |
5 | words, "It was the right thing to do." |
6 | They also felt that GM would ultimately prevail |
7 | in the courts, if not with the full Commission. They |
8 | did not want to surrender GM's right to freely and |
9 | voluntarily choose the customers with whom we would and |
10 | would not deal. We did not want to be forced to accept |
11 | a system that was less efficient and less competitive. |
12 | Somehow the complaints and investigations never resulted |
13 | in any Commission actions against our competitors. Our |
14 | chairman, Tom Murphy, agreed, and the rest is history. |
15 | We fought the charges to the bitter end. |
16 | Three years later, on September 24th, 1979, the |
17 | ALJ, Administrative Law Judge, found no evidence that |
18 | GM's refusal to deal and its pricing policies injured |
19 | the independent body shops as a class. Every |
20 | independent body shop witness was doing very well, and |
21 | the industry was doing better than comparable |
22 | industries, growing faster than, for example, our own |
23 | General Motors body shops and general repair shops. |
24 | He also found no harm to independent part |
25 | distributors. Crash parts prices were actually rising |
1 | less rapidly than general inflation and, normally less |
2 | rapidly than the price of the so-called competitive |
3 | products, such as spark plugs and fan belts. He found |
4 | that "creating a duty to deal would increase GM's |
5 | distribution costs." He said, and again I quote, "The |
6 | evidence here does not show that GM has discouraged, |
7 | defeated or prevented the rise of new competition in the |
8 | new GM crash parts market." |
9 | He concluded that GM did not have any predatory |
10 | intent in establishing the system and that there |
11 | appeared to be "no substantially adverse effect on |
12 | competition attributable to the refusal to sell new GM |
13 | crash parts to anyone other than GM dealers." He did |
14 | find, however, that under Section 5 of the Federal Trade |
15 | Commission Act, that we had unfairly discriminated |
16 | against the independent body shops whom he found had to |
17 | pay more for the parts than did our GM dealers. He |
18 | agreed that, indeed, some of our dealers were engaged in |
19 | extensive wholesaling and thus engaged and incurred |
20 | extensive wholesaling costs, but he rejected our |
21 | contention, based on our own GM financial studies, that |
22 | when the dealer's wholesaling and carrying costs were |
23 | included in the prices that their body shops had to pay, |
24 | were actually below the prices that they were charging |
25 | the independent body shops. |
1 | He ordered us to terminate our wholesale |
2 | compensation plan. He decreed the implementation of the |
3 | joint GM/Commission staff which would "cooperatively" |
4 | devise a nondiscriminatory plan for distributing new GM |
5 | crash parts. |
6 | The Commission staff appealed, the headline in |
7 | the October 4th Washington Post read, "FTC Challenged |
8 | Its Own Ruling on GM Crash Parts." So did we. Finally, |
9 | on June 25th, 1982, the full Commission dismissed the |
10 | complaint in its entirety. Unlike the ALJ, they did |
11 | find injury to competition to the independent body |
12 | shops -- to the independent body shop repair witnesses, |
13 | I should say. But in their words, apparently, and in |
14 | spite of the fact that they could find no overall injury |
15 | to the body shops as a class, what disturbed them was |
16 | this perceived difference in price at the GM repair |
17 | shops and body shops, independent body shops. |
18 | The Commission found, though, that the injured |
19 | body shop competition was offset by business |
20 | justifications. That creating a duty to deal could |
21 | result in higher costs of distribution, which ultimately |
22 | would be passed on to consumers in the form of higher |
23 | prices for GM crash parts. Just as we had said 19 years |
24 | earlier. |
25 | They found no injury to competition in wholesale |
1 | parts distribution. Most importantly, they rejected the |
2 | proposed remedy as unworkable. They did not want the |
3 | Commission to be involved in "ongoing supervision of the |
4 | system." They did not want to, in effect, become |
5 | another Council on Wage and Price Stability, having to, |
6 | "commit extensive resources to reviewing GM's |
7 | interpretations of to whom and at what price it could |
8 | sell these crash parts." |
9 | The long ordeal was over. After 19 years of |
10 | investigation and tens of millions of dollars in |
11 | corporate and commission resources, we have not opened |
12 | up our distribution system since. We have not sold |
13 | crash parts directly to independent body shops or to |
14 | independent warehouse distributors. Neither has anyone |
15 | else. We did drop the costly and ineffective wholesale |
16 | compensation plan, the subsidy for dealer resales. |
17 | We have further simplified our pricing program, |
18 | in response to the modern computer and the high speed |
19 | Internet. In the final analysis, the issue came down to |
20 | who can more efficiently manage GM's business? Who can |
21 | more efficiently choose the customers with whom we deal |
22 | and the prices we charge? We share the Commission's |
23 | interest in an efficient system of distribution and in |
24 | keeping the car buyer happy. |
25 | So, the only question, was and is, who can do |
1 | the better job? Thankfully, on June 25th, 1982, the |
2 | Commission finally said, and for very good reasons, it |
3 | did not want to second guess our business judgment |
4 | anymore. We could only hope in the future that the |
5 | courts and the Congress also will share these |
6 | sentiments. Thank you. |
7 | (Applause.) |
8 | MR. ABBOTT: Thanks, Tom, for a cautionary tale |
9 | about agency antitrust enforcement. One of the things |
10 | we are hoping to do in these hearings is to get the |
11 | views of business planners, people inside the |
12 | businesses, and their reactions to antitrust |
13 | enforcement. |
14 | Our next speaker also comes from the business |
15 | world, Mark Whitener, senior counsel, competition law |
16 | and policy at General Electric Company. Prior to |
17 | joining GE, Mark was deputy director of the Federal |
18 | Trade Commission's Bureau of Competition, where he was |
19 | responsible for a variety of antitrust enforcement and |
20 | policy initiatives, where he worked on merger |
21 | guidelines, health care, intellectual property, and |
22 | international enforcement. Mark also spent several |
23 | years in private practice in Washington and London |
24 | prior to joining the FTC. Mark has written widely, |
25 | testified before Congress, and was editor of the ABA |
1 | antitrust section's antitrust magazine. |
2 | Mark? |
3 | (Applause.) |
4 | MR. WHITENER: Well, thank you. Tom did all the |
5 | heavy lifting for us now, and makes my job a bit easier, |
6 | because I can just tell you what I think are all the |
7 | policy implications of what Tom just said. I'm going to |
8 | urge the agencies to use these hearings to set out a |
9 | pretty simple position on this topic, and the topic that |
10 | I'm addressing is unilateral, unconditional refusals to |
11 | deal with competitors. I think other forms of behavior |
12 | that take the form, for example, of the vertical |
13 | restraints or exclusive dealing, I think all of those |
14 | are readily distinguished from what we're talking about |
15 | here today. Perhaps we can get into that during the |
16 | discussion. |
17 | So, it seems to me that what the agencies can do |
18 | here is set out a position that you can call it per se |
19 | legality, I suppose, but my sense is that we're really |
20 | not creating a rule of exclusion, but what we're doing |
21 | is addressing rules of definitions. What does it mean |
22 | when we talk about exclusionary conduct under Section 2? |
23 | And I think that what the agency should say is that |
24 | unconditional refusals to deal with competitors simply |
25 | do not constitute exclusionary conduct. And I think |
1 | that position, by the way, can be taken consistently |
2 | with any of the various analytical models one might |
3 | choose for looking at Section 2 issues generally. |
4 | That position can be consistent with an |
5 | aggressive view of how to look at other forms of |
6 | behavior, or a permissive view, because definitionally, |
7 | it seems to me what we're saying is that when we try and |
8 | define what is exclusion, versus what is the simple |
9 | exercise of one's property rights, or even one's market |
10 | power, if that's what we're -- if that's what exists in |
11 | the technology, that we're taking the rights to one's |
12 | property, that exploiting those rights unilaterally, |
13 | that choosing not to deal with competitors by supplying |
14 | them licensing is within the inherent property right, or |
15 | if market power exists, is simply the exercising the |
16 | market power and not the unlawful maintenance of |
17 | increasing that power. |
18 | If the Commission were to take this position, it |
19 | seems to me that there are a couple of positive effects. |
20 | Not including, by the way, any significant shift in |
21 | federal enforcement policy. This is not an area where |
22 | the agencies have been active for many years, and I |
23 | think quite rightly so. |
24 | When businesses look at this issue and assess |
25 | risk, they're looking at two things. Private |
1 | litigation, which plays out before generalist judges and |
2 | agencies, and increasingly international enforcement. |
3 | And I think for the agencies to take a clear view, clear |
4 | position on this issue, would not only promote the |
5 | sensible interpretation of the law in the U.S. as it's |
6 | applied to private litigation, but also can help us |
7 | advocate for sensible policy abroad. And I'll come back |
8 | to that topic in a moment, but I think it's a very |
9 | important one. |
10 | The ramifications of this approach would be |
11 | essentially to say that unconditional refusals to deal |
12 | with competitors are not exclusionary, regardless of the |
13 | nature of the property, intellectual or otherwise, |
14 | regardless of whether the property owner began dealing |
15 | and stopped or never began dealing at all, I believe we |
16 | made that point. It's not a meaningful distinction or |
17 | way to distinguish between anticompetitive and |
18 | competitive action, regardless of the property owner's |
19 | reasons for not dealing. Whether we use that as a |
20 | question of intent or pretext or otherwise. And |
21 | regardless of the price that's charged, if a firm with |
22 | monopoly power decides to deal, and decides to exercise |
23 | the right that's recognized elsewhere in Section 2 to |
24 | charge different prices for different end users and in |
25 | essence price discriminate, this conduct, standing |
1 | alone, is not a Section 2 violation. |
2 | Because again, as an analytical matter, I'm not |
3 | advocating changing the law or defining a category of |
4 | practices that otherwise are exclusionary as lawful, but |
5 | simply recognizing that what we're talking about here in |
6 | this clear case of the unconditional refusal whether to |
7 | license or to sell, this is simply the exercise of all |
8 | the rights and the capturing of all the value inherent |
9 | in the firm. |
10 | Now, the reason for this, analytically, what |
11 | exists with antitrust and the reasons for this have |
12 | essentially gone off the radar. The reason why these |
13 | cases are rare is because in most instances, courts |
14 | either through express analysis or intuition come to a |
15 | view essentially like the one that I'm describing, but |
16 | if you ask judges and juries to apply the ill-defined |
17 | standards that exist today, some of them are going to |
18 | answer the question the other way. You're really not |
19 | given much guidance in terms of how to address it. |
20 | There is, I think, an important incentives issue |
21 | in play here. I think Bob asked the right question, |
22 | which is where's the evidence? I think we should be |
23 | looking for evidence to underlie more of our antitrust |
24 | judgments, in many areas of the law, rather than relying |
25 | on intuition or case law or anything else that might not |
1 | really tell us a lot about reality. |
2 | So, I think it's a fair question. Hew offered |
3 | some examples, some studies. I do think, though, there |
4 | is a doctrinal or analytical or philosophical question |
5 | here to be answered in terms of incentives, and that is |
6 | we, I think, should assume, you're entitled to assume |
7 | that incentives are diminished when firms are forced to |
8 | share their property and their technology. For the same |
9 | reason that we assume that the antitrust laws bring |
10 | something positive to the economy. |
11 | The antitrust laws reflect a belief in a |
12 | competitive model, and it seems to me that forced |
13 | sharing, which I think is a fair way to describe as a |
14 | corollary to the refusals to deal area, in essence |
15 | replaces the competition with regulation. I don't think |
16 | we can imagine any remedy to a refusal to deal case that |
17 | is not in some very substantial sense regulatory. And |
18 | you can talk about the various models and Steve has made |
