Participant Presentations And Session Transcript For September 12
1 | UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION |
2 | and |
3 | UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE |
4 | |
5 | |
6 | |
7 | SHERMAN ACT SECTION 2 JOINT HEARING |
8 | INTERNATIONAL ISSUES |
9 | TUESDAY, SEPTEMBER 12, 2006 |
10 | |
11 | |
12 | |
13 | |
14 | HELD AT: |
15 | UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION |
16 | SATELLITE BUILDING, CONFERENCE ROOM C |
17 | 601 NEW JERSEY AVENUE, N.W. |
18 | WASHINGTON, D.C. |
19 | 9:30 A.M. TO 4:00 P.M. |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | Reported and transcribed by: |
25 | Susanne Bergling, RMR-CLR |
2
1 | MODERATORS: |
2 | GERALD F. MASOUDI |
3 | Deputy Assistant Attorney General |
4 | Department of Justice |
5 | and |
6 | RANDOLPH W. TRITELL |
7 | Assistant Director for International Antitrust |
8 | Federal Trade Commission |
9 | |
10 | PANELISTS: |
11 | Morning Session: |
12 | Philip Lowe |
13 | Hideo Nakajima |
14 | Eduardo Perez Motta |
15 | Sheridan Scott |
16 | |
17 | Afternoon Session: |
18 | George Addy |
19 | Margaret Bloom |
20 | Paul Lugard |
21 | James F. Rill |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
3
1 | C O N T E N T S |
2 | |
3 | MORNING SESSION: |
4 | Introduction |
5 | Presentations: |
6 | Philip Lowe |
7 | Hideo Nakajima |
8 | Eduardo Perez Motta |
9 | Sheridan Scott |
10 | Moderated Discussion |
11 | Lunch Recess |
12 | |
13 | AFTERNOON SESSION: |
14 | Introduction |
15 | Presentations: |
16 | George Addy |
17 | Margaret Bloom |
18 | Paul Lugard |
19 | James F. Rill |
20 | Moderated Discussion |
21 | Conclusion |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
1 | P R O C E E D I N G S |
2 | - - - - - |
3 | MR. TRITELL: This must be some sort of record, |
4 | a minute before we're supposed to start, a hush has |
5 | descended upon the room. I don't have to tell everybody |
6 | to get in their seats, so thank you, we are off to a |
7 | good start. |
8 | Good morning. I'm Randy Tritell, Federal Trade |
9 | Commission's Assistant Director For International |
10 | Antitrust. I will be co-moderating this morning's |
11 | session along with Gerald Masoudi, Deputy Assistant |
12 | Attorney General for the Department of Justice, which is |
13 | co-sponsoring these hearings with the Federal Trade |
14 | Commission. |
15 | As you know, the FTC and the DOJ strive to |
16 | allocate matters efficiently consistent with our |
17 | respective highest and best uses. In that spirit, it |
18 | falls to me to open this morning's hearings by sharing |
19 | the following four insights. |
20 | One, please turn off your cell phones, |
21 | Blackberries and other devices. Two, the restrooms are |
22 | outside the double doors and across the lobby. There |
23 | are signs to guide you. Three, in the unlikely event |
24 | the building alarm sounds, please proceed calmly and |
25 | quickly as instructed. If we must leave the building, |
1 | go out the New Jersey Avenue entrance by the guard's |
2 | desk, follow the phalanx of FTC employees to a gathering |
3 | point, and await further instructions. Four, although |
4 | we would love to hear what you think of the interesting |
5 | issues we will be discussing today, we cannot |
6 | accommodate any comments or questions from the audience |
7 | at today's hearing. |
8 | I would also like to thank at least some of the |
9 | people who have put in a tremendous amount of work to |
10 | organize this hearing today. From the Department of |
11 | Justice, Joe Matelis, Gail Kursh, Ed Eliasberg and |
12 | Brandon Greenland, and from the Federal Trade |
13 | Commission, Patricia Schultheiss, Doug Hilleboe, |
14 | Elizabeth Argeris and Ruth Sacks, as well as the staffs |
15 | of the International Divisions of both agencies. |
16 | We are honored to have assembled for this |
17 | morning's session a distinguished panel of senior |
18 | officials from several of our fellow competition |
19 | agencies from around the world. They will discuss how |
20 | their agencies apply their antitrust laws to single-firm |
21 | conduct and alleged abuses of dominance. |
22 | Our panelists this morning are Philip Lowe, the |
23 | Director General for Competition of the European |
24 | Commission; Hideo Nakajima, the Deputy Secretary General |
25 | of the Japan Fair Trade Commission; Eduardo Perez Motta, |
1 | the President of the Mexican Federal Competition |
2 | Commission; and Sheridan Scott, the Commissioner of |
3 | Competition of the Canadian Competition Bureau. |
4 | I would now like to turn over the podium to my |
5 | co-moderator, Jerry Masoudi. |
6 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, Randy. |
7 | Welcome to today's session in our ongoing series |
8 | of panels on single-firm conduct. The Department of |
9 | Justice Antitrust Division and the FTC are jointly |
10 | sponsoring these hearings to help advance the |
11 | development of the law under Section 2 of the Sherman |
12 | Act. |
13 | We have had a number of previous sessions. On |
14 | June 20, we had a session that included opening remarks |
15 | from FTC Chairman Debbie Majoras and Assistant Attorney |
16 | General Tom Barnett of the Antitrust Division, as well |
17 | as comments from Dennis Carlton, who will soon be a |
18 | Deputy Assistant Attorney General at the Department of |
19 | Justice, and Herbert Hovenkamp. |
20 | On June 22nd, we had panels on predatory pricing |
21 | and predatory buying, and then on July 18th, we had a |
22 | session on unilateral refusals to deal. Transcripts |
23 | from these sessions are available on the DOJ and FTC web |
24 | sites, and transcripts of this session and future |
25 | sessions will also be made available. |
1 | Today we will concern ourselves with how |
2 | allegations of anticompetitive single-firm conduct are |
3 | treated in jurisdictions outside the United States and |
4 | related international issues. This morning we will be |
5 | hearing from our panel of distinguished enforcers, and |
6 | then in the afternoon, we will hear from practitioners |
7 | and academics active in the international area. |
8 | First, we will have approximately 20 minutes per |
9 | panelist to give an opening presentation. We will then |
10 | have a 15-minute break, and finally, we will have a |
11 | moderated discussion period. Our discussion today will |
12 | include an opportunity for our panelists to respond to |
13 | each other's presentations. So, our first panel I think |
14 | will end at about noon, and we will start back up after |
15 | a lunch break at 1:30. |
16 | I would like to join Randy in thanking the |
17 | staffs of the FTC and the Antitrust Division for helping |
18 | put together today's presentation, and I will now turn |
19 | it back to Randy to give a more detailed introduction of |
20 | our panelists. |
21 | MR. TRITELL: Before introducing our first |
22 | speaker, I would just like to reiterate that the U.S. |
23 | agencies consider these hearings to be extremely |
24 | important. In particular, regarding today's session, |
25 | given the large and increasing number of jurisdictions |
1 | that apply antitrust laws to single-firm conduct and as |
2 | commerce increasingly crosses national borders, it is |
3 | fitting and important that we hear the views and learn |
4 | from the experience of our international colleagues as |
5 | we try to both broaden and deepen our understanding of |
6 | the issues in this critical area. |
7 | I am going to provide a brief introduction to |
8 | each of our speakers before their presentations, and I |
9 | direct you to the more detailed biographical information |
10 | in the packet outside this room. |
11 | First we will hear from Philip Lowe, who, again, |
12 | is the Director General for Competition in the European |
13 | Commission. Before his appointment to that post, Philip |
14 | was first in private industry and then served in a |
15 | variety of capacities in the European Commission, |
16 | including as Director of the Merger Task Force of the |
17 | Competition Directorate, head of the Cabinet of the |
18 | European Commissioner for Transport, Director General |
19 | For Development, head of the Cabinet of the Commission's |
20 | Vice President, and the Acting Deputy Secretary General. |
21 | Philip? |
22 | MR. LOWE: Well, good morning, everyone, and |
23 | thank you, Randy and Jerry. I'm very grateful to |
24 | Chairman Debbie Majoras and Assistant Attorney General |
25 | Tom Barnett for giving me the opportunity to take part |
1 | in this joint FTC-DOJ set of hearings on Section 2 of |
2 | the Sherman Act. These hearings seem to reflect a |
3 | strong interest throughout the world over the last few |
4 | years in what you call single-firm conduct. |
5 | At the International Competition Network's |
6 | conference in Capetown last May, a new working group was |
7 | launched on international conduct. The OECD has |
8 | arranged round tables on issues related to single-firm |
9 | conduct, and numerous conferences have had single-firm |
10 | conduct appearing on the agenda. |
11 | At the Commission, we have 40 years of case law |
12 | related to the application of Article 82 of the European |
13 | Community Treaty. Article 82 is the treaty article |
14 | prohibiting abuses of dominant position, so broadly |
15 | equivalent to your Section 2, although as you realize, |
16 | the European structure requires a firm to be dominant |
17 | before it can be caught by any issue of abuse. |
18 | Of course, we have recently been reflecting very |
19 | carefully on the coherence and the consistency of our |
20 | policy under the Treaty and Article 82, and we thought |
21 | it was a logical step, after having reformed or, say, |
22 | modernized the application of Article 81, the article |
23 | dealing with agreements and merger control regime, that |
24 | we moved our policy in the area of Article 82 more |
25 | towards an effects-based approach in line with what we |
1 | have initiated under Article 81, the merger control. |
2 | This required, nevertheless, a thorough review of the |
3 | policy so far and, indeed, the case law which was at the |
4 | back of it. |
5 | The application of Article 82 was, I think, |
6 | widely criticized as being fragmented without guiding |
7 | principles and for applying in some instances general |
8 | form-based criteria whose meaning was not always clear |
9 | in specific cases. To that extent, this would cause |
10 | Article 82 to be applied in cases where there would be |
11 | not any sufficient likely or even actual restrictive |
12 | effect on the market, and this would clearly be wrong. |
13 | There was much concern from the business |
14 | community about these false positives, so-called type |
15 | one errors. Likewise, it is a mistake and would be a |
16 | mistake if a form-based approach caused Article 82 not |
17 | to be applied to the cases in which there was likely or |
18 | actual harm to the market, false-negatives or type two |
19 | errors. |
20 | The vocal parts of business were perhaps less |
21 | concerned about these errors, but as an authority |
22 | charged with, in principle, protecting consumer welfare, |
23 | an objective which the Commission and in particular my |
24 | Commission have underlined in the last few years, I |
25 | believe we've got to be concerned about both types of |
1 | errors, and this is a fundamental reason for our review |
2 | of Article 82. |
3 | After some initial internal debate, we involved |
4 | our colleagues in the national competition authorities |
5 | in the EU Member States in discussions about the review. |
6 | In December last year, we published a discussion paper |
7 | on the application of Article 82 to exclusionary abuses, |
8 | and we suggested what we regarded as a framework for the |
9 | continued rigorous enforcement of Article 82, building |
10 | on the economic effects-based analysis carried out in |
11 | recent cases. |
12 | The discussion paper aimed to describe a |
13 | consistent methodology for the assessment of some of the |
14 | most common abusive practices, which you have already |
15 | discussed in the context of these hearings, predatory |
16 | pricing, single branding, tying and bundling and refusal |
17 | to supply. |
18 | Now, we didn't in the discussion paper go |
19 | through all the aspects of Article 82, and I haven't got |
20 | time today either to go through every single aspect. |
21 | You will notice that one major difference between the |
22 | application of Section 2 and Article 82 is the explicit |
23 | reference in 82 to exploitative abuses, which we have |
24 | not dealt with in the discussion paper, and we have not |
25 | taken a decision about whether we will deal with them in |
1 | any guidelines at the present time. However, there is |
2 | or there has been some comment from the public |
3 | consultation that we should, in fact, clarify what our |
4 | position is. |
5 | What I would like to do first of all, however, |
6 | is to emphasize some of the principles we set out in the |
7 | section of the paper called "A Framework For Analysis of |
8 | Exclusionary Abuses," and then I'll give you a flavor of |
9 | what has been the reaction to the principles and to the |
10 | methodologies outlined in the discussion paper during |
11 | the public consultation, which has been in force this |
12 | year. |
13 | The paper I think for the first time makes it |
14 | clear that the main objective of Article 82 is to serve |
15 | consumer welfare by protecting competition. We want to |
16 | protect competition on the market, not individual |
17 | competitors. The basic assumption is that the |
18 | competition will benefit consumers and that limits on |
19 | competition will hurt consumers. Of course, limits on |
20 | competition should, therefore, in principle be |
21 | prohibited unless it can be shown that efficiencies |
22 | outweigh the loss of competition for consumers. |
23 | Naturally, the paper states that we are |
24 | concerned about likely and actual effects on consumer |
25 | welfare in the short, medium and long term, and |
1 | obviously the longer the conduct has been going on, the |
2 | more we will concentrate on actual effects. So, |
3 | consumer welfare we regard as the anchoring principle |
4 | for our competitive analysis, and we do not enter much |
5 | into what Debbie Majoras in her opening remarks at these |
6 | hearings called "the search for the Holy Grail test," |
7 | and I agree entirely with her that the debate hasn't any |
8 | dimension or it could run the danger of becoming too |
9 | academic and losing practical significance. |
10 | That's not the aim of the discussion paper. |
11 | What we're attempting to do is to make a first |
12 | contribution to establishing principles and |
13 | methodologies which give clarity to business and the |
14 | legal community on what policy will apply and guidance |
15 | to those agencies, in particular in Europe, which we |
16 | have to apply them. |
17 | Now, there are two central questions which the |
18 | paper calls on us to ask. The first is, does the |
19 | conduct of a dominant firm have the capacity to |
20 | foreclose? This depends in good part on the form and |
21 | nature of the conduct, whether it is positive or |
22 | negative in its consumer effects. The answer to that |
23 | question is fairly obvious if one is dealing with |
24 | exclusive dealing. Sometimes it is less obvious to |
25 | distinguish between the capacity to foreclose and any |
1 | other effect, for example, in the case of rebates, and |
2 | I'll come back to that in a moment. |
3 | The second question we ask is does the conduct |
4 | have a likely or actual market distorting effect. |
5 | Likely effects are, in our opinion, effects which in a |
6 | specific market context are predictable on the basis of |
7 | experience and/or a solid theory of economic harm. The |
8 | likelihood and significance of foreclosure depends on |
9 | factors such as preexisting market power and barriers to |
10 | expansion or entry, the market coverage of the conduct, |
11 | and in the case of selective foreclosure, the importance |
12 | of the targeted customers or competitors. |
13 | Actual effects are established on the basis of |
14 | evidence of market evolution in the past, and this |
15 | doesn't necessarily involve complicated economic |
16 | studies. It can be presented as facts which can be then |
17 | investigated by the authorities on the basis of the |
18 | evidence submitted to it. |
19 | Now, coming back to rebates, as I mentioned |
20 | earlier, it is not immediately obvious whether any |
21 | particular rebates have the capacity to exclude. To |
22 | answer that question, we first need to ask, exclude who? |
23 | In the paper, we propose that for rebates as well as for |
24 | other types of price-based conduct, the exclusion of as |
25 | efficient competitors is abusive. |
1 | Now, this is not the only test which can be used |
2 | to show abuse. It nevertheless appears to us in |
3 | principle as a useful one, as it allows dominant firms |
4 | to assess their conduct based on their own costs. A |
5 | failed price/cost test is, of course, not the end of the |
6 | analysis. We would still have to show a likely market |
7 | foreclosure effect. |
8 | And by the way, as public consultation has |
9 | shown, one test may not be the final answer to the |
10 | analysis we need to carry out. There may be several |
11 | tests which have been proposed which are relevant to a |
12 | particular case. Nevertheless, we are comforted in the |
13 | view that the benchmark of the efficient competitor on |
14 | the market is one which is extremely important to judge |
15 | the behavior of the dominant company against it. |
16 | Now, the paper also states that if conduct |
17 | clearly creates no efficiencies and only raises |
18 | obstacles to residual competition, there is no need to |
19 | carry out a full effects-based analysis. Such conduct |
20 | can be presumed to be abusive. However, as with any |
21 | presumption, the dominant company can, of course, rebut |
22 | it by providing evidence that the conduct will create |
23 | efficiencies, or as our case law refers to in the |
24 | opinion of the court, is objectively justified. |
25 | Now, exclusionary conduct could escape the |
1 | prohibition of Article 82 if the dominance undertaken |
2 | can provide an objective justification for its behavior |
3 | or if it can demonstrate that its conduct produces |