19 | a serious attempt to describe how one may engage in that |
20 | regulation, but I think we have to call it what it is, |
21 | which is price regulation of every firm that is being |
22 | forced to share. |
23 | Now, Trinko was a step in the right direction, |
24 | in general terms, in the sense that it expressed a |
25 | skepticism about refusals to deal and a skepticism about |
1 | its cousin essential facilities. But what Trinko didn't |
2 | do, by following this Court's tendency to decide cases |
3 | generically with a sweeping view of the actual holding, |
4 | is the scenario of what exists after Trinko and what has |
5 | been applied by the lower courts following Trinko. |
6 | There are several analytical tests that really are not |
7 | satisfying, that really don't help businesses evaluate |
8 | risk very well, and that really don't pose a meaningful |
9 | way to distinguish between precompetitive and |
10 | anticompetitive conduct. |
11 | Most of these have been referred to already. |
12 | This question of whether one has ever dealt or has |
13 | stopped dealing with a competitor. Well, that may be, |
14 | as a factual matter, something that reduces litigation. |
15 | Whether a firm is more likely to have a happy |
16 | competitor, if you deal with them and stop, that doesn't |
17 | really help us say what is or isn't anticompetitive. |
18 | The question of whether someone's refusal |
19 | relates to intellectual property or not. Not a question |
20 | that Trinko exactly addressed, but certainly an issue |
21 | that now is clear that there is a -- there is arguably a |
22 | different treatment under the law, depending on whether |
23 | you look at Xerox or the decision in Kodak or Trinko. |
24 | Depending on whether the property is intellectual or |
25 | tangible, depending on what circuit you can be sued in. |
1 | The question of intent, and this I think is a |
2 | really important point in understanding why I think we |
3 | should not view unconditional refusals as exclusionary |
4 | at all. The intent by a firm that has developed a |
5 | product or technology is always essentially the same. |
6 | Regardless of how they express it in the conversation or |
7 | in the documentation, that intent is to maximize |
8 | profits, to maximize the returns on the investment in |
9 | that product. |
10 | That intent might be expressed in ways that are |
11 | very pleasing to the ear of the antitrust lawyer or a |
12 | judge or a jury, protecting the intellectual property |
13 | rights. Kodak tells us that that's legitimate and |
14 | contextual. Maximizing returns on investment. As |
15 | opposed to other sorts of ways to describe profit |
16 | maximization, which might in the case of refusal to |
17 | deal, essentially say, keep -- make sure I can keep this |
18 | all to myself. Make sure I can exclude other types of |
19 | service competitors from competing with me. Well, that |
20 | begins to sound like something in the words of the model |
21 | jury instruction that the ABA has put out on refusals to |
22 | deal. Like something that is intended to block |
23 | competitors. |
24 | If you look at the jury instruction that the ABA |
25 | has promulgated in this area, blocking competitors is |
1 | not a legitimate business justification for the refusal |
2 | to deal. Now, how do you distinguish blocking |
3 | competitors from the actual fact of keeping the returns |
4 | for myself, maximizing my profits, maximizing the return |
5 | on my investment. |
6 | So, I think the fact that Trinko has perpetuated |
7 | the law in language that I found so surprising when I |
8 | read it coming from Justice Scalia's process and his |
9 | clerks. This procompetitive zeal, anticompetitive |
10 | malice, language is not helpful. And some of us may |
11 | think, you know, as we see it, the risk here is not that |
12 | our colleagues in the federal agencies are putting forth |
13 | cases, it's that claims will be filed, it's that judges |
14 | will look at the law and conclude that they have to let |
15 | it go to trial, it's that juries will be asked to |
16 | decide, in essence, when you boil it down, whether this |
17 | refusal was good or bad. |
18 | And again, I don't think this is an area where |
19 | we're facing the onslaught of litigation. It is an area |
20 | where I think there is some natural tendencies that |
21 | diminish the number of cases that are filed. Section |
22 | two cases are not quick hits for class action lawyers. |
23 | They're not -- if you get to trial, they're massive and |
24 | resource intensive. They may have settlement value, so |
25 | there is risk. They certainly impose costs on firms |
1 | that have to defend them if they're brought and they |
2 | have to counsel around them if they're not. |
3 | So, I don't think Trinko really settled it. I |
4 | think it was a step, some might say, and Bob might be |
5 | right, it was a signal of a very fundamental or |
6 | philosophical view. The lower courts aren't bound by a |
7 | philosophical view, they're still allowing some cases to |
8 | go through. |
9 | And I think the jury instructions are |
10 | instructive. If you look at monopolization instruction |
11 | two and three, if you put those together and you ask |
12 | yourself, for example, if I'm a firm and I've developed |
13 | a piece of sophisticated equipment, maybe it's got some |
14 | patent protection, maybe other parts of it don't, it has |
15 | parts, integrated parts, I provide service, and for now |
16 | I'm the only service provider and for now I've decided |
17 | not to sell parts, or make it a little bit easier, I've |
18 | decided not to train my competitors. Service |
19 | organizations come to me and want to pay me Steve's |
20 | monopoly price or exclusionary price, they want to pay |
21 | me a lot for service, or service training, train them to |
22 | come in and service my equipment. And I decide I'm not |
23 | going to set up a service operation, I'm not going to |
24 | offer that service to my competitors. And so in the |
25 | short run, I would make a lot of money this quarter if I |
1 | sold my service, but I know over the next two or three |
2 | or four years, my service is going to be substantially |
3 | lower, because I've created competitors in my service |
4 | operation. |
5 | So, then I think we have the profit sacrifice. |
6 | I think if I understand the test, and again, the |
7 | question here is not to criticize the profit sacrifice |
8 | test, it's to say that we really should not put that |
9 | behavior in that test at all, because I don't think it |
10 | should be viewed as exclusionary. |
11 | So, just to finish up, private litigation is |
12 | where the real risk is in many of these areas. It's not |
13 | a question of the floodgates being opened. I think the |
14 | floodgates were probably turned down a bit after Trinko, |
15 | but I think the agencies can be more instructive, and I |
16 | think in the international market, this can be much more |
17 | than theoretical. U.S. enforcers and practitioners and |
18 | academics go out and talk to those in other countries |
19 | who are developing laws or who are developing |
20 | enforcement policy, such as the European Union review of |
21 | Article 82, or who are creating an entirely new |
22 | anti-monopoly law, as is happening in China, we see |
23 | subtle expression of this policy, or in some cases very |
24 | unsubtle expressions, such as an essential facilities |
25 | doctrine written in ways that were similar to the U.S. |
1 | version, or even a doctrine written similarly to some of |
2 | the recent cases in the refusal to deal area. We look |
3 | at that and we're concerned, because we understand how |
4 | it can be used, and in fact, it's likely to effect on |
5 | limiting innovation and being used to confiscate |
6 | property, being used to bring about industrial policy, |
7 | being used to bring about a different economic status |
8 | that some regulator may prefer than the one that would |
9 | happen if people who innovated brought in terms of |
10 | innovation. |
11 | And when we are commenting on those issues, and |
12 | I've experienced this myself, sometimes the audience |
13 | says yes, but you have the essential facilities |
14 | doctrine, or you have refusals to deal. In fact, we've |
15 | basically taken this out of cases, post-Trinko cases, |
16 | and these are the questions that we're going to empower |
17 | our regulators to ask, and by the way, very substantial |
18 | fines or other penalties that can come into play for the |
19 | violations. I think the way that would be described in |
20 | other countries, I think that is diminished when we |
21 | still have work to do in cleaning up the vestiges of |
22 | these sorts of policies in our own law. I think this |
23 | could be applied to refusals to deal. |
24 | (Applause. ) |
25 | MR. ABBOTT: Thanks, Mark, for bringing in the |
1 | international dimension and the vagaries of juries and |
2 | jury instructions. Quite interesting. We are going to |
3 | take a ten-minute break now, and I would urge people to |
4 | try and get back here as promptly as possible. Thank |
5 | you. |
6 | (Whereupon, there was a recess in the |
7 | proceedings.) |
8 | MR. McDONALD: Ladies and gentlemen, thank you |
9 | for your attention and returning to your seats following |
10 | our very outstanding presentations from the panel. As |
11 | promised, we will ask the panelists to take about three |
12 | minutes each to respond to panelists' remarks, to defend |
13 | their remarks and to defend their honor. We will go in |
14 | the initial order that they made their presentations. |
15 | Bill Kolasky? |
16 | MR. KOLASKY: Thank you. Thank you very much, |
17 | Bruce. I realized when I sat down that I hadn't really |
18 | gotten to the punchline of my presentation, which was |
19 | how do you apply the Section 2 depth-wise sliding scale |
20 | rule of reason to refusals to deal. And so I just |
21 | wanted to sort of move through that very quickly. |
22 | First, I agree with those who say, and Mark Whitener in |
23 | particular, that in general unconditional, unilateral |
24 | refusals to deal ought not to be unlawful. And so I |
25 | think in evaluating competitive effects in the first |
1 | step of the rule of reason analysis, courts should |
2 | distinguish sharply between a simple unilateral refusal |
3 | to deal, and a refusal that is part of a broader pattern |
4 | of anticompetitive conduct. |
5 | The classic example of that is the MCI/AT&T |
6 | case, where AT&T basically played rope a dope with MCI |
7 | in their negotiations over interconnection and their |
8 | misuse of the regulatory process through sham |
9 | litigation. That was what really constituted the |
10 | exclusionary conduct. |
11 | Second, in evaluating proper justifications, |
12 | courts should, and here I agree completely with Hew, as |
13 | Phil Areeda used to say, courts should really take into |
14 | account macro justifications, namely that they should |
15 | recognize that a monopolist's desire to capture the |
16 | value of its investments and innovation is part of what |
17 | stimulates the economy. It is competition on the |
18 | merits, and it is a legitimate business justification in |
19 | and of itself. |
20 | Third, as with any rule of reason test, with |
21 | respect to refusals to deal, the degree of scrutiny of |
22 | the proffered business justifications, including that |
23 | one, should depend on the strength of the showing of |
24 | anticompetitive effect. But most importantly, courts |
25 | should not substitute their judgment for that of the |
1 | monopolist, as to its business strategies, as to what is |
2 | the most profitable business strategy. And then |
3 | finally, again agreeing with Hew, courts should not |
4 | impose any remedy that they cannot efficiently enforce. |
5 | I know we're going to talk about the |
6 | efficient -- the essential facilities doctrine, so I am |
7 | going to save my remarks on that until we get to it. |
8 | Thanks. |
9 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Bob Pitofsky? |
10 | MR. PITOFSKY: Bill, let me start off with a |
11 | question, in your sliding scale approach to refusals to |
12 | deal, which I found very helpful, but what do you do |
13 | with a situation, you get to step three, the defendant |
14 | says, well, I had these good business reasons, and then |
15 | you say, well, the burden is now on the plaintiff to |
16 | show that they are not persuasive. And suppose the |
17 | plaintiff somehow falls short? Is that -- that's the |
18 | end of the deal? |
19 | MR. KOLASKY: No, I think that there could be a |
20 | case in which the plaintiff is not able to rebut the |
21 | justifications, but nevertheless shows that there are |
22 | anticompetitive effects, and you might have to engage in |
23 | a balancing then of the anticompetitive effects against |
24 | the procompetitive benefits of the conduct. My point is |
25 | simply, if you look at Section 1, rule of reason cases, |
1 | courts almost never reach that fourth step, and I doubt |
2 | that they would reach it very often in Section 2 cases. |
3 | MR. PITOFSKY: I think that's fine, I |
4 | couldn't -- I'm comfortable, entirely comfortable with |
5 | where you are, and I think the emphasis on why they did |
6 | it and what their reasons are is certainly where the |
7 | emphasis should be, and if you get to step four, where |