4 | efficiencies which outweigh the negative effect on |
5 | competition. There is an objective justification where |
6 | the dominant company is able to show that the otherwise |
7 | abusive conduct is actually necessary on the basis of |
8 | objective practice external to the parties involved; in |
9 | particular, external to the dominant company. |
10 | The dominant company may, for example, be able |
11 | to show that the conduct concerned is necessary for |
12 | safety or health reasons related to the dangerous nature |
13 | of the product in question, but that necessity, that |
14 | concept necessity, must be based on objective practices |
15 | that apply in general for all undertakings in the |
16 | market. |
17 | Now, I want to come on to efficiencies. The |
18 | same conduct can, of course, have effects which enhance |
19 | efficiency and effects which restrict competition, and |
20 | in this paper we propose a weighing or balancing |
21 | approach where efficiencies are balanced against the |
22 | negative effects on competition, and that balancing |
23 | exercise determines whether or not the conduct is |
24 | abusive. |
25 | Now, this test is important, and notwithstanding |
1 | all the discussions about how efficiencies should be |
2 | assessed and upon whom the burden of proof should lie, |
3 | the one core element that I cannot see us moving away |
4 | from is that fundamentally, there should be this |
5 | balancing, and ultimately, that balancing of the |
6 | efficiencies against the distorting effects is in the |
7 | responsibility of the agency concerned, although you can |
8 | argue the burden of proof of efficiencies on the side of |
9 | the defendant must go beyond simple provision of |
10 | evidence to actually argue why the behavior is necessary |
11 | and why it is beneficial to consumers. |
12 | The purpose of competition law should be to |
13 | maximize consumer welfare. Of course, consumer welfare |
14 | can be harmed by inappropriate, disproportionate |
15 | intervention by a regulatory body, but it can also be |
16 | harmed by inappropriate reluctance to intervene. As I |
17 | mentioned earlier, in working towards maximizing |
18 | consumer welfare, we need to be as concerned about |
19 | under-enforcement as over-enforcement, and we need to be |
20 | as concerned by not giving up emphasis on efficiencies |
21 | as we are by giving too much emphasis to efficiencies. |
22 | Now, as to how we carry out this analysis in |
23 | practice, EC law already provides us with a framework. |
24 | Certain types of conduct can be analyzed both under |
25 | Article 81 and under 82. Consistency requires that the |
1 | conditions for assessing efficiencies defense under 82 |
2 | be similar to what we have as a policy with respect to |
3 | restrictive agreements under Article 81 and the |
4 | exemptions under Article 81-3. |
5 | The efficiencies must be realized or are likely |
6 | to be realized by the conduct. The conduct must be |
7 | indispensable to realize the efficiencies. Overall, |
8 | consumers should benefit from the efficiencies, there |
9 | must be consumer buy-in, and competition shouldn't be |
10 | eliminated as a result of the practices concerned. |
11 | We also discussed the issue in the paper of the |
12 | extent to which -- the market power of the company, and |
13 | here again, I think this is a departure for us as an |
14 | agency. We identify in I hope a convergent way with |
15 | U.S. thinking the concept of dominance mostly with the |
16 | concept of significant market power. That market power, |
17 | if it is very high, as indicated by the strength of the |
18 | constraints upon the dominant company, may mean that we |
19 | will have to undertake the balancing of efficiencies in |
20 | a much more rigorous way if, indeed, the strength of the |
21 | market power is very great. |
22 | The burden of proving a capability to foreclose |
23 | and the likely or actual foreclosure, and I emphasized |
24 | this before, it physically falls on the authority or the |
25 | plaintiff, but the burden of proving an objective |
1 | justification for efficiencies should be on the dominant |
2 | company. Ultimately, however, the agency should carry |
3 | out the assessment, and that assessment in our system is |
4 | controlled by the courts as to whether we have actually |
5 | made that balancing in a way which doesn't project any |
6 | obvious misinterpretation of the facts or bad judgment |
7 | as to the likely effects. |
8 | Now, let me indicate some areas of reasonable |
9 | consensus internationally and in Europe as to the ideas |
10 | in the discussion paper. There's certainly some welcome |
11 | for the overall aim of clarifying the application of |
12 | Article 82 and for an effects-based approach. There's a |
13 | broad welcome for the clarification that the ultimate |
14 | objective is to protect consumers, and some commentators |
15 | have frequently had the impression that it was |
16 | otherwise. |
17 | There's broad consensus on the aim to protect |
18 | competition and not competitors, and an authority must |
19 | be free to act where harm remains likely but has not yet |
20 | materialized. We don't have to wait until a patient is |
21 | dead before we try to revive them. And there is an |
22 | emphasis throughout the commentary on the need for safe |
23 | harbors and presumptions of both legality and illegality |
24 | to ensure that the effects-based approach is applied in |
25 | a practical and operational way, but, of course, they |
1 | have to be based on sound economic principles, and the |
2 | attempts to define the safe harbors shouldn't result in |
3 | more uncertainty than actually leaving the thresholds |
4 | outside any guidelines. |
5 | For example, if the pressure is an effects-based |
6 | approach to lower the safe harbor to a very restrictive |
7 | level in order to look at an operation in detail on the |
8 | basis of economic or econometric analysis, frequently we |
9 | are giving the impression that we would systematically |
10 | engage in very detailed economic effects-based analysis |
11 | above the safe harbor, and this has given rise to some |
12 | commentary that we have, in fact, tried to extend the |
13 | degree of the outreach of Article 82 as a result of the |
14 | proposed guidelines. |
15 | There are some difficult open questions. We |
16 | consider the conduct that clearly creates no |
17 | efficiencies and only raises obstacles to competition |
18 | should be presumed to be abusive, but what are the |
19 | classes of conduct which are so nakedly abusive that we |
20 | have a per se rule prohibiting them? Similarly, conduct |
21 | which is clearly competition on the merits should be |
22 | legal, but we have the challenge of defining the |
23 | categories of the conduct which fall into that area as |
24 | well. |
25 | When it comes to price-based conduct, how far |
1 | should we rely on price/cost tests? What are the |
2 | alternatives to the price/cost tests? How exactly |
3 | should they be formulated? For example, we need to show |
4 | profit sacrifice to prove predation. Nothing like a |
5 | tongue-twister. Is profit sacrifice also an appropriate |
6 | test for other price-based conduct, for instance, |
7 | rebates? |
8 | There is a lot of commentary in the U.S. about |
9 | the explicit need for a recoupment test in predation. I |
10 | have to say that we're quite sensitive to that comment, |
11 | our traditional view being that if we have a good story, |
12 | a robust story, about the dominance of a company, then |
13 | it should be capable of recouping. However, depending |
14 | on the predictability and the operationality of any |
15 | methodology we announce in guidelines, we are certainly |
16 | giving thought to the need for an explicit recoupment |
17 | test. |
18 | The role of the so-called "meeting competition |
19 | defense" is most clear when it comes to price |
20 | discrimination. In the U.S., you have even stated |
21 | explicitly, you have got it in the acts. It makes |
22 | perfect sense that a company can argue that the reason |
23 | it charges different prices to different customers is |
24 | that competition forces it to do so, but it's much less |
25 | clear what the meeting competition defense should have |
1 | as a role beyond price discrimination. |
2 | For example, I'm not sure it should be a defense |
3 | in itself when a company argues that it is losing money |
4 | on particular sales by charging prices below avoidable |
5 | costs because competition forces it to do so. That begs |
6 | the question why the company wants to make those sales |
7 | at all. It may have a good reason for doing so, but it |
8 | seems to me that that reason then should be the defense, |
9 | not the meeting competition defense. |
10 | The reactions to our paper show definite support |
11 | for efficiencies playing a role in the analysis, and in |
12 | that respect, there is an ongoing debate, which I hope |
13 | will end very quickly, on who should have the burden of |
14 | proof. All I can say is that the approach of expecting |
15 | an agency to analyze potential efficiencies is one which |
16 | is bound to fail because the agency has less information |
17 | than the companies who are arguing for the efficiencies, |
18 | and the approach that the -- well, that some say the |
19 | defendants should be balancing efficiencies against |
20 | distorted effects is equally unrealistic, because it is |
21 | the agency who has the major role in analyzing what the |
22 | likely distorted effects are. |
23 | I have only touched the surface, ladies and |
24 | gentlemen, of the issues raised in our paper. It proves |
25 | I think that we are at the same degree of reflection, |
1 | review, thorough review of our policy, as you are in the |
2 | States. All I can say is that the major challenges for |
3 | us are no longer in the area of general principles, but |
4 | in the area of balancing legal certainty, |
5 | operationality, against an effects-based approach which |
6 | gives a right answer and avoids type one and type two |
7 | error. |
8 | Thank you very much. |
9 | (Applause.) |
10 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you very much, Philip, for |
11 | getting us off to a strong start this morning. |
12 | I would now like to introduce our next speaker, |
13 | Hideo Nakajima, Deputy Secretary General of the Japan |
14 | Fair Trade Commission. In that capacity, Mr. Nakajima |
15 | is in charge of international affairs, where he heads |
16 | the Japanese delegations to multilateral organizations |
17 | and bilateral consultations among competition |
18 | authorities. |
19 | Before joining the JFTC, Mr. Nakajima worked |
20 | with the Asian Development Bank in Manila as Assistant |
21 | to the President and Director General of Budgeting and |
22 | Personnel Management, and for the Ministry of Finance |
23 | where he served as Research Director of the |
24 | International Finance Bureau and Chief Planning Officer |
25 | of Japan's Fiscal Investment and Loan Program. |
1 | Mr. Nakajima, the floor is yours. |
2 | MR. NAKAJIMA: Thank you very much. My name is |
3 | Hideo Nakajima. I'm the Deputy Secretary General of |
4 | Japan's Fair Trade Commission. I am really grateful to |
5 | the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade |
6 | Commission for the invitation to participate in this |
7 | important panel. It's a great honor to be here. |
8 | I was asked by DOJ and FTC to talk about |
9 | specific examples of how JFTC applies our consumer |
10 | policy to single-firm conduct. In doing so, first let |
11 | me take a few minutes to briefly explain about our |
12 | general statutory or legal framework on the regulation |
13 | of single-firm conduct, since such framework, I believe, |
14 | looks different from that of United States as well as |
15 | that of the EU, and then I would like to present several |
16 | specific cases regarding single-firm conduct in our |
17 | nation. |
18 | So, first, let me explain the basic framework of |
19 | our Antimonopoly Act, which is Japan's basic competition |
20 | law. In our country, single-firm conduct is regulated |
21 | by two different provisions. One is private |
22 | monopolization; the other is unfair trade practices. |
23 | First, private monopolization. Private |
24 | monopolization is prohibited in Section 3 of the AMA and |
25 | defined in Section 2 of the Act as those business |
1 | activities of a firm which brings about a substantial |
2 | restraint of competition in any particular field of |
3 | trade by excluding or controlling the business |
4 | activities of other firms. |
5 | Exclusion is interpreted as making it difficult |
6 | for other firms to continue their business activities or |
7 | preventing other firms from entering the market. |
8 | "Control" means to deprive other firms of their freedom |
9 | of decision-making concerning their business activities |
10 | and to force them to obey the controller's intents. |
11 | Regarding "substantial restraint of |
12 | competition," the Tokyo High Court opined that |
13 | "restraining competition substantially means bringing |
14 | about a situation in which competition itself has |
15 | significantly lessened and thereby a specific firm or |
16 | firms can control the market by determining freely, to |
17 | some extent, prices, qualities, volumes, and various |
18 | other terms on its or their own volition." |
19 | Unlike U.S. and EC regulations on single-firm |
20 | conduct, the provision of the AMA concerning private |
21 | monopolization does not refer to the position of a |
22 | relevant firm in the market. Therefore, in our legal |
23 | framework, dominant position of a firm or firm's |
24 | dominance is not a statutory prerequisite for |
25 | establishing private monopolization, and in determining |
1 | whether a specific single-firm conduct falls under |
2 | private monopolization, that is, whether its specific |
3 | unilateral conduct has substantially restrained |
4 | competition in the market, various relevant factors |
5 | should be considered in a comprehensive manner. Those |
6 | factors to be taken into account would include market |
7 | characteristics, market shares, entry barriers, buyer |
8 | power as well as the relevant unilateral conduct and its |
9 | anticompetitive effects. |
10 | Of course, it would be quite natural to presume |
11 | that a firm which can control the market with some |
12 | latitude of its own volition by excluding or controlling |
13 | the business activities of other firms usually has a |
14 | certain degree of market dominant position or |
15 | substantial market power. Actually, as we will see |
16 | later, that is the case for all the private |
17 | monopolization cases the JFTC has handled so far. |
18 | Regarding the remedial measures for private |
19 | monopolization, the JFTC is to issue an order to cease |
20 | the conduct of exclusion or control bringing about |
21 | private monopolization, and to take necessary measures |
22 | to restore competitive situation. |
23 | In addition, by the amendments to the AMA, which |
24 | became effective at the beginning of this year, |
25 | administrative surcharges are now to be imposed on a |
1 | firm in case of private monopolization caused by the |
2 | control of other firms' business activities. This is |
3 | because such controlling type of private monopolization |
4 | where the powerful firm dominates the business |
5 | activities of other firms in the market and thereby |
6 | control the prices, volumes of supplies, customers of |
7 | their relevant products or services is considered not |
8 | different from cartels in terms of its economic |
9 | consequences on competition in a market. |
10 | Criminal sanctions such as imprisonment (up to |
11 | the maximum of three years) and fines (up to the maximum |
12 | of 5 million yen in case of natural persons and 500 |
13 | million yen in case of legal persons) are applicable to |
14 | private monopolization like cartel cases. However, so |
15 | far criminal sanctions have never been imposed on any |
16 | private monopolization cases. |
17 | Another provision stipulating regulations on |
18 | single-firm conduct in the AMA is unfair trade |
19 | practices, which are prohibited by Section 19 of the |
20 | AMA. Unfair trade practices refer to several specific |
21 | types of conduct designated by the JFTC in its |
22 | notifications as ones tending to impede fair |
23 | competition. |
24 | Among various types of unfair trade practices, |
25 | such as, one, unjust refusal to deal, two, unjust |
1 | dealings on exclusive terms, three, unjust dealings on |
2 | restrictive terms, four, unjust low sales prices, five, |
3 | unjustly discriminatory prices, six, unjust tie-in |
4 | sales, and seven, unjust interferences with competitor's |
5 | transactions, can be considered to be used as means to |
6 | create or maintain monopolies by controlling or |
7 | excluding competitors, and regulations against those |
8 | types of conduct are aimed at preventing private |
9 | monopolization at an incipient level. |
10 | In this connection, let me just touch upon the |
11 | multiple functions which the regulation on unfair trade |
12 | practice under the Act are to serve. That is, in |
13 | addition to supplementary function to regulations on |
14 | private monopolization, which I just referred to, unfair |
15 | trade practices regulate other types of single-firm |
16 | conduct, such as customer inducement by deceptive or |
17 | unjust benefits practices, and abuse of superior power |
18 | or what we call dominant bargaining position, which is |
19 | considered as undermining the very basis of fair |
20 | competition itself. Maybe it's better to briefly |
21 | explain here what dominant bargaining position means in |
22 | AMA to avoid possible misunderstanding. |
23 | The dominant bargaining position means that |
24 | large-scale firm, like a large-scale retailer, has a |
25 | superior power in bilateral transactions with it's |
1 | counterpart, like by small-scale supplier who is heavily |
2 | dependent on such large-scale firm for their business. |
3 | The large-scale firm does not necessarily have to be |
4 | absolutely dominant in a relevant market. In Japan, |
5 | abusive conduct by such dominant bargaining power, such |
6 | as coercive behaviors by large-scale retailer against |
7 | his small-scale suppliers heavily dependent on the |