8 | you have to balance anticompetitive effects against |
9 | something, you know, it's really a crap shoot, and very |
10 | hard to expect the judges, much less juries to do that |
11 | in a reasonable and rational way. And I don't end up |
12 | agreeing with too many people up here. |
13 | Mark, I think your unconditional refusal to |
14 | deal, conditional refusal to deal is an excellent way of |
15 | introducing the subject. I'm just a little |
16 | uncomfortable with absolute select safe harbor. I go |
17 | along with you as far as strong, strong presumption, but |
18 | then I sort of get off the train, because I worry about |
19 | the really unusual case, and I think IHS in Europe, and |
20 | I'm not one to know enough about it, but I'm going to |
21 | oversimplify it. A company with a monopoly position on |
22 | a form of intellectual property says I will deal with A, |
23 | B, C and D, that's all fine, I'll work out the terms, |
24 | but as far as X, you've already said that you want |
25 | access because you want to be my rival, and I'm not |
1 | going to do that. And I refuse to deal with you. And |
2 | then it turns out on careful analysis that the alleged |
3 | investment, all the incentive, all the work that the |
4 | monopolist is supposed to do, approached zero. This |
5 | monopoly fell in its lap, and yet it refuses to license |
6 | a rival. It is, it is a sort of an unconditional |
7 | refusal to deal, but I would like someone to take a look |
8 | at it. I would like to not close the door before a |
9 | little more analysis takes place. |
10 | Third, I mentioned that I looked carefully at |
11 | Greg Werden's piece on no economic sacrifice of profits. |
12 | You know, when you get to the end, after all the talk |
13 | about universal meetings, he has a balancing test in |
14 | there, too. So, there's going to have to be some sort |
15 | of balance, and I'll stop there. |
16 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Hew? |
17 | MR. PATE: Not surprisingly, I would like to |
18 | close the door, and I think when Steve and I have talked |
19 | about this, he says in a way, my part of this is much |
20 | easier, because basically everything I'm saying boils |
21 | down to don't try this at home. And that's right. And |
22 | it may be fine for Professor Salop to put -- charge up |
23 | and to propose formulas, but the basic thrust of my |
24 | presentation is that if businesses are required to |
25 | undergo this sort of exercise in district courts in |
1 | front of juries, that the uncertainty and the lack of |
2 | predictability that is created are going to be harmful |
3 | to economic activity. That does not make me, as Alden |
4 | suggested, an antitrust skeptic, it makes me a skeptic |
5 | about the ability of antitrust to provide general rules |
6 | that should require firms to assist their rivals. |
7 | I'm not a skeptic about doing this in Section 1, |
8 | in the same way, I think some of the examples that Steve |
9 | mentioned in terms of the Halliburton example, reaching |
10 | an agreement not to compete in Kansas in return for |
11 | getting transportation in Iraq, or what have you, you |
12 | know, that's a Section 1 agreement not to compete. It |
13 | need not be characterized as a Section 2 refusal to |
14 | assist, and I don't think that there's any slippery |
15 | slope that leads from saying you shouldn't have that |
16 | sort of duty to authorizing everything else. |
17 | As to the balancing test and the meet for the |
18 | case and these sorts of things, the problem is that the |
19 | information to make these decisions is not going to be |
20 | available to businesses at the time they have to decide |
21 | whether to undertake the unilateral conduct, and |
22 | deciding what the consumer welfare effects are going to |
23 | be is extremely difficult. It is not the same as what |
24 | the agencies do or purport to do in a merger context, |
25 | where both parties have voluntarily entered into a |
1 | transaction knowing that all of their information is |
2 | going to be available, that third party information is |
3 | going to be available, and that a prediction can be |
4 | made. Very different from making a business decision |
5 | exante about whether to undertake competitive activity |
6 | and risk capital. |
7 | So, Bob concedes that step four is a crap shoot, |
8 | if you get to it, I think steps three are a crap shoot, |
9 | too, because we're going to be rummaging around in files |
10 | looking for sound bits from sales executives memos and |
11 | the like if we're going to embrace an intent base |
12 | approach to all this. |
13 | So, to me, I'm very attracted to Mark Whitener's |
14 | idea that just carve out the idea of a unilateral |
15 | unconditional refusal to assist a competitor. Many of |
16 | the cases that are going to be litigated won't be that |
17 | simple, but if we had agreement on that, as a very |
18 | clear, crisp proposition, it would certainly be helpful |
19 | in terms of how the case would be analyzed thereafter. |
20 | IMS Health and IP, there's some different things |
21 | there, I think that, you know, maybe a copyright was |
22 | recognized in a system that shouldn't, but I really do |
23 | think that if you're going to grant an IP right, which |
24 | should provide very great certainty, and then leave the |
25 | door just a little bit open to analyzing case by case |
1 | whether enough effort was put into the innovation, that |
2 | can't be a sensible way to run an IP system. |
3 | So, if there's a problem with the IP system, |
4 | maybe that needs to get fixed, as a better way to |
5 | approach those sorts of situations. Thanks. |
6 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Steve? |
7 | MR. SALOP: I guess I want to make three |
8 | comments. The first is that I heard a lot of criticisms |
9 | of intent tests, but no, the sacrifice standard, the NES |
10 | standard is inherently an intent test. It's just an |
11 | intent test that doesn't work -- that doesn't |
12 | quantitatively, but does it in an objective way. That |
13 | it's fundamentally an intent test, we're trying to |
14 | figure out whether the sole purpose of the conduct was |
15 | to generate monopoly power. |
16 | With respect to balancing, I find I have to |
17 | disagree with Bob, it's not trying to -- it's not some |
18 | sort of social balancing adding up the social debits and |
19 | credits. What it actually is is trying to figure out |
20 | the effect on consumers, and I think that's different, |
21 | because it's more -- it is something that is more |
22 | objective. |
23 | For example, just like in mergers, you do |
24 | balancing efficiencies and -- efficiency effects and |
25 | market power effects, but in the end, the question is: |
1 | Is the merger going to raise prices? And so I wouldn't |
2 | call it -- act as if it's some kind of open-ended |
3 | balancing, it's something that's really fairly |
4 | objective. |
5 | The general criticism that balancing tests are a |
6 | crap shoot, you know, there are balancing tests all over |
7 | the law. All over the place. And a generalized |
8 | criticism that courts aren't good at balancing, well, |
9 | that's pretty much what courts do. In negligence cases, |
10 | in first -- in due process cases and so on. |
11 | Finally, don't do this at home, Mark said, |
12 | whether or not we do it at home, we shouldn't let the |
13 | Chinese do it. |
14 | (Laughter.) |
15 | MR. SALOP: In the end, this don't do it at home |
16 | argument always comes down to saying you want to |
17 | eliminate the jury system, and/or generalist judges. |
18 | And, you know, if you think that antitrust is beyond the |
19 | capability of juries, and you want to get Congress to |
20 | change the rules or amend the constitution, and have it |
21 | all done by an expert agency, like the FTC, well then go |
22 | after that. That's an issue of throwing the baby out |
23 | with the bath water. If it's a problem of the juries |
24 | can't do it, then get somebody to make the decisions |
25 | that are good at it. And just like if antitrust isn't |
1 | up to the task of maintaining competition or economy, |
2 | well then maybe we have to go with regulation, but you |
3 | have to solve the problem in a way that's tailored to |
4 | what the problem really is, not some other problem. |
5 | So, for example, dealing with a -- if you don't |
6 | like the law, the issue is change the law, don't change |
7 | the standard itself, and that would be another example |
8 | of something that the courts might do. I say the way to |
9 | make antitrust coherent is that another 30 years from |
10 | now we don't make fun of the dark ages now is to make |
11 | sure that the rules make logical sense, rational |
12 | economic sense, not just the goal-oriented to solving |
13 | the problem of higher prices. |
14 | MR. WALTON: I guess I'm still worried about the |
15 | remedy in the Hughes case and I go back to the testimony |
16 | for 19 years the Commission tried to get us to sell |
17 | these crash parts to all vehicles and customers, at the |
18 | same prices, terms and conditions of sale, this is their |
19 | words, said prices to be subject to reasonable cost |
20 | justified quantity discounts and documents. We argued |
21 | for 19 years on what that meant. We have very good |
22 | economists, excellent economists at the Federal Trade |
23 | Commission, we had economists elsewhere and we could |
24 | never come to an agreement as to what that meant. |
25 | The Commission finally 19 years later said they |
1 | didn't want to have anything to do with it. They said |
2 | they didn't want to "commit extensive resources to |
3 | redoing GM's interpretations to whom and what price it |
4 | should sell its crash parts." |
5 | The other thing is, why do we have a dealer |
6 | list? One of the major reasons we have a dealer |
7 | distribution system is we don't know what the price |
8 | should be. That's a subject between the dealer and the |
9 | dealer's customers and the region in which the dealer |
10 | operates. It depends on the trade-in analysis the |
11 | dealer gets on the car, that's part of the price, it |
12 | depends on financing, insuring, there's no way that we |
13 | in Detroit, folks in the central office, can tell the |
14 | dealer what price to charge for its products. |
15 | And then how, if we didn't do it, how can |
16 | someone in the court, the jury, or the government figure |
17 | out what the prices should be? That just goes to, I |
18 | think, basically the onus that debate has been won and |
19 | lost on what's been more effective, central planning or |
20 | decentralized markets, and it's decentralized markets |
21 | that we're trying to take advantage of in our dealer |
22 | distribution system. That's it. |
23 | MR. WHITENER: Okay, well, on the Chinese point, |
24 | I think what I'm trying to say is when we say to them |
25 | don't do it, we're essentially saying, do as I say, not |
1 | as I do. So, I don't think it's credible if we say |
2 | don't do it if we're doing it. |
3 | On the sort of regulation point, taking a point |
4 | that Bob made, sort of a general sense that you don't |
5 | want to slam the door on the rare case that might be |
6 | meritorious. You put that alongside Steve's concern |
7 | that if we withdraw antitrust from the field, we're |
8 | inviting sort of massive direct regulation that we |
9 | might -- and we might, you know, regret. It seems to me |
10 | that if you put those two together, the instances when |
11 | real intervention to force some holder of a bottleneck, |
12 | or a dominant standard that's durable, the instances |
13 | when that's really going to be in the public interest |
14 | are going to be rare, and my point is that that's |
15 | something that antitrust is not really set up to do. |
16 | So, if you encounter one of those situations, to |
17 | Bob's point, when you haven't slammed the door on the |
18 | government's ability to exercise the power to take, or |
19 | to regulate. But that's the proper way to do it, |
20 | because that's in essence what you're doing, not really |
21 | applying the antitrust standards that are going to be |
22 | applied to other types of cases. |
23 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. We have developed a |
24 | list of propositions that we would like to get the |
25 | response of the panelists to, both in terms of |
1 | determining whether there's a general consensus or |
2 | perhaps a widespread disagreement on these propositions, |
3 | and also to get their more in-depth views on these |
4 | particular points. |
5 | Let's start with one on the essential facilities |
6 | doctrine as distinct from the refusals to deal more |
7 | generally. Could I have by show of hands from the panel |
8 | whether they agree with the proposition that courts |
9 | should abandon the essential facilities doctrine. |
10 | MR. SALOP: Could you define essential |
11 | facilities doctrine so we know which one you're |
12 | referring to? |
13 | MR. McDONALD: That is actually a question that |
14 | I've got for the panel, so if you want to abstain for |
15 | the moment, let's see the hands -- |
16 | MR. SALOP: I'll abstain until I find out what |
17 | the doctrine is. |
18 | MR. McDONALD: Those who agree with the |
19 | proposition. Very good. Bob Pitofsky, it would be |
20 | helpful to know from you as one of the proponents of a |