8 | retailer have been a serious concern among the public, |
9 | and JFTC has recently dealt vigorously with those cases |
10 | among various types of unfair trade practice. |
11 | Anyway, a single-firm conduct falls under the |
12 | unfair trade practices, thereby prohibited, if such a |
13 | conduct is found to belong to any of these specified |
14 | conducts designated by the JFTC and to tend to impede |
15 | fair competition. "Tending to impede fair competition" |
16 | is assumed not to have comparable anticompetitive effect |
17 | to "substantial restraint on competition," which is |
18 | necessary for violation of the prohibition of private |
19 | monopolization. |
20 | As such, the regulations on the unfair trade |
21 | practices are basically applicable to both "dominant" |
22 | firms and "nondominant" firms. However, regarding some |
23 | types of conduct designated by the JFTC as unfair trade |
24 | practices, for example, unjust dealing on exclusive |
25 | terms, whether a firm is "influential in the market" or |
1 | not, is considered. |
2 | According to the Guidelines Concerning |
3 | Distribution Systems and Business Practices issued by |
4 | the JFTC, whether a firm is "influential in a market" or |
5 | not is determined by, among other things, the firm's |
6 | market share or its market position. Here, in order for |
7 | a firm to be found influential, either the market share |
8 | of no less than 10 percent or the market position among |
9 | the top three is prerequisite. |
10 | Regarding remedies for unfair trade practices, |
11 | as in the case of private monopolization, a cease and |
12 | desist order, or order of taking elimination measures, |
13 | is to be issued, though unlike private monopolization, |
14 | neither of administrative surcharges nor criminal |
15 | sanctions are to be imposed. |
16 | Now, let me go to the enforcement activities of |
17 | the JFTC on single-firm conduct regulations. |
18 | First, the private monopolization. Since the |
19 | enactment of the AMA in 1947, the JFTC has found illegal |
20 | a total of 15 cases of private monopolization, and for |
21 | the last ten years, we have dealt with nine cases. Most |
22 | of the recent cases are excluding type of private |
23 | monopolization. On the other hand, for the last ten |
24 | years, we have handled a total of more than 200 cartel |
25 | cases. |
1 | As already mentioned, whether some specific |
2 | single-firm conduct is found to fall under private |
3 | monopolization is to be determined by taking into |
4 | consideration various relevant factors comprehensively |
5 | on a case-by-case basis. However, in actual |
6 | enforcements, we have taken legal measures only for |
7 | those cases where substantial restraints of competition |
8 | in the market have been quite obvious. Let me take up |
9 | two examples. |
10 | The first one is the case against Paramount Bed |
11 | Company, Limited (Paramount Bed), where the decision was |
12 | issued on March 31, 1998. |
13 | The relevant market of this case was the one on |
14 | the hospital bed ordered by Tokyo Metropolitan |
15 | Government's Finance Department, and the Paramount Bed |
16 | held approximately 90 percent share in this market and |
17 | other two manufacturers held the rest. Seeing the whole |
18 | Japanese market of the hospital bed, the market |
19 | situation was not so different, and Paramount Bed |
20 | manufactured and sold the majority of hospital beds |
21 | ordered by the government or by local municipalities. |
22 | Under such a market condition, Paramount Bed |
23 | approached the procurement officials to craft tender |
24 | specifications that would only apply to products |
25 | manufactured by Paramount Bed. By means of this |
1 | conduct, Paramount Bed was able to exclude the business |
2 | activities of other hospital bed manufacturers. |
3 | Also, in the situation that manufacturers were |
4 | not allowed to participate in bids, Paramount Bed |
5 | controlled the business activities of bid participants |
6 | by choosing a successful bidder among the participants |
7 | who sell its beds, and by indicating respective bidding |
8 | prices to successful bidders as well as other bidding |
9 | participants. Moreover, Paramount Bed provided funds to |
10 | bid participants in order to ensure that those |
11 | participants would obey the instruction of Paramount |
12 | Bed. |
13 | The JFTC found that the conduct by Paramount Bed |
14 | fell under the private monopolization, as it excluded |
15 | the business activities of other hospital bed |
16 | manufacturers and controlled the business activities of |
17 | its supplier and therefore substantially restricted |
18 | competition in the market by exercising the monopoly |
19 | power (dominance). Therefore, the JFTC ordered |
20 | elimination measures to Paramount Bed. |
21 | The second case is the one against Hokkaido |
22 | Shimbun Press, where the consent decision was issued on |
23 | February 28, 2000. |
24 | The relevant market of this case is the daily |
25 | newspaper market in the Hakodate area, which is located |
1 | in the southern part of Hokkaido. Hokkaido Shimbun |
2 | published a general daily newspaper that accounted for a |
3 | majority of general daily newspaper publications in the |
4 | Hakodate area. |
5 | Under the market circumstances, when Hakodate |
6 | Shimbun was entering the daily newspaper market in the |
7 | Hakodate area, Hokkaido Shimbun obstructed the entry of |
8 | Hakodate Shimbun and carried out the following actions |
9 | to hinder their business: |
10 | First, Hokkaido Shimbun applied for trademark |
11 | registration to the Patent Agency regarding nine |
12 | mastheads, including "Hakodate Shimbun," that would be |
13 | used when publishing newspapers in the Hakodate area, |
14 | although they had no specific plans to use those |
15 | mastheads. |
16 | Second, the main newspaper publishers in |
17 | Hokkaido received articles through Jiji Press and Kyodo |
18 | News Service. Based on a priority policy with prior |
19 | contractors where Jiji Press would not deliver articles |
20 | against the will of the present contractors, Hokkaido |
21 | Shimbun implicitly solicited Jiji Press not to deliver |
22 | articles to the Hakodate Shimbun so that Jiji Press and |
23 | Hakodate Shimbun could not conclude a delivery |
24 | agreement. |
25 | Third, to make it difficult for Hakodate Shimbun |
1 | to earn advertisements revenues, even in the situation |
2 | where damage to Hokkaido Shimbun itself was expected, |
3 | Hokkaido Shimbun split the price of inserting |
4 | advertisements in local edition in half for small and |
5 | medium-sized companies, who would be the targets for |
6 | Hakodate Shimbun for collecting advertisements. |
7 | The JFTC found that the conduct by Hokkaido |
8 | Shimbun fell under excluding type of private |
9 | monopolization, as it excluded the business activities |
10 | of Hakodate Shimbun and substantially restricted |
11 | competition in the market. Hokkaido Shimbun appealed |
12 | for a hearing procedure against the recommendation but |
13 | finally accepted to take measures issued by the JFTC. |
14 | Next, enforcement activities of unfair trade |
15 | practices. |
16 | For the last ten years, the JFTC has taken legal |
17 | measures against around 50 cases of unfair trade |
18 | practices, including 10 cases of dealing on exclusive or |
19 | restrictive terms, and nine cases of interference with |
20 | transaction. |
21 | In determining whether any specific single-firm |
22 | conduct falls under unfair trade practices, that is, |
23 | whether it tends to impede fair competition, basically |
24 | speaking, as in the case of private monopolization, |
25 | various relevant factors should be taken into account on |
1 | a case-by-case basis. For example, in a case concerning |
2 | discriminatory pricing, the Tokyo High Court opined that |
3 | various factors, including the structure and development |
4 | of the relevant market, the difference of supply costs, |
5 | market position of the concerned retailer (market |
6 | share), and subjective intentions for setting price |
7 | differentials would need to be taken into account in a |
8 | comprehensive way (April 27, 2005). |
9 | On the other hand, in this connection, it should |
10 | be noted that regarding unfair trade practices, the JFTC |
11 | has designated in its series of notifications those |
12 | types of single-firm conduct which are likely to tend to |
13 | impede fair competition, and has also clarified more |
14 | specifically what kinds of conduct violate our AMA as |
15 | unfair trade practices in various guidelines, including |
16 | Guidelines Concerning Distribution Systems and Business |
17 | Practices which was issued in 1991 to address the final |
18 | report of U.S.-Japan Structural Impediments Initiative |
19 | in 1990. Therefore, we believe that there has been a |
20 | certain level of clarity, predictability and |
21 | transparency secured in the determination of unfair |
22 | trade practices. |
23 | Let me take up one example of the case of unfair |
24 | trade practices, which involved a market dominant |
25 | company in Japan, Microsoft KK (MSKK), a subsidiary of |
1 | Microsoft Corporation, and the recommendation decision |
2 | was issued on December 14, 1998. |
3 | According to the decision, the market situation |
4 | of the case was as follows. First, MS Excel had been |
5 | popular among consumers since 1993 and had acquired the |
6 | top market share for spreadsheet software. On the other |
7 | hand, MS Word was originally an English word processor |
8 | and it was said that the function for Japanese language |
9 | did not work very well, and thus, "Ichitaro" produced by |
10 | the Japanese software company had the top share for word |
11 | processor software in Japan in 1994. |
12 | In the market situation, MSKK decided to take a |
13 | policy to make PC manufacturers pre-install both MS |
14 | Excel and MS Word in their PCs in 1995. On the other |
15 | hand, many PC manufacturers, including major ones, asked |
16 | MSKK to license only MS Excel because they preferred to |
17 | pre-install Ichitaro rather than MS Word. However, MSKK |
18 | rejected this proposal and finally made these PC |
19 | manufacturers accept the license agreement where PC |
20 | manufacturers should pre-install not only MS Excel but |
21 | also MS Word in their PCs. |
22 | In addition, MSKK decided to take a position |
23 | that it made PC manufacturers pre-install not only MS |
24 | Excel and MS Word but also MS Outlook schedule |
25 | management software in their PCs, in 1996. Since there |
1 | was another type of schedule management software, which |
2 | held the top market share, and was called Organizer |
3 | produced by Lotus Corporation, a part of the PC |
4 | manufacturers asked MSKK to license only MS Excel and MS |
5 | Word in order to pre-install Lotus Organizer instead of |
6 | MS Outlook. However, MSKK again rejected the proposal |
7 | and finally made all manufacturers accept installing MS |
8 | Outlook as well as both MS Excel and MS Word in their |
9 | PCs. |
10 | The JFTC found that MSKK unjustly made PC |
11 | manufacturers buy its word processor software by tying |
12 | it with its popular spreadsheet software. In addition, |
13 | MSKK unjustly made PC manufacturers buy its schedule |
14 | management software by tying it with its spreadsheet |
15 | software and word processor software. These conducts |
16 | fell under the category of illegal tie-in sales. |
17 | In summary, as I have mentioned, under our AMA, |
18 | single-firm conduct can be regulated by either private |
19 | monopolization or unfair trade practices. In both |
20 | cases, a case-by-case basis approach is to be taken in |
21 | determining whether concerned conduct is unlawful or |
22 | not, by considering all relevant factors |
23 | comprehensively. |
24 | Finally let me touch upon the current |
25 | discussions related to regulations against single-firm |
1 | conduct which have been developed in the Antimonopoly |
2 | Act Study Group established in Cabinet Office as a |
3 | private discussion body under the Chief Cabinet |
4 | Secretary. At that group, there is an argument that |
5 | surcharge should be imposed on not only controlling type |
6 | of private monopolization but also excluding type of |
7 | private monopolization. |
8 | Also, others argue that even some types of |
9 | unfair trade practices should be subject to surcharge. |
10 | As an official of the JFTC, since these discussions |
11 | would affect the future regulation system against |
12 | single-firm conduct, I would like to carefully study |
13 | various views of relevant parties and continue to |
14 | monitor future discussion in this study group. |
15 | Finally, needless to say, ongoing discussions |
16 | here in the United States and the EC on single-firm |
17 | conduct is very helpful and valuable to advance our own |
18 | thinking on the regulations on single-firm conduct. We |
19 | will continue to closely monitor such discussion. |
20 | Thank you very much for your kind attention. |
21 | (Applause.) |
22 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you very much, Mr. Nakajima, |
23 | for that perspective from Japan. |
24 | Moving to Mexico, I'm pleased to introduce |
25 | Eduardo Perez Motta, the Chairman of Mexico's Federal |
1 | Commission on Competition. Before joining the CFC, |
2 | Eduardo was ambassador and permanent representative of |
3 | Mexico to the World Trade Organization. He's also |
4 | headed the Representation Office of the Ministry of |
5 | Trade and Industrial Development in Brussels, where he |
6 | coordinated the Mexican team negotiating the Free Trade |
7 | Agreement between Mexico and the European Union. |
8 | Eduardo? |
9 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Good morning. I would like to |
10 | first of all thank the DOJ and the FTC, my good friends, |
11 | Tom Barnett and Debbie Majoras, for inviting me to |
12 | participate in these hearings. It is a real pleasure |
13 | and a privilege to be here today. |
14 | For a relatively small economy, best practices |
15 | abroad become an important instrument to promote or to |
16 | maintain or to try to maintain best practices within |
17 | your country, and this was actually the case of Mexico, |
18 | where we recently had a very important overhaul in our |
19 | legal framework in competition. |
20 | So, let me first try to see if this works. It |
21 | is not responding. |
22 | (Pause in the proceedings.) |
23 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Okay, thank you. |
24 | Well, also the heart of competition policy in |
25 | Mexico comes actually from our Constitution. Article 28 |
1 | in our Constitution basically uses very strong words, |
2 | and it comes from 1857, but with very strong words |
3 | against monopolies, it says that the law will severely |
4 | punish all kinds of concentration in one or a few hands |
5 | of basic commodities, all agreements, processes or |
6 | combinations undertaken by producers, industrialists, |
7 | tradesmen, et cetera, to prevent competition or free |
8 | market access and force consumers to pay exaggerated |
9 | prices. That's the way it is written in our |
10 | Constitution. |
11 | And also, it will banish whatever constitutes an |
12 | undue exclusive advantage in favor of one or more |
13 | persons and against the public in general or a certain |
14 | social class. That's the origin and that's the heart of |
15 | competition policy in Mexico. |
16 | Even though this is a very old basic origin of |
17 | the competition law, it is not until 1993 when we |
18 | created the Federal Law of Economic Competition, which |
19 | translates those definitions in specific procedures. |
20 | So, it was not until 1993 where also the Federal |
21 | Commission on Competition for Mexico was created. So, |
22 | our institution is relatively young, and it was a month |
23 | ago when we published the first real overhaul of the |
24 | Federal Law of Economic Competition. That was a reform |
25 | approved at the end of the last legislature, which was |
1 | April, April this year, where it was published about a |
2 | month ago. |
3 | So, those specific procedures in our law |
4 | basically go in three instruments. First, merger review |
5 | process. Second, what we call absolute monopolistic |
6 | practices, which is basically cartels. And third, what |
7 | we call relative monopolistic practices, which is |
8 | precisely the topic of today's discussion, and it's in |
9 | general single-firm dominant conduct. |
10 | So, I will concentrate in the last of our |
11 | instruments, but I would have to say that in each and |
12 | every one of those instruments, in the last reform, we |
13 | got an improvement either of our procedures or we got an |
14 | important simplification of procedures, like in the case |
15 | of the merger review process, it was a major |
16 | simplification of the procedures in Mexico. We |
17 | increased the thresholds, we created a fast-track |
18 | mechanism, and we also included efficiency |
19 | considerations as an obligation for the Commission to |
20 | consider when evaluating a merger. |
21 | In the case of absolute monopolistic practices, |
22 | we introduced a major reform, which was the leniency |
23 | program, which is the state of the art. We were |
24 | inspired from best practices in the U.S., best practices |
25 | in the European Union, as well as in Canada, we used |
1 | OECD recommendations to basically build that program, |
2 | and that's a very interesting situation, because this is |
3 | the only kind of program, the leniency program in |
4 | Mexico, in the case of competition law, is the only area |
5 | where that applies in our law, in general. |
6 | So, we don't have that -- that this is the first |
7 | time that we introduced this kind of legislation, which, |
8 | of course, has a very important mechanism of incentives |
9 | basically to change the interests of players to create |
10 | that kind of solutions or even to just stabilize them in |
11 | the medium term. |
12 | So, going directly to single-firm dominant |
13 | conduct, we have to distinguish in our law two types of |
14 | situations. First, when we evaluate relative |
15 | monopolistic practices, we basically make a difference |
16 | between what we should consider as specific conduct of a |