21 | rare essential facilities doctrine is what does it mean, |
22 | and is there a requirement, or do the general |
23 | requirements of Section 2 apply when you're bringing an |
24 | essential facilities claim? Do you, for example, have |
25 | to show the representing competitive effect? |
1 | MR. PITOFSKY: Well, I think that if you sum up |
2 | the four qualifications in MCI, which virtually every |
3 | lower court adheres to, then you, in effect, you have |
4 | found an anticompetitive effect. And the four I believe |
5 | was: This only applies to monopolists, it must truly be |
6 | essential, you can't compete without it, and therefore |
7 | if the monopolist doesn't make it available, it won't be |
8 | in the competition. The monopolist has requested and |
9 | denies making it available, and -- oh, and that it's |
10 | feasible to make it available. There aren't any |
11 | chemical engineering business reasons why it can't be |
12 | done. |
13 | If all of those circumstances are true, and they |
14 | will rarely all be present, then it seems to me that |
15 | allowing the monopolist to charge any price it chooses |
16 | up to the point where substitute products can become |
17 | available, is not a good idea. You're better off |
18 | cautiously making essential facilities doctrine actual. |
19 | MR. McDONALD: So, your point is at least under |
20 | the first two elements of the MCI test implicitly |
21 | incorporate the rest of Section 2? |
22 | MR. PITOFSKY: I think so. |
23 | MR. McDONALD: Is there anyone who wants to |
24 | disagree with that and say we ought to demand more for |
25 | any sort of essential facilities case? |
1 | MR. KOLASKY: I'll take the bait, I think you |
2 | should do that, because the first two, as I understand |
3 | those requirements, is simply that the monopolist has an |
4 | essential facility, that it owns and controls an |
5 | essential facility, and that it has a monopoly, and that |
6 | the plaintiff is going to -- or the rival is not able to |
7 | duplicate that facility. I think if you allow the |
8 | essential facilities test to be imposed on that basis, |
9 | then you really are in an area where you're going to |
10 | have compulsory sharing in lots of cases. |
11 | And I guess one question I would like to turn |
12 | and put to Bob, as an advocate of the essential |
13 | facilities doctrine, is: Would you apply the doctrine |
14 | in cases of intellectual property, because there, when |
15 | you're talking about patents and copyrights, it's going |
16 | to be rare that the defendant would be able to show that |
17 | it's not feasible to make the essential facility |
18 | available? |
19 | MR. PITOFSKY: That's a good question, and the |
20 | answer is that I am not sure it does apply with |
21 | intellectual property. I think that's where the case |
22 | law now is. |
23 | MR. McDONALD: Steve Salop, did your fellow |
24 | panelists answer your question or would you like to |
25 | yourself pose what the essential facilities doctrine |
1 | ought to look like? |
2 | MR. SALOP: Well, I set out my -- I set out my |
3 | standard, I think in cases where it's a really big |
4 | monopoly, you know, I mean, you know, I -- the first |
5 | couple of MCI prongs or about monopoly power in the two |
6 | markets, so I would say in the situation where it's a |
7 | really big monopoly and in a very important market, then |
8 | maybe it will weaken the plaintiff's need to show as |
9 | much anticompetitive effect, and you use my prong two |
10 | test as a way to determine the rate that's pressed, and |
11 | that would be the way to handle it. You would have to |
12 | worry there about incentives, and I think you would, but |
13 | yeah, I think it's -- I think it is something that we |
14 | should do where it's a really important monopoly. |
15 | You know, there's a lot of markets where |
16 | normally, take Trinko, something like Trinko, that you |
17 | say, oh well, the regulator is going to get it. But, |
18 | you know, it's an accident of history that this industry |
19 | has been regulated and say operating systems are not |
20 | being regulated. So, the question is, what do you do |
21 | where you have like a big monopoly, if this was -- if |
22 | the FCC had made the decision 25 years ago to include |
23 | operating systems in its jurisdiction and it had held up |
24 | with the courts well then, you know, the case in Europe |
25 | that, you know, some of the prongs in the case here |
1 | would have gone to the FCC and we would be in a |
2 | situation like Trinko. They would have made a decision |
3 | of whether or not Microsoft had to "share," had to give |
4 | access to the information that they wanted in Europe to |
5 | the APIs or to look into the operating systems of |
6 | someone here. But Microsoft turns out not to be |
7 | regulated. Nobody took on the task of regulation. |
8 | So, the question is, should the court take over |
9 | the regulation, and I agree there is regulation, should |
10 | the court take over the regulation when nobody else is |
11 | doing it, or where the company otherwise isn't |
12 | regulated. I don't see why not. You know, it's not as |
13 | if courts never do that. Gas prices have been regulated |
14 | since 1950, for example. There are little places where |
15 | district courts are acting like regulators. They're |
16 | extreme, I agree they're extreme, and they're rare, but |
17 | it's not to say that it should never be done. And I |
18 | don't think that's all Bob is trying to get at by |
19 | preserving the essential facilities doctrine for |
20 | extraordinary cases. |
21 | MR. McDONALD: Hew, do you have a comment on the |
22 | implication of applying the essential facilities |
23 | doctrine in the intellectual property area? |
24 | MR. PATE: Sure, I would say before that, I |
25 | don't think it's an accident of history that some of |
1 | these cases occur in situations where the State had |
2 | previously put a firm in a monopoly position and tried |
3 | to interfere in the first place and the law is trying to |
4 | introduce competition. I don't think it's an accident. |
5 | As to IP, yes, I think the interesting thing |
6 | about the MCI, the four-part test, is it would be a very |
7 | good way to describe exactly what the patent system is |
8 | trying to incentivize, and the paradigm of the most |
9 | valuable patent that produces something brand new that's |
10 | extremely valuable, that nobody can duplicate, and we |
11 | have a patent system that says, in order to incentivize |
12 | that, you ought to have the exclusive right to it. And |
13 | it just can't make sense, in my judgment, for antitrust |
14 | then to come along and second guess that. |
15 | We're seeing that now in Europe, where the |
16 | question is on the table whether it was sufficiently |
17 | innovative intellectual property to be protected in the |
18 | trade secret realm, for example, and I think that's just |
19 | a very disorderly way to go forward, because it damages |
20 | the predictability on which businesses rely to commit |
21 | capital. |
22 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Steve, did you start |
23 | to respond? |
24 | MR. SALOP: I just wanted to make a footnote to |
25 | what you said. I mean, the court didn't create the Ma |
1 | Bell monopoly, the Ma Bell monopoly got created by a |
2 | series of mergers and certain conduct that was declared |
3 | not to follow antitrust laws. It was not as if the |
4 | government said all of these competing telephone |
5 | companies can merge. |
6 | MR. PATE: No, but there was a state sanctioned |
7 | local loop monopoly in place was what I was suggesting. |
8 | Not that -- not that the court ordered the creation of a |
9 | monopoly. |
10 | MR. SALOP: Well, they didn't disagree, they |
11 | didn't break up the operating companies 80 years ago. |
12 | They didn't. It's not like they made them do it. They |
13 | committed. |
14 | MR. PITOFSKY: Just one line. Look, the fact is |
15 | lower courts have mandated access in situations where |
16 | intellectual property was involved, and I didn't notice |
17 | that it asked for investments or anything on patent work |
18 | or intellectual property followed that, but I have to |
19 | agree with you. The essential facilities doctrine runs |
20 | head on into the very purpose of the patent system, and |
21 | underlying that purpose, when the patent system is out |
22 | of control, and this is for a different panel, but it's |
23 | just, it leaves you with a feeling that essential |
24 | facilities wasn't designed to do that. |
25 | MR. McDONALD: The last comment, Bill Kolasky? |
1 | MR. KOLASKY: I guess I will make what I call |
2 | the Robert Bork point, and that is that all of the |
3 | discussion so far has been about policy reasons why you |
4 | should or should not have an essential facilities |
5 | doctrine. There really is a more fundamental point, and |
6 | that is the language and the congressional intent |
7 | underlying Section 2. Section 2 is designed to prohibit |
8 | affirmative conduct that is designed to gain a monopoly |
9 | through improper means. And I don't think that you can |
10 | use Section 2 to impose an affirmative duty on someone |
11 | to share, unless they have taken affirmative acts to |
12 | acquire or maintain their monopoly by improper means. |
13 | Simply not sharing is not an affirmative act. I mean, |
14 | you contrast that to the affirmative acts that were |
15 | taken by Aspen Ski Co., which went beyond a simple |
16 | refusal to deal. |
17 | MR. WHITENER: Right, and that was essentially |
18 | the comment that I was trying to make, there's no |
19 | essential principle, once you declare that retaining is |
20 | maintaining. Yes, we can understand how the English |
21 | language can be used if I say that I take steps to |
22 | retain my rights and not share them, I'm maintaining a |
23 | monopoly if there's a monopoly on the product. But |
24 | that's semantics. That's the point I was trying to |
25 | make. |
1 | A minute ago Steve said I thought basically that |
2 | it's an accident of history that some segments are |
3 | regulated and some aren't, and therefore some courts |
4 | should and do step into those voids where the lack of |
5 | regulations occurred. I think if I understood it right, |
6 | that's a fundamental -- well, I don't agree with that |
7 | idea of the political system, the regulatory act is |
8 | conscious, a lack of regulation is the result of a |
9 | judgment at some level of the political administrative |
10 | system, that there's not going to be regulation, and my |
11 | point is that those -- it's in the political process |
12 | where decisions expressly to regulate a particular |
13 | sector, to re-allocate resources, to take to cap prices, |
14 | et cetera, those should be made in the political |
15 | process, not where courts decide that a failure to |
16 | regulate is a mistake. |
17 | MR. McDONALD: Very strong points. Shall we |
18 | move to the second proposition? |
19 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, the second proposition is the |
20 | antitrust laws should never require a firm to deal with |
21 | a rival. Who agrees with this proposition? |
22 | MR. PITOFSKY: Wait, wait, wait, what does it |
23 | mean? Does never include remedy law? That after you |
24 | found a violation on some basis, remedy is mandating the |
25 | theory? |
1 | MR. ABBOTT: Let's stipulate, I'll say, that we |
2 | have not found an antitrust violation and assume as part |
3 | of a remedy certainly that's been required and so let's |
4 | stipulate that's not included in the statement. |
5 | MR. KOLASKY: So you're assuming this is a |
6 | liability question? |
7 | MR. ABBOTT: Right, so this is a very broad |
8 | question, that the antitrust laws should never require a |
9 | firm to deal with a rival. |
10 | MR. SALOP: We each answered this question |
11 | already. |
12 | MR. ABBOTT: Well -- |
13 | MR. WHITENER: If a refusal is unconditional, I |
14 | agree with the statement. |
15 | MR. ABBOTT: Is there anybody else who would say |
16 | if the refusal is unconditional, they agree with this |
17 | statement? Mark and Hew? |
18 | MR. PATE: Unilateral and unconditional, I |
19 | assume you're meaning. |
20 | MR. ABBOTT: Unilateral and unconditional. |
21 | Because clearly if you add conditional, then the |
22 | conditions can mimic, you know, tying, exclusive |
23 | dealing, other arrangements. So, clearly, good point. |
24 | So -- |
25 | MR. WHITENER: And Bob makes a good point, too, |
1 | excepting other situations where you're recommending a |
2 | merger. |
3 | MR. ABBOTT: Right. Sure, sure. So, I think |
4 | the panel has ably pointed out that the statement was -- |
5 | MR. SALOP: I have a question. I have a |
6 | question. On this word unconditional, if two companies |
7 | go to the monopolist and they both want to buy the input |
8 | and one says -- and he says why do you want it? And one |
9 | says I want it to enter a market and compete with you, |
10 | and the other says I want it to put on my coffee table, |
11 | and he gives it to the second but not the first, is that |
12 | conditional or unconditional? |
13 | MR. WHITENER: He doesn't give it to the firm |
14 | who says he wants to buy it to compete with you, right? |
15 | That shouldn't be unlawful. There's no condition |
16 | whatsoever. |
17 | MR. SALOP: I'm sorry. |
18 | MR. KOLASKY: There is a condition. I will not |