17 | single firm which is dominant in a specific market and |
18 | this second one, which is regulation. |
19 | For the first one, for conduct, basically what |
20 | our laws says is that the relative monopolistic |
21 | practices are those acts or agreements or combinations |
22 | whose object or effect is to unduly exclude, |
23 | substantially impede access, or establish exclusive |
24 | advantages in favor of one or more persons, and this is |
25 | subject, of course, to the rule of reason, and those are |
1 | the articles in our law which are used to address these |
2 | issues. |
3 | Now, in terms of regulation, this is a |
4 | completely different situation, where you could have a |
5 | declaration on effective competition conditions, which |
6 | in this case the Commission, the Competition Commission |
7 | of Mexico, is empowered to resolve on the existence of |
8 | effective competition conditions as a prerequisite for |
9 | economic regulation, and this could be done either by a |
10 | sectorial regulator or by the Ministry of the Economy. |
11 | The way this analysis is made in our law is just |
12 | the following. The first step is to find out if the |
13 | practice exists, and we have those practices typified in |
14 | 11 specific practices. We think that this typification |
15 | basically provides a legal certainty to the companies, |
16 | because they know exactly in which cases those practices |
17 | could be sanctioned or not as long as the other |
18 | conditions, of course, apply. |
19 | We have to demonstrate the object or effect of |
20 | that practice. It is clear that the size of the firm |
21 | does not demonstrate a harm necessarily. We also have |
22 | to apply the rule of reason. The agent has to have a |
23 | substantial market power in the relevant market, and it |
24 | is clear that competitor injury does not demonstrate a |
25 | violation. And finally, efficiencies. Efficiencies |
1 | must show that the conduct has a favorable effect on |
2 | competition or that those anticompetitive effects are |
3 | offset by consumer benefits. |
4 | So, in the end, what is important is to look at |
5 | the net effect on welfare, and as Philip was saying, in |
6 | this case, the burden of proof is on the side of the |
7 | company. So, basically the agency would use the |
8 | information and the arguments that the company is giving |
9 | in order to evaluate those efficiencies. |
10 | Now, in terms of those specific practices, as I |
11 | was saying, in our law, we have identified and typified |
12 | 11 specific practices, which some of them are oriented |
13 | to single-firm dominant conduct, and some others are |
14 | other anticompetitive practices which are, of course, as |
15 | well subject to the rule of reason. |
16 | For the second type of practices, which are |
17 | other anticompetitive practices, we could include or we |
18 | include vertical market division by reason of geography |
19 | or time; vertical price restrictions; exclusionary group |
20 | boycotts; and discrimination in price, sales or |
21 | purchasing conditions. For single-firm dominant |
22 | conduct, we have identified tied sales, exclusive |
23 | dealing, refusals -- refusals to sale, predation, |
24 | loyalty discounts, cross subsidization, and raising |
25 | rivals' costs. |
1 | Of course, we have different cases that have |
2 | applied to each of these practices. For instance, in |
3 | the case of exclusive dealings, maybe the most important |
4 | case was the case of Coca-Cola, where we boast the |
5 | highest fine in the history of the Mexican Commission. |
6 | That was the case between Pepsi against Coca-Cola. |
7 | For the case of tied sales, maybe the case that |
8 | comes to my mind, was some ports in Mexico. They were |
9 | offering piloting services, and it happens that those |
10 | pilots in some of those ports also owned the boats. |
11 | They had a company where they offered the services of |
12 | the boats to transport the pilots to the ships, and it |
13 | happened that if you wanted to use a pilot, they gave |
14 | you the service only as long as you contracted at the |
15 | same time, the ships that transported those guys. So, |
16 | that was a case of tied sales, and we sanctioned those |
17 | pilots in this particular case. |
18 | The case of predation, this was an interesting |
19 | case. The most important one was on Chiclets. That was |
20 | a Warner-Lambert case against Adams, and in that case, |
21 | the case went off to the Supreme Court, and actually we |
22 | lost the case because the Supreme Court considered -- at |
23 | that time, the predation was part of a group of |
24 | practices which were not identified in the law. They |
25 | were in the rulings. So, basically the Supreme Court |
1 | said that because that was not typified in the law, it |
2 | was not possible to apply it. So, that was basically |
3 | their decision in terms of unconstitutionality of that |
4 | particular article. That was changed. That was changed |
5 | precisely in the reform that was just recently passed. |
6 | Actually, those cases, those five particular |
7 | practices, were the ones that originally were in our |
8 | rulings, and they were moved to the law in the recent |
9 | approval of the reform. |
10 | For the efficiency considerations, I would like |
11 | just to raise this in the case of WalMart in a recent |
12 | investigation in the Mexican Commission. The claim was |
13 | in this case that WalMart was pressuring its suppliers |
14 | to charge higher prices to its competitors under the |
15 | threat of suspending purchases of their products. Maybe |
16 | you have had a similar situation in the U.S. I'm not |
17 | really sure, but that could have been the case. |
18 | Efficiencies were the main arguments, and they |
19 | were offered by WalMart. They argued that lower prices |
20 | from suppliers resulted from cost reductions in its |
21 | distribution systems, better inventory management, |
22 | shorter average payment periods, et cetera, and those |
23 | efficiencies were translated into the lower prices for |
24 | consumers. So, that was the consideration, that the |
25 | weight of those arguments outweighed the possible |
1 | anticompetitive impact of that behavior, and the |
2 | Commission basically decided that the efficiency gains, |
3 | the net efficiency gains, were positive in this case, |
4 | and we closed that case. |
5 | So, let me briefly just end by speaking a little |
6 | bit about the sectorial cases, not the conduct of single |
7 | firm which has a dominant position in the market, but |
8 | the case when Mexico's competition law allows for price |
9 | regulation when this is warranted by competition |
10 | analysis, and this is important because this would apply |
11 | for most regulated sectors or for some unregulated |
12 | sectors when you have a situation of a lack of |
13 | competition in that particular market. |
14 | For the regulated sector, this is a much |
15 | clear-cut situation. You could have, in the case of |
16 | telecommunications, railroads or airports, a lack of or |
17 | the absence of competition conditions and then the need |
18 | to regulate prices in very specific cases. |
19 | In the second situation, which is when the |
20 | Executive has -- the Executive in Mexico has actually |
21 | the constitutional attribution to issue price controls, |
22 | and actually, the Mexican economy used to be, a few |
23 | years ago, a highly regulated economy. Most of the |
24 | prices were controlled during some time. |
25 | With the entrance into force of Mexico's |
1 | competition law in 1993, there was a specific regulation |
2 | on that. So, there was a specific restriction on that |
3 | attribution that could only apply when the Federal |
4 | Competition Commission could issue what we call a |
5 | Declaration of Lack of Competition Conditions, and only |
6 | in those conditions, prices would be regulated, and the |
7 | procedure to make this Declaration of Absence of |
8 | Competition Conditions was made in the recent reform of |
9 | the Mexican law. |
10 | One example of the first case, which is the one |
11 | in which this could apply for a regulated sector, was |
12 | the case of Telmex, when in 1997, the Commission |
13 | initiated an official procedure to determine if Telmex, |
14 | which is what we consider the dominant telephone company |
15 | in Mexico, had precisely a dominant position. We |
16 | divided the markets in to five markets, and we basically |
17 | considered that Telmex had substantial market power in |
18 | those five telephone markets, like local telephone |
19 | service, national long distance service, international |
20 | long distance service, access to interconnection to |
21 | local networks, and interurban transport. |
22 | Basically, there was an amparo, which is an |
23 | appeal by the company, and we have this case -- just |
24 | imagine, this case was started in 1997. We are in 2006, |
25 | and this case is still in the courts and has not been |
1 | solved. So, actually, from a legal point of view, I |
2 | cannot speak about dominance on Telmex, but they do have |
3 | 95 percent of the leased lines in Mexico. I'm just |
4 | finished. Actually, I'm just finished. So, just in |