19 | sell it to you unless you agree not to sell it to me. |
20 | MR. WHITENER: No, I'm not going to sell to |
21 | somebody who is a competitor or who is going to use the |
22 | product to compete with me. That's -- |
23 | MR. SALOP: Can I just get where you're going? |
24 | If he says I'm not going to sell to anybody unless he |
25 | agrees not to compete. Is that legal? |
1 | MR. WHITENER: No, that's illegal. Let's put it |
2 | this way, if you want to call the fact that it's a |
3 | competitor a condition, I'll grant that. I don't think |
4 | I'm going to grant anything else, but I'll grant that. |
5 | If you want to say that the fact that -- |
6 | MR. SALOP: I don't believe that you still |
7 | believe in so much in RPM law. I mean, here we are in |
8 | the thick of Parke-Davis versus Dr. Miles, this is -- |
9 | MR. WHITENER: No, I think you're distinguishing |
10 | between agreements and unilateral practice is important |
11 | in a lot of settings, including this one. |
12 | MR. SALOP: So, if he has a history in which |
13 | 5,000 people have asked him to sell, and half of them |
14 | don't compete and they get it, and the other half which |
15 | did want to compete, who said, just stupidly said to the |
16 | guy, when they asked for the product, that they were |
17 | going to compete, he said no to them, but you would not |
18 | infer that illegal agreement? |
19 | MR. WHITENER: Not illegal for the firm -- |
20 | MR. SALOP: Should it get to the jury as to |
21 | whether there was an agreement or not or is that as a |
22 | matter of law there was no agreement? |
23 | MR. WHITENER: It didn't sound like agreement |
24 | evidence to me just now, but -- |
25 | MR. PATE: Do you, Steve, feel that field of use |
1 | restrictions and licenses should be subject to antitrust |
2 | scrutiny? IP licenses, patent licenses? I mean? |
3 | MR. SALOP: Subject to the other conditions of |
4 | my rule, but there can be an argument that IP has got |
5 | some special place, you know, I could imagine the |
6 | Supreme Court could make that declaration, but, you |
7 | know, the thing, very few refusals to deal would be |
8 | actionable under my view because very few people have |
9 | the requisite monopoly power in the two markets, but, |
10 | you know, this constitutional question of whether IP is |
11 | different, until the Supreme Court decides it, I'm not |
12 | going to decide it, I'm not going to argue IP. |
13 | MR. ABBOTT: I think there's also, we've |
14 | probably spent a lot of time on IP and I'm sure it will |
15 | rise again. There's also statutory construction |
16 | questions regarding section 271 of the patent act which |
17 | raises questions about whether that section should be |
18 | construed as applying to antitrust or just to so-called |
19 | patent misuse. |
20 | But let me move away from IP for a second and |
21 | relatedly ask what is the difference between charging a |
22 | price higher than a buyer is willing to pay, and |
23 | refusing to deal? One can imagine offering to deal at |
24 | an infinite price is tantamount to refusal to deal, but |
25 | what if you just say, okay, I'm a monopolist, have a |
1 | right to charge my price, and a potential competitor |
2 | says, well, this is just way higher than I'm willing to |
3 | pay. Bill? |
4 | MR. KOLASKY: You know, one of the problems I |
5 | have with -- one of the problems I have with a lot of |
6 | these questions is that antitrust is necessarily a very |
7 | fact-specific field, and it's one of the beauties of the |
8 | common law approach and the rule of reason. And, so, I |
9 | think it's very hard to answer these questions in the |
10 | abstract without knowing the facts of the particular |
11 | case. You have a case such as the MetroNet decision in |
12 | the Ninth Circuit which was decided on remand after the |
13 | Supreme Court's decision in Trinko, where prior to |
14 | Trinko, the Ninth Circuit had held that Quest had to |
15 | make Centrex features available to a reseller at a price |
16 | at which that reseller would be able to resell those |
17 | features profitably. |
18 | On remand, the Ninth Circuit realized the error |
19 | of its ways, which were particularly clear in that case, |
20 | because you had dozens of other resellers who were able |
21 | to compete profitably, buying the features at the price |
22 | that Quest was willing to sell them to this reseller. |
23 | So, my point is simply, you have to look at the |
24 | facts of each individual case, and I don't think you can |
25 | answer it globally. |
1 | MR. ABBOTT: Anybody want to elaborate on that? |
2 | MR. SALOP: Well, I'll just say a word on it. |
3 | You have to distinguish between bargaining failure and |
4 | an anticompetitive refusal to deal. I think that's the |
5 | issue we're getting at. So, you know, aside from |
6 | everything else involved, that might have just been the |
7 | defendant's posted price, and he might say that's the |
8 | price I posted and I might be open to negotiate and the |
9 | plaintiff never even offered me a price, didn't make a |
10 | genuine offer. And I think that the plaintiff should |
11 | have to make a genuine offer over and above the, you |
12 | know, the compensatory price. |
13 | MR. ABBOTT: Hew? |
14 | MR. PATE: I don't think that that distinction |
15 | is going to hold up in practice, and I do think, Alden, |
16 | that it is very difficult to draw this boundary. It has |
17 | been understood, I thought, that American antitrust law |
18 | does not tell the monopolist that it is unlawful to |
19 | charge the monopoly price. That's a difference we have |
20 | with the Europeans, where under article 82, it can be an |
21 | abuse to charge a high price. That is of why it's so |
22 | hard categorically to tell Europeans under their system |
23 | that what they're doing when they look at compelled |
24 | sharing is fundamentally inconsistent with the |
25 | principles of antitrust. I think it is fundamentally |
1 | inconsistent with an important principle of antitrust |
2 | here. |
3 | MR. SALOP: I guess that the refusal to deal |
4 | approach, then, that I'm taking and a lot of other |
5 | economists have taken is the situation where the firm is |
6 | trying to charge a price above the monopoly price, and |
7 | that's -- so, you know, what it's saying is that it's a |
8 | sacrifice of profits in some sense in order to achieve |
9 | and obtain -- |
10 | MR. WHITENER: See, what's not clear to me is |
11 | where the sacrifice is, if I'm charging the profit |
12 | maximizing price for me. You know, at some point I can |
13 | set a price that fully compensates me, not only for what |
14 | I think Steve calls the monopoly price, but the |
15 | exclusionary price. That is the price of not having |
16 | somebody else take this product and compete with me with |
17 | it. I think I'm entitled to charge that, and I think |
18 | what's being proposed is simply a scheme to regulate the |
19 | monopolist pricing, but at a level called something like |
20 | an exclusionary price, rather than the monopoly price. |
21 | It's still essentially third party intervention saying |
22 | we're going to decide what price the monopolist can |
23 | capture for its profit. |
24 | MR. WALTON: I guess I have a problem with how |
25 | do we get this pricing? I just, first of all, what if |
1 | it is a false positive? Then I'm not really a |
2 | monopolist. What if we're misidentified as a false |
3 | positive. Even if we identified you correctly, who's |
4 | going to set this price? I just told you it's very, |
5 | very difficult for someone, even in our position in |
6 | Detroit to set the prices, let alone someone else. So, |
7 | I worry about this stringently. |
8 | MR. ABBOTT: Okay, I suggest we move on to the |
9 | next question. |
10 | MR. McDONALD: A firm can refuse to deal with |
11 | its competitors only if there are legitimate competitive |
12 | reasons for the refusal. The burden of coming forward |
13 | with legitimate competitive reasons has been imposed on |
14 | the defendant. Who agrees with this proposition? |
15 | (No response.) |
16 | MR. McDONALD: Not even Bill Kolasky on the |
17 | step-wise approach? |
18 | MR. SALOP: It doesn't say whether they have |
19 | monopoly power. It doesn't -- |
20 | MR. McDONALD: I would think that would -- I |
21 | would bet that would be implicit. |
22 | MR. SALOP: Are you thinking whether we think |
23 | that Kodak was rightly decided? Is that the question? |
24 | MR. McDONALD: No. Steve? |
25 | MR. SALOP: Actually the opinion of the Supreme |
1 | Court, yes, I thought that opinion was rightly decided, |
2 | I thought the Justice Department and Kodak took a really |
3 | extreme position, and, you know, killing their argument |
4 | was like shooting fish in a barrel. |
5 | MR. PITOFSKY: Disclosure. |
6 | MR. SALOP: And I could write the brief. |
7 | MR. PITOFSKY: I do, too, think Kodak was right. |
8 | This was the famous footnote that caused a lot of people |
9 | to be upset. And I don't believe any subsequent case |
10 | has taken that footnote as accurate. |
11 | MR. McDONALD: Very good. Bill Kolasky, on the |
12 | subject of legitimate reasons, you directed us to |
13 | consider macro reasons, macro justifications, such as |
14 | the defendant's -- a defendant wanting to maintain |
15 | incentives to innovate, a defendant wanting to recoup |
16 | the investment it's made in the innovation. As a |
17 | practical matter, how would a defendant go about proving |
18 | that? |
19 | MR. KOLASKY: I don't think that you need proof |
20 | of that, in an individual case. The analogy I would use |
21 | is to the law in the area of conscious parallelism, |
22 | where one of the reasons why we don't allow conscious |
23 | parallel pricing behavior to be attacked under Section 1 |
24 | is because it is perfectly natural competitive behavior. |
25 | It's the kind of behavior that you would expect of a |
1 | firm in an oligopoly market. |
2 | Similarly, you would expect a firm, including a |
3 | monopolist, that spends good money developing new |
4 | facilities, inventing new products, in order to gain a |
5 | competitive advantage, to want to use those products and |
6 | those facilities for that purpose. And that is a |
7 | legitimate business justification in and of itself. I |
8 | don't think it requires further additional proof. I |
9 | think the burden is really on the plaintiffs then to |
10 | show that there is some other purpose underlying the |
11 | refusal to make the facilities or the inventions |
12 | available. |
13 | MR. McDONALD: That's probably especially |
14 | applicable in the intellectual property context. Any |
15 | comments from the other panelists quickly on this point? |
16 | MR. SALOP: Well, I gave a quote from Kodak on |
17 | this about the limits on this defense. You know, I |
18 | mean, what worries me about it is the proof of |
19 | competitors could equally not well make this argument. |
20 | The group of competitors could say, you know, if we |
21 | can't set the price jointly, we're going to be involved |
22 | in doing this competition, and we won't be able to make |
23 | enough money to re-invest and next thing you know the |
24 | United States is going to lose out to China. And, you |
25 | know, just antitrust categorically does not -- does not |
1 | permit that argument with regard to competition. The |
2 | antitrust courts are very suspicious of that kind of |
3 | argument, and I think we should be when a firm makes it |
4 | as well. |
5 | As for these, you know, expectations, Bill said |
6 | that it's what we expect the firm to do. I mean, I |
7 | don't agree with that. I mean, we expect firms in the |
8 | paper industry to collude, but that doesn't mean we let |
9 | them do it. |
10 | MR. PATE: I don't think this comparison to a |
11 | group of horizontal competitors makes much sense, and |
12 | courts are pretty well equipped to investigate whether |
13 | there has been an agreement among competitors. Firms |
14 | are pretty well equipped to understand that they're not |
15 | supposed to get involved in that kind of conduct, and so |
16 | there the law has a workable mechanism to enforce a |
17 | judgment about whether society is going to be better or |
18 | worse off with that sort of collusion. |
19 | I don't think anybody on the panel would argue |
20 | that if you had a magic machine that would correctly |
21 | tell us the consumer welfare balancing answer, that we |
22 | wouldn't want to impose it. The point is that there is |
23 | no such machine, and in the unilateral context, there's |
24 | no way to give firms a basis on which to make decisions |
25 | about investing capital that is workable when we're |
1 | talking about this category of forced sharing. |
2 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Strong points. |
3 | Moving to the next proposition. |
4 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, next proposition, and don't |
5 | ask me to define the language here, because it's |
6 | Professor Hovenkamp. Herb Hovenkamp, "Condemnation for |
7 | unilateral refusals to deal should be reserved for |
8 | situations in which firms have extraordinary amounts of |
9 | very durable market power." So, extraordinary, very |
10 | durable, and he doesn't define what it means, but do you |
11 | agree with his statement? |
12 | (No response.) |
13 | MR. ABBOTT: So, he's saying here that there |