5 | time. |
6 | So, thank you very much for this invitation. |
7 | It's a real honor for me to be here today, and I hope we |
8 | will have a good session, some questions and I hope |
9 | answers as well. Thank you very much. |
10 | (Applause.) |
11 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you very much, Eduardo, and |
12 | congratulations on your success in the reform of |
13 | Mexico's competition law. |
14 | We will now move to the north, and I am very |
15 | pleased to introduce Canada's Commissioner of |
16 | Competition, Sheridan Scott. Sheridan is responsible |
17 | for the administration and enforcement of Canada's |
18 | Competition Act as well as consumer protection statutes. |
19 | Before joining the Competition Bureau, she was Chief |
20 | Regulatory Officer of Bell Canada, Vice President of |
21 | Planning and Regulatory Affairs for the Canadian |
22 | Broadcasting Corporation, and Senior Legal Counsel at |
23 | the Canadian Radio Television and Telecommunications |
24 | Commission. She has also taught law at the University |
25 | of Ottawa and Carlton university. |
1 | Sheridan? |
2 | MS. SCOTT: Thank you very much, Randy, and I |
3 | would like to join my colleagues in saying what an honor |
4 | and a privilege it is to be here today and how thankful |
5 | I am for the invitation from the DOJ and the FTC to be |
6 | able to talk to you this morning a bit about Canada's |
7 | competition law. |
8 | As Randy mentioned, as Commissioner of |
9 | Competition, I am responsible for the administration and |
10 | enforcement of the Competition Act. Under our |
11 | legislation, the single-firm anticompetitive behavior is |
12 | captured by the abuse of dominance provisions found in |
13 | Sections 78 and 79 of our legislation. |
14 | This morning, I'd like to outline the |
15 | Competition Bureau's approach to enforcing the abuse of |
16 | dominance provisions and the necessary elements for a |
17 | successful application under the Act. I'd also like to |
18 | discuss the most recent abuse case that went before the |
19 | Competition Tribunal, and finally, touch upon some of |
20 | the challenges that we face in trying to enforce Section |
21 | 79. |
22 | Most of the points that I'll be making this |
23 | morning can actually be found in our Abuse of Dominance |
24 | Guidelines -- found on our web site -- that are |
25 | instructions for the business community to understand |
1 | the approach that we take to enforcing the legislation. |
2 | Now, since 1986, abuse of dominant position has |
3 | been a reviewable matter under the Competition Act. |
4 | What that means is it is a matter that is not inherently |
5 | bad but subject to review by our Competition Tribunal, a |
6 | specialized court that is composed of judges as well as |
7 | laypersons with a background in accounting, business and |
8 | economics. They determine whether, on balance, |
9 | anticompetitive conduct has substantially lessened or |
10 | prevented competition or is likely to do so. |
11 | It's only once a firm becomes dominant in its |
12 | relevant market that the firm's behavior is open to |
13 | examination under Section 79. The Act outlines a test |
14 | with three essential elements, all of which must be met |
15 | in order to conclude that an abuse of dominant position |
16 | has occurred. |
17 | Firstly, the Bureau must demonstrate to the |
18 | Tribunal that one or more persons substantially or |
19 | completely control throughout Canada or a part of it a |
20 | class or species of business. In other words, you must |
21 | demonstrate that a company is dominant in its market. |
22 | Now, our analysis begins, not surprisingly, with a |
23 | definition of a relevant product market, looking at a |
24 | number of factors, most importantly, substitutability. |
25 | The geographic market is also defined, and here the |
1 | Bureau will consider factors such as the evidence of |
2 | foreign competition, imports, and transportation costs. |
3 | Once the product and geographic market have been |
4 | defined, the law requires a determination of market |
5 | power. This requirement is fundamental to a success |
6 | under an application under Section 79. The Tribunal has |
7 | clarified that high market share together with barriers |
8 | to entry will typically be sufficient to support a |
9 | finding of market power. A prima facie conclusion of |
10 | market power may be made on the basis of high market |
11 | share alone, but factors such as barriers to entry, |
12 | excess capacity, and countervailing powers also normally |
13 | bear in the Bureau's assessment. |
14 | To date, the cases brought before the Tribunal |
15 | have all included respondents which possessed very high |
16 | market shares; indeed, in excess of 80 percent in all |
17 | examples. In the Abuse Guidelines, the Bureau states |
18 | that a market share of less than 35 percent will |
19 | normally not give rise to concerns of market power, |
20 | while the Tribunal has indicated that a market share of |
21 | less than 50 percent cannot be considered a prima facie |
22 | indication of market power. Whether a firm with market |
23 | share falling below 50 percent would be found to exhibit |
24 | market power remains to be tested before our Tribunal. |
25 | The second element the Bureau must make out is |
1 | that the dominant person or persons have engaged in or |
2 | are engaging in a practice of anticompetitive acts. A |
3 | business must engage in more than an isolated act to |
4 | constitute a practice, which means engaging in several |
5 | acts of the same nature or several acts of a different |
6 | nature. Assessing when behavior is anticompetitive is |
7 | still complex. Some examples of behavior, such as the |
8 | introduction of a new brand or aggressive pricing could |
9 | have a procompetitive business purpose and not an |
10 | anticompetitive business purpose, so we're very careful |
11 | to look into the differences in those sorts of |
12 | behaviors. |
13 | Now, Section 78 provides a nonexhaustive list of |
14 | anticompetitive acts. The section references acts such |
15 | as the preemption of scarce facilities or resources |
16 | required by a competitor for the operation of its |
17 | business; margin squeezing, requiring a supplier to sell |
18 | to only certain customers. The Tribunal has also found |
19 | other facts that are not listed in the legislation, such |
20 | as the use of long-term exclusive contracts, to be |
21 | anticompetitive when engaged in by a dominant firm. |
22 | In order to be found anticompetitive, the |
23 | behavior engaged in must have a predatory, exclusionary |
24 | or disciplinary purpose vis-a-vis a competitor. The |
25 | Tribunal does not require evidence of subjective intent, |
1 | but rather, evidence as to the overall character or |
2 | purpose of the act in question. This is determined by |
3 | considering factors such as the reasonably foreseeable |
4 | or expected consequences of acts, any business |
5 | justification, and any evidence of subjective intent, |
6 | the so-called "smoking gun." |
7 | For example, in a case involving Laidlaw, the |
8 | Tribunal found that acts engaged in by Laidlaw could |
9 | only be interpreted as being targeted towards its |
10 | competitors. The respondent in that case had acquired |
11 | competitors and imposed onerous no-compete clauses in |
12 | the purchase agreements, utilized long-term contracts |
13 | with highly restrictive clauses, and intimidated both |
14 | customers and competitors through threats of litigation. |
15 | In assessing all the facts of that case, the Tribunal |
16 | had no difficulty concluding that Laidlaw had engaged in |
17 | a practice of anticompetitive acts in the relevant |
18 | markets. |
19 | In each potential abuse case, once dominance, |
20 | the first element that I described, and a practice of |
21 | anticompetitive acts, the second element, has been |
22 | established, the Commissioner must still convince the |
23 | Tribunal that there has been a substantial negative |
24 | effect on competition as a result of the anticompetitive |
25 | act. This third element under Section 79 requires that |
1 | the practice has had, is having or is likely to have the |
2 | effect of preventing or lessening competition |
3 | substantially in a market. |
4 | This requirement ensures that the Bureau examine |
5 | the effect on competition as a whole, not just taking |
6 | into account the repercussions of the practice on a |
7 | specific competitor. In assessing the effect on |
8 | competition, the Tribunal will examine the degree to |
9 | which the anticompetitive acts preserve or enhance the |
10 | dominant firm's market power; that is, through the |
11 | preservation or enhancement of barriers to entry or |
12 | expansion. While the issue of substantial lessening of |
13 | competition has been considered by the Tribunal, it has |
14 | not yet had the opportunity to comment on the |
15 | substantial prevention of competition, something that |
16 | we're looking at and seeing in cases that we can take to |
17 | it. |
18 | The Tribunal has noted in Tele-Direct, a case |
19 | concerning directory advertising, that where a firm has |
20 | a very high degree of