14 | should be condemnations in the rare instances, for |
15 | instance, where there are extraordinary amounts of very |
16 | durable market power. |
17 | MR. KOLASKY: I suspect you have people |
18 | disagreeing for a lot of different reasons on this one. |
19 | MR. ABBOTT: So, does anyone agree with that? |
20 | MR. SALOP: Well, if you let me define the |
21 | words, I could -- I can define extraordinary amount and |
22 | very durable market power in a way that I agree with it |
23 | 100 percent. |
24 | MR. ABBOTT: Does it make any sense to use those |
25 | terms which by definition are extremely, one might |
1 | argue, open for debate? |
2 | MR. PITOFSKY: You could interpret this as an |
3 | expansion of the essential facilities doctrine, which |
4 | I'm sure Hovenkamp didn't intend. I mean, it's hard to |
5 | deal with really vague language like that. |
6 | MR. KOLASKY: I was going to make the same point |
7 | with the flip side of this. I haven't read this |
8 | particular passage of the antitrust enterprise, but from |
9 | reading his treatise, I would be -- I would be surprised |
10 | if he didn't say this in the context of suggesting how |
11 | the essential facilities doctrine should be limited, and |
12 | if that's the case, you know, my response is since I |
13 | think the essential facilities doctrine should be |
14 | abandoned all together, you know, I suppose if you're |
15 | not going to do that, I would agree it should be limited |
16 | in some way and this is as good a way to limit it as |
17 | any. |
18 | MR. ABBOTT: Mark, do you have any thoughts on |
19 | that? |
20 | MR. WHITENER: Actually, I think I tend to agree |
21 | with what Bill just said. I would eliminate the |
22 | doctrine, but if you couldn't do that, you know, look |
23 | for some limiting factors. I don't think this concept, |
24 | again, going back to my earlier comments, really helps |
25 | you distinguish as a matter of antitrust policy when you |
1 | want to intervene. It's just sort of a directional |
2 | thing that's saying if the, you know, the impact is |
3 | great we're going to intervene and if it's not we |
4 | aren't. But so I think it's better just -- in fact, I |
5 | think this point illustrates why the doctrine probably |
6 | isn't very helpful. |
7 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, why don't we try, I think |
8 | given the inexactitude of the terms here, why don't we |
9 | move to the next proposition. |
10 | MR. McDONALD: This is one that we discussed in |
11 | the forward, the legality of a refusal to deal should |
12 | depend on whether the refusal constitutes a change from |
13 | prior business practices. Hew, you outlined some of the |
14 | reasons that you thought that that was probably |
15 | incorrect. Let's see the vote. |
16 | (No response.) |
17 | MR. McDONALD: Who agrees with this proposition? |
18 | MR. SALOP: May I rephrase the proposition? |
19 | (Laughter.) |
20 | MR. McDONALD: Who invited the economist? |
21 | MR. SALOP: You know, economists go through |
22 | depositions, we know better than to answer questions |
23 | like this. How about you ask whether the refusal |
24 | constitutes a change from prior business practice is a |
25 | relevant fact, agree or disagree. Would you accept that |
1 | rephrasing? |
2 | MR. McDONALD: I'll accept that amendment. |
3 | What's the vote? Hew, do you think it's not relevant? |
4 | MR. PATE: I'm on board for the idea that if |
5 | it's really unilateral and unconditional, I wouldn't |
6 | ask, but is it a relevant fact, I mean I guess that |
7 | describes the current state of the law, and similar to |
8 | Bill's answer, if we're going to get into this |
9 | enterprise, I would make it a relevant fact instead of a |
10 | dispositive fact. So, I guess I would go with you that |
11 | far. |
12 | MR. SALOP: What if you were not sure whether it |
13 | was conditional or unconditional? Would it be relevant |
14 | then? Because you're never sure whether it's |
15 | conditional or unconditional. |
16 | MR. PATE: The way I say it in the written |
17 | paper, do I believe it's relevant, it does provide some |
18 | benchmark, it gives some indication that there was a |
19 | price at which one time there was a willingness to deal. |
20 | I'm not sure that I see why it's relevant to whether -- |
21 | just deciding whether something is conditional or |
22 | unconditional or that I would use it as sort of a tie |
23 | breaker if I wasn't sure. |
24 | MR. SALOP: Oh, no, no, I agree with you, it |
25 | doesn't tell you anything about whether it's conditional |
1 | or unconditional, but if you want per se legality for |
2 | refusals to deal that you know are unconditional, but |
3 | it's potentially actionable if you knew it was |
4 | conditional, then you've got two prongs, you've got two |
5 | issues now, and so the threshold question would be is it |
6 | conditional or not, and once you've answered that, you |
7 | would know where to go. |
8 | So, I'm just suggesting what if you weren't sure |
9 | whether it was conditional. You know, you're going to |
10 | have to have some burden of proof to define at some |
11 | threshold on what defines conditional, and so if there's |
12 | some uncertainty about that, that might take you a step |
13 | further and then this would be relevant. |
14 | MR. PATE: Yeah, I'm not sure I agree that |
15 | there's a connection. Again, I think the relevance is |
16 | that if you were in a situation where the court is going |
17 | to get into policing a duty of forced dealing, then it |
18 | is true that prior practice gives you a starting point |
19 | where the complete absence of prior practice doesn't, |
20 | but that's the best I'll say for it. |
21 | MR. McDONALD: Bob? |
22 | MR. PITOFSKY: I think I -- look, this is a |
23 | response to arguments that the defendant might make. |
24 | The defendant might say, it's not feasible for me to |
25 | make this particular service or facility available, and |
1 | the answer is you used to do it, why can't you do it |
2 | now? Well, the defendant might say, we'll never figure |
3 | out what a fair price is if you mandate the price, and |
4 | the answer is, well, you seem to have come up with a |
5 | fair price before. In that sense, it could be a factor. |
6 | Is it really the heart of the matter, is it dispositive? |
7 | I don't think so. |
8 | MR. McDONALD: Don't you think, Bob, that in |
9 | Aspen and in Trinko's characterization of Aspen, this |
10 | was a liability factor? |
11 | MR. PITOFSKY: The court made a fair amount |
12 | about the Aspen, I -- I wouldn't do it that way. The |
13 | fact that it's a departure from my entire business, it's |
14 | one factor among five or six others, and I wouldn't even |
15 | make it high on my list of factors. |
16 | MR. McDONALD: Okay. I'm getting strong |
17 | endorsement of this. |
18 | MR. KOLASKY: Can we just follow up on that. |
19 | And I think Aspen really illustrates the problem very |
20 | well. You know, I agree completely with Bob. I think |
21 | it's a relevant factor, but by no means a dispositive |
22 | factor. I think what the court found particularly |
23 | relevant about it in Aspen was that Ski Co. had entered |
24 | into the multi-mountain pass at a time when the three |
25 | mountains that it later owned were separately owned. |
1 | And, so, you know, there was a belief that a basis for |
2 | concluding that in a competitive market, you would have |
3 | a multi-mountain pass that covered all of the mountains |
4 | in that particular area, and the same was true at other |
5 | areas around the country where there were multiple |
6 | peaks, including ones in which Ski Co. operated, so |
7 | there was a good basis for the court to believe, and |
8 | infer, that it was a profitable, procompetitive, |
9 | cooperative arrangement that benefited consumers. |
10 | The problem with it in Aspen, if you look |
11 | closely at the facts, and there's a very good article in |
12 | the Antitrust Law Journal by Lopatka and Page which |
13 | could do that, is that, you know, they show that given |
14 | the way the revenue sharing was done in Aspen, Highlands |
15 | was benefitting disproportionately to Ski Co., and, you |
16 | know, I think Steve and I may disagree about the facts |
17 | of the case on this, you could actually argue that all |
18 | that Ski Co. was trying to do in that case was to |
19 | renegotiate the price. You know, there was some bravado |
20 | in the language they used about making an offer to |
21 | Highlands that it couldn't accept, but that's the sort |
22 | of thing people often kind of, you know, overstate and |
23 | that often engage in when they're in tough negotiations. |
24 | MR. McDONALD: Facts are important. Steve, you |
25 | have a point on this and Tom Walton had his hand up, |
1 | too. |
2 | MR. SALOP: I was going to say that the Trinko |
3 | court is all over the place on this, because there was |
4 | a, you know, a lot of different conduct, as Bill pointed |
5 | out, in Aspen. With respect to the sharing of, you |
6 | know, with respect to the joint ticket, that was |
7 | collusion. So, you know, and indeed they were sued by |
8 | the Colorado Attorney General for it. So, yeah, in some |
9 | sense, all they were trying to do, on that part, they |
10 | were just trying to redistribute cartel profits. |
11 | I think what the -- what the part of Aspen that |
12 | the Trinko court endorsed was not about the four |
13 | mountain pass, though they talked about the four |
14 | mountain pass. They were really animated, as I am, |
15 | about the fact that they refused to sell daily tickets |
16 | in bulk or indeed at retail to Highlands, even though |
17 | they sold them to a lot of other people. And that's the |
18 | part that really showed the sacrifice. And, you know, |
19 | so the part that's the outer boundary of antitrust, it's |
20 | not the refusal to sell daily tickets, I would say, you |
21 | know, which is well within the refusal of the law, but |
22 | the fact that you find a firm liable for a Section 2 |
23 | violation for refusing to sell to its competitor. |
24 | MR. McDONALD: Tom Walton? |
25 | MR. WALTON: I'm not an expert in any of this, |
1 | which is why I'm abstaining from most of the questions. |
2 | One thing that's been addressed partially, I think it's |
3 | important that if someone had decided that Chrysler had |
4 | tried the system that the Commission was recommending, |
5 | that we could somehow have a burden to go back to that |
6 | failing system. |
7 | MR. SALOP: Actually, if you show they failed, |
8 | it would be important -- but if they succeeded. |
9 | MR. WALTON: I think it did in that case, the |
10 | ALJ, the Administrative Law Judge did take that into |
11 | account in his decision that there were competitive |
12 | reasons, efficiency reasons for adopting this. |
13 | MR. PATE: And it only took 17 years, 19, yeah. |
14 | MR. SALOP: What do you expect in the Nixon |
15 | antitrust with Muris and Jim Miller. I mean, they were |
16 | just very slow and much too interventionalist. |
17 | MR. KOLASKY: If I can just respond to Steve's |
18 | point, because one thing that I, you know, Aspen really |
19 | illustrates how you have to be careful here. The mere |
20 | fact that Ski Co. was not willing to sell tickets to |
21 | Highlands at the retail price, does not necessarily show |
22 | that their decision made no economic sense and was not |
23 | profit maximizing. If the availability of the four |
24 | mountain pass diverted a large enough number of skiers |
25 | from the three Ski Co. mountains to Highlands, then even |
1 | if Highlands was willing to pay the full retail price |
2 | where the Ski Co. tickets had sold, it could be a |
3 | money-losing proposition for Aspen, depending on how the |
4 | revenue sharing was done. |
5 | MR. SALOP: I agree with that, that's a footnote |
6 | in my paper, and interestingly, what's really actually |
7 | interesting about the Trinko court, is they did not |
8 | balance the losses in the one market against the gains |
9 | in the other. When they did their profit sacrifice |
10 | test, they took the very superficial naive approach. |
11 | They said, oh, you sacrificed profits on the daily |
12 | ticket, that's it, that's your profit sacrifice. So, |
13 | really they took quite an extreme position in that. |
14 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. Moving to the next |
15 | proposition. |
16 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, the next proposition. |
17 | MR. McDONALD: It is difficult to craft an |
18 | injunctive remedy in a refusal to deal case. |
19 | MR. KOLASKY: You mean one that works well? |
20 | MR. McDONALD: It's really easy to craft one |
21 | that doesn't, yes, Hew probably agrees. Everybody |
22 | agrees. Steve, yours is difficult enough. Bob |
23 | Pitofsky, you've said that you thought that one reason |
24 | that it was appropriate to have refusal to deal |
25 | liability is that the defendant would get a reasonable |
1 | royalty from the remedy. How would you calculate that |
2 | reasonable royalty? |
3 | MR. PITOFSKY: Well, it's hard to generalize. I |
4 | mentioned two examples, one is that you previously have |
5 | been dealing with people and charging them a royalty, |
6 | and you know, the first thing I would do is say to the |
7 | parties, why don't you try to work it out, and come back |
8 | to us with a proposal. And they come back and say we |
9 | can't work it out and you say, I'm going to refer it to |
10 | arbitration. And then the arbitrator comes back and |
11 | comes up with a number. Presumably that will work most |
12 | of the time. And if neither one of those approaches |
13 | work, you get some expert economist to come in and argue |
14 | with some other expert economist and you come up with a |
15 | reasonable number. Look, we all voted, it's very |
16 | difficult, the most difficult part of this whole area to |
17 | accomplish, but it has been done, it can be done, and |
18 | the price is not, I think, part of it. |
19 | MR. McDONALD: Steve, is your formula one that |
20 | can be applied by a jury in district court? |
21 | MR. SALOP: With expert economists and good |
22 | lawyers, yeah, I think so. I think it can be proved. |
23 | MR. McDONALD: All right, we'll move on to the |
24 | next proposition. |
25 | MR. ABBOTT: Next proposition is that an |
1 | intellectual property owner's unconditional, unilateral |
2 | decision not to license technology to others cannot |
3 | violate the antitrust laws. Again, this is that the |
4 | unilateral, unconditional decision not to license |
5 | technology to others cannot violate the antitrust laws. |
6 | Who agrees? |
7 | MR. PITOFSKY: That's what the law is. |
8 | MR. ABBOTT: All right, one, two, three, four. |
9 | Who disagrees? |
10 | MR. SALOP: I don't agree. |
11 | MR. ABBOTT: Steve Salop abstains and Bill |
12 | Kolasky disagrees. |
13 | MR. KOLASKY: Can we explain why? |
14 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, explain why you disagree, |
15 | Bill. |
16 | MR. KOLASKY: Again, I'm going to keep coming |
17 | back to the common law nature of antitrust. Suppose the |
18 | fact pattern similar to what you had in MCI and AT&T but |
19 | involving intellectual property rights instead of |
20 | interconnection. A patent owner knows that rival A is |
21 | thinking about investing in R&D to develop a competing |
22 | technology, and so it strings A along, promising to |
23 | license it, but in fact, playing rope-a-dope with it, |
24 | delaying it, in order to discourage the rival from |
25 | investing in its own technology. I would think in those |
1 | circumstances, you could hold the refusal to license to |
2 | be an antitrust violation. |
3 | Again, it's not a simple unconditional refusal |
4 | to license, but there's a pattern of conduct that is |
5 | having an anticompetitive effect. |
6 | MR. WHITENER: I think that last point is |
7 | important, it's outside the context of unilateral, |
8 | unconditional behavior. You have something else going |
9 | on, whether that's something that would be an antitrust |
10 | violation, I don't know, but now you're describing |
11 | something else, and I think it's very, very important |
12 | and useful to always come back in these cases to what it |
13 | is we are looking for and separate out conduct of what |
14 | you described by the simple decision to obtain the |
15 | property one's self. |
16 | MR. PATE: And you probably plead the elements |
17 | of fraud in the way you described it, right, so it's an |
18 | open question whether that needs to stay an antitrust |
19 | claim before you can prove the wrongful behavior. |
20 | MR. SALOP: That's what the Microsoft cases and |
21 | the Telecom cases that all of these allegations are |
22 | still rolling in the negotiations and, you know, they |
23 | were elements. |
24 | MR. ABBOTT: Should one distinguish between |
25 | patent licensing, let's maybe soften the unconditional, |
1 | in other forms of intellectual property licensing, such |
2 | as trademarks. For example, trade secrets, is there a |
3 | reason to distinguish among forms of IP? |
4 | MR. PATE: I would say as long as they're |
5 | defined correctly, if there isn't a problem with the |
6 | underlying IP system, the answer probably is no, that |
7 | there shouldn't be a requirement to license any of |
8 | those, as long as they're performing their proper |
9 | function, and I think you have to give a conclusive |
10 | promotion of correctness to the IP system in doing so, |
11 | and then turn to IP reform as the way to handle it if |
12 | the IP system isn't. Otherwise, you have this collision |
13 | that defeats the purposes of both bodies of law. |
14 | MR. ABBOTT: Anyone disagree, or are we all of a |
15 | common mind here? |
16 | (No response.) |
17 | MR. ABBOTT: Okay. Well, let's move to the next |
18 | proposition, which is compulsory licensing of IP as an |
19 | antitrust remedy should be rare. Now, probably we |
20 | should distinguish between remedies in different sorts |
21 | of cases here, but first I would like to get people to |
22 | vote on this proposition as a general matter. Who |
23 | agrees? |
24 | MR. PITOFSKY: Yeah, I agree it should be rare. |
25 | MR. KOLASKY: Are you taking merger out? |
1 | MR. ABBOTT: Well, that's why I said we should |
2 | distinguish between all the forms of situations in which |
3 | remedies arise. |
4 | MR. WALTON: In a merger case, it could be the |
5 | least restrictive, most effective remedy in some cases. |
6 | If it was a remedy for a unilateral, unconditional |
7 | refusal, you shouldn't be doing it in the first place. |
8 | MR. ABBOTT: So, what you're saying is that this |
9 | decree depends upon the facts, and certainly we've seen |
10 | a number of major cases in mergers in which IP was very |
11 | key to the merger, in which compulsory licensing was |
12 | required. How about the nonmerger context? |
13 | MR. PITOFSKY: Let me just in the merger |
14 | context, the leading example is Ciba-Geigy where the |
15 | Commission allowed the merger to go through on the |
16 | condition that a basket of intellectual property rights |
17 | were divested to a third party. And as that's the one |
18 | time that I think Business Week said that the government |
19 | finally got something right. So, it can be a least |
20 | restrictive alternative can be the best way to go. Does |
21 | it come up a lot? It has been known to come up. |
22 | MR. ABBOTT: Okay, I think this question has |
23 | raised fewer sparks than some of the other ones, and |
24 | let's see if the next one generates some sparks. |
25 | MR. McDONALD: This one is tailor made for Tom |
1 | Walton. A manufacturer's refusal to deal with |
2 | independent service organizations should not violate the |
3 | antitrust laws. |
4 | MR. WALTON: Yes, I would be all for that. I |
5 | would say in Kodak, General Motors, there's two -- there |
6 | was a -- I'm not an expert in Kodak, by any means, I've |
7 | read it briefly, but apparently there was a distinction |
8 | between whether Kodak was going to impose this refusal |
9 | to deal on manufacturers that already had their copy |
10 | machines, that was one issue. But the other issue was |
11 | whether it would be going forward, whether it would |
12 | impose -- it did not do that, it did not do that, first |
13 | thing. |
14 | The second thing it did was impose this |
15 | restriction on companies like General Motors that were |
16 | going to buy the machines, or bought a new machine, then |
17 | they would have to use only the parts provided by Kodak |
18 | or not use the independent service organization. You |
19 | have the right to not enter into that agreement. |
20 | So, the Kodak market was a competitive market, |
21 | so I don't see any -- I may be wrong, but I just don't |
22 | see any problem with that situation. |
23 | MR. SALOP: That case was not the first |
24 | situation. |
25 | MR. WALTON: Oh, was it? I may stand corrected. |
1 | MR. McDONALD: By a show of hands, who else is |
2 | willing to share Tom Walton's is unconditional |
3 | endorsement to this proposition? |
4 | MR. PATE: If the question is competitive |
5 | upstream market, would you have agreed with the Kodak |
6 | result, I would say no, so I think I would raise my hand |
7 | on that. |
8 | MR. WHITENER: Same. |
9 | MR. McDONALD: Do any of the panelists care to |
10 | speak on the circumstances in which refusal to deal with |
11 | an ISO definitely should be an antitrust violation? |
12 | (No response.) |
13 | MR. KOLASKY: Again, I think what makes it |
14 | difficult is the qualification that Hew put on his |
15 | answer, you know, if you had a situation like Kodak |
16 | where you had a competitive upstream equipment market, |
17 | then it's hard to imagine the circumstances in which you |
18 | would find a refusal to deal with an ISO unlawful. But |
19 | what if you had the circumstance where you had a |
20 | monopolist upstream who is refusing to deal with ISOs? |
21 | Again, I think as a general matter, there's a strong |
22 | presumption that it's not unlawful, but if the plaintiff |
23 | is willing to show facts that show that it was a part of |
24 | an anticompetitive pattern of conduct that was designed |
25 | to maintain or expand your monopoly, then it could be |
1 | unlawful if there are not legitimate business reasons |
2 | for it. |
3 | MR. SALOP: I would not use the distinction Bill |
4 | did, but rather I would ask whether it was a change in |
5 | conduct such as it was a monopoly, so if even a |
6 | monopolist from the get-go says you have to deal with |
7 | me, that would be okay, but the question is, you know, |
8 | the Kodak case was about the change in conduct. |
9 | MR. KOLASKY: But another situation, normally |
10 | you think that the markets for ISOs are relatively easy |
11 | to enter, and that therefore a refusal to deal with ISOs |
12 | is not likely to raise entry barriers, but suppose the |
13 | plaintiffs were able to show that the reasons the |
14 | monopolist was refusing to deal with ISOs was to make it |
15 | more difficult for somebody else to enter the equipment |
16 | market, and thereby break down their monopoly. On those |
17 | facts, then I think you might have a basis for |
18 | liability. |
19 | MR. McDONALD: Thank you. We're going to move |
20 | now to a couple of hypotheticals. |
21 | MR. ABBOTT: Okay. The first hypothetical |
22 | raises a question of IP, and let me read it: Ajax |
23 | Company holds a patent (patent X) over a small part of a |
24 | device that provides a new broadband service far |
25 | superior to any alternatives. There are no acceptable |
1 | substitutes for that patented part; without it the new |
2 | broadband service cannot be deployed. Firms holding all |
3 | patents covering all other essential parts of the device |
4 | have entered into a patent pool that sets a reasonable |
5 | royalty. Under this all third party businesses may |
6 | obtain a license. Ajax, however, refuses to license |
7 | patent X to anyone, thereby preventing third party |
8 | companies from having any access to the part that is |
9 | necessary to be able to provide the welfare-enhancing |
10 | broadband service." |
11 | Well, again, this is a small component of a |
12 | larger device, but by holding the patent and refusing to |
13 | license the patent for that one component, despite the |
14 | fact there are many other components, in effect, Ajax is |
15 | able to prevent any other firm from launching the |
16 | broadband device, and the broadband service that depends |
17 | upon the device. First of all, does Ajax have an |
18 | absolute right not to license patent X? |
19 | MR. WHITENER: I mean, I think it does, but I'm |
20 | not sure in the hypothetical yet really if I understand |
21 | what Ajax is doing. I don't particularly care, because |
22 | I don't think I'm going to condemn their decision to sit |
23 | on their patent, but what are they planning to do to |
24 | make money? Are they going to invent some other way to |
25 | do the broadband service? If they're just trying to |
1 | stupidly put the patent in a drawer, I don't think that |
2 | subjects them to liability. |
3 | MR. PATE: No, I don't think that they are |
4 | required to license the patent, and it really doesn't |
5 | matter to me whether they put it in the drawer or not. |
6 | Not because that wouldn't produce a situation wherein |
7 | that case consumer welfare wouldn't be enhanced by |
8 | taking it from them, but because of a judgment that a |
9 | property rule here is going to be superior to a |
10 | liability rule in producing innovation over the |
11 | long-term. And if the broadband service is one that's |
12 | going to cure avian flu or something, then presumably |
13 | the government can take, and with just compensation, use |
14 | it if there's some sort of emergency at issue, but |
15 | otherwise, no, I don't think Ajax has any obligation. |
16 | MR. ABBOTT: Does anyone else think it matters, |
17 | does it matter if Ajax plans to launch a new broadband |
18 | service itself? We've heard from a couple of people, as |
19 | opposed to just sitting on the patent, or alternatively, |
20 | and the facts haven't been presented here, but maybe |
21 | they have some interest in some other broadband |
22 | investment, and they find it profitable, at least in the |
23 | near term, not to have a new broadband service |
24 | introduced by anyone. |
25 | Steve? |
1 | MR. SALOP: It would make it a lot more |
2 | interesting. But Ajax is a client of mine and I don't |
3 | feel that I should comment. You know, I think that it's |
4 | what we've been talking about all day. I mean, once you |
5 | say Ajax has an -- is a competitor downstream, that |
6 | they've got ISDN, and now this is DSL, then you've got |
7 | the vertically integrated -- if they're a monopolist |
8 | downstream, then you basically have the hypothetical |
9 | that we've been talking about all day. |
10 | MR. ABBOTT: Does anybody, and we heard Hew Pate |
11 | speak directly to this, does anybody believe that the |
12 | welfare impact on the industries or consumers who would |
13 | benefit from the new broadband service should be taken |
14 | into account? |
15 | (No response.) |
16 | MR. ABBOTT: No one is willing to comment on |
17 | that? So, you all agree with Hew's proposition that it |
18 | doesn't matter, and the absolute right not to license? |
19 | And you don't need to -- you don't take into account any |
20 | potential welfare effects? |
21 | MR. PITOFSKY: I find this very difficult to |
22 | deal with, because as a practical matter, you have to |
23 | ask Ajax why? Why are you doing this? What's your |
24 | role? What are your other facilities? What are your |
25 | resources? And I know you don't like the idea of |
1 | somebody having to explain why, but in a bizarre |
2 | situation like this, I can't even begin to cope with |
3 | this hypothetical. Well, what do you mean you want |
4 | what? Is there no price under the sun that will be |
5 | enough that this patent pool can induce you to come into |
6 | the transaction? And depending on what that reason is, |
7 | then we go forward with, under what circumstances, if |
8 | any, should the law intervene. |
9 | MR. KOLASKY: I'm sort of with Bob on this in |
10 | the sense that I don't think there are nearly enough |
11 | facts in this hypothetical to begin to answer the |
12 | question. I mean, on its face, this sounds like Ajax |
13 | has simply invented a better mousetrap and it ought to |
14 | be free to capture the value from that new mousetrap |
15 | however it wants, and if, for example, hypothetically |
16 | the members of the patent pool currently have, you know, |
17 | 100 percent of the market and Ajax is a new entrant, |
18 | that using this new device as its entry point, then it's |
19 | perfectly natural that it would want to have a period of |
20 | time in which it has exclusive rights to that device. |
21 | It may down the road license others, and in addition its |
22 | refusal to license may stimulate the others to try to |
23 | develop an alternative to this new device. So, this |
24 | doesn't sound anticompetitive on its face. It sounds |
25 | like competition on the merits. |
1 | MR. ABBOTT: Steve, a quick comment? |
2 | MR. SALOP: I agree with Bob, and I think |
3 | stating that in this pristine way, you know, in Aspen, |
4 | the reason why Aspen took that extreme position that |
5 | they just had a right to do whatever they wanted, was |
6 | because they squandered all their other defenses in the |
7 | courts below. And, you know, in a real world case, |
8 | unless Ajax just decided to fight this because, you |
9 | know, their CEO or board members were intellectual |
10 | property lawyers and they felt it was a good thing just |
11 | to fight it for the good of the country, they would give |
12 | a reason. And the reason -- and then the reason is |
13 | going to matter. |
14 | MR. PATE: But the thing that's important is |
15 | that requiring them to give a reason, in and of itself, |
16 | is going to generate a tremendous amount of uncertainty |
17 | in our system of litigation-based decision making. So, |
18 | you can always come up with a better result in the |
19 | individual case, you've got to consider what you do to |
20 | the system when you do that. |
21 | MR. WHITENER: Right, and if somebody states the |
22 | reason bluntly in an email, which is I want to keep |
23 | others from competing with me in my IP, you know, you |
24 | might get to trial and you might have liability, even |
25 | though, beyond repeating myself, all you were doing was |
1 | keeping it. |
2 | MR. PATE: I don't know which is better, we've |
3 | had some strain of this conversation that has said that |
4 | the worst thing would be that if Mr. Ajax is cranky and |
5 | has it in the drawer, then we're worried about the |
6 | consumer welfare effects of it not being used, but that |
7 | if it's being used to get a competitive advantage, then |
8 | that's good, that's the American way, but, you know, as |
9 | Mark points out, it may be that if the email says that |
10 | we're going to use this to stick it to the competition, |
11 | that's when you have a really protracted litigation. |
12 | MR. ABBOTT: Well, let's turn quickly to the |
13 | last hypothetical, we're going to make this litigation |
14 | last some more. The final hypothetical is a shorter |
15 | one, so -- but perhaps ironically has fewer ambiguities |
16 | than our previous hypothetical. Alpha Company owns the |
17 | only source of an input (input Z), or if we had an |
18 | English speaker here, it might be input Zed, and alpha |
19 | uses input Z to make widgets. Beta Company invents a |
20 | new technology that uses input Z to make widgets at a |
21 | lower cost than Alpha's technology. Alpha refuses to |
22 | sell input Z to Beta, but Alpha does sell input Z to |
23 | firms in other industries for $100 per unit. |
24 | First of all, should Alpha be required to sell |
25 | input Z to Beta, since it sells to firms in other |
1 | industries? Hew? |
2 | MR. PATE: Well, and you're eliminating |
3 | arbitrage, they can't get it from the $100 purchasers |
4 | for some reason? |
5 | MR. ABBOTT: Yes, let's assume that. Yes, I |
6 | think -- |
7 | MR. PATE: No, I don't think Alpha has an |
8 | obligation to sell the input it owns to Beta. |
9 | MR. ABBOTT: Anybody else? |
10 | MR. KOLASKY: Again, too few patent facts. Does |
11 | Alpha have a monopoly on the widgets market, are there |
12 | other ways to make widgets with inputs A, B and C? I |
13 | mean, you just don't know enough. |
14 | MR. WHITENER: I actually think under these |
15 | facts, I know enough to say no obligation to deal, no |
16 | obligation if they deal, no obligation to deal at $100, |
17 | no obligation to deal at Steve's, you know, the monopoly |
18 | at nonexclusionary price. I mean, look, Alpha owns Z. |
19 | Alpha has the rights to all the return money on Z, and |
20 | it really shouldn't matter if Z can be deployed in one |
21 | antitrust market or 50. It's all the same way of saying |
22 | Alpha owns, lawfully, I assume, developed Z, it gets |
23 | every dollar attributable to ownership of Z by |
24 | exploiting it itself. And I do have a question for |
25 | Steve, if Beta, with this low-cost technology, assume if |
1 | they get the input at whatever, let's say $100, if we |
2 | can predict that their lower cost widget manufacturing |
3 | method is going to let them ultimately take most or all |
4 | the sales of widgets, do they have to share their |
5 | manufacturing technology with Alpha? |
6 | MR. KOLASKY: That's an interesting question. |
7 | MR. SALOP: I mean, that's an interesting |
8 | question. It would depend, is there a monopoly on that |
9 | technology or are there other makers of that technology? |
10 | MR. WHITENER: We are predicting over that, |
11 | since they get the input at $100, they are going to get |
12 | all the widget sales because they have a lower cost of |
13 | manufacturing. And let's assume they can readily |
14 | license this device to Alpha. Do they have to share it? |
15 | MR. SALOP: I mean, I think you have to go |
16 | through now it's the machinery is an input, but it |
17 | wouldn't -- so I guess you're saying they have a |
18 | monopoly on securing your technology, but they may have |
19 | no market power in the widget business, and, you know, |
20 | the monopoly power in the widget business, which is what |
21 | Bill is getting at, is a very important element, not to |
22 | mention the alternatives to input Z. |
23 | MR. WHITENER: I think what would happen if you |
24 | did conclude there was monopoly power and an obligation |
25 | to deal, one consequence is Alpha's incentive to develop |
1 | a lower cost technology itself is now removed, because |
2 | they can share, and if Beta gets to buy the input at |
3 | $100, their incentive to innovate around or replicate Z |
4 | I think is what is similarly diminished. |
5 | So, I mean, I think you can construct a set of |
6 | facts that says they have to deal with each other and I |
7 | think you have wound up essentially with the economics |
8 | of one firm producing rather than two firms struggling |
9 | to compete with each other. |
10 | MR. SALOP: Or the two firms competing. That's |
11 | the problem with the competitive nature, if they do or |
12 | not. |
13 | MR. ABBOTT: Any additional comments on that |
14 | hypothetical? |
15 | (No response.) |
16 | MR. ABBOTT: Well, if not, let just have a few |
17 | closing remarks, and I think my colleague, Bruce |
18 | McDonald, may want to say one or two things as well. |
19 | Let me move to the podium, very briefly. |
20 | It's difficult to generalize based on depth and |
21 | also the comments that were made today, but I think |
22 | we've heard some interesting discussions and analyses of |
23 | different aspects of the refusals to deal with |
24 | competitors. Number one, we have heard alternative |
25 | forms of multipart balancing tests, some of these tests |
1 | have been characterized as really sliding scale, tests |
2 | that rely on certain propositions, but that don't |
3 | require a lot of difficult administration. We've also |
4 | heard some concerns that the problem with any of these |
5 | tests, and this is going to repeat a theme, that when |
6 | you go to a jury, will the jury be able, sensibly, to |
7 | apply them given their, in effect, potentially high |
8 | error costs. We've heard some responses that, well, no, |
9 | the juries are in the business of doing that, generalist |
10 | courts and judges are in the business of weighing, |
11 | applying weighing balancing tests in all sorts of areas |
12 | of law. |
13 | We've also, I think, heard all speakers, |
14 | certainly emphasize the theme that facts and hard facts |
15 | and details are very important, that's certainly come up |
16 | in the context of propositions we raised and in |
17 | hypotheticals. There's always a demand, quite |
18 | understandable, for more details and more facts. I |
19 | think that all of this, and in particular, the specific |
20 | written comments and written presentations by our |
21 | panelists will prove quite valuable as we ponder the |
22 | record developed throughout the hearings and there are |
23 | no simple or some might argue there are simple answers |
24 | here, but certainly there are no -- there is no |
25 | unanimity of opinion. |
1 | Despite that fact, I think we've heard that, and |
2 | it seems to be a general theme, that imposing a duty to |
3 | deal on the monopolist is something that is very rare. |
4 | Some would say that general unconditional impositions to |
5 | deal should never be applied, others say there's more |
6 | nuance to that, but I think there's a general |
7 | understanding that this is a very unusual sort of |
8 | requirement, and certainly perhaps intentionally with |
9 | antitrust law and having more to do with regulation, and |
10 | that brings us to the sort of broader question that over |
11 | the tension and the dividing line between antitrust |
12 | remedies and regulation in general, and the ability of |
13 | courts and expert agencies to administer such tests will |
14 | remain with us. |
15 | And now I would like to turn briefly to Bruce |
16 | McDonald to see if he has any additional insights to |
17 | share, and also to thank him and all of the people from |
18 | the Department of Justice who have helped so much in |
19 | putting together this session. I would also like to |
20 | thank all of my colleagues in the Federal Trade |
21 | Commission, too numerous to mention, who have done a |
22 | wonderful job in making this session a success. |
23 | Bruce? |
24 | MR. McDONALD: Let me just add thank you that |
25 | today's discussion does highlight that even though this |
1 | may be one of the most narrow grounds for battle in the |
2 | refusal to deal -- in the single firm conduct debate, it |
3 | is certainly one of the most hard fought. The agencies |
4 | work hard to try to incorporate the latest thinking into |
5 | their enforcement decisions and these hearings are a |
6 | part of helping us to remain on the cutting edge. We |
7 | can't thank the panel enough for the time they devoted |
8 | to preparing their presentations and for being here and |
9 | for sharing their expertise for us. |
10 | On behalf of the FTC and DOJ, thank you very |
11 | much. |
12 | (Applause.) |
13 | (Whereupon, at 5:13 p.m., the hearing was |
14 | concluded.) |
15 | |
16 | |
17 | |
18 | |
19 | |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
1 |
CERTIFICATE OF REPORTER
|
2 | |
3 | |
4 | I, Sally Jo Bowling, do hereby certify that the |
5 | foregoing proceedings were recorded by me via stenotype |
6 | and reduced to typewriting under my supervision; that I |
7 | am neither counsel for, related to, nor employed by any |
8 | of the parties to the action in which these proceedings |
9 | were transcribed; and further, that I am not a relative |
10 | or employee of any attorney or counsel employed by the |
11 | parties hereto, nor financially or otherwise interested |
12 | in the outcome of the action. |
13 | |
14 | |
15 | |
16 | |
17 | |
18 |
SALLY JO BOWLING
|
19 | |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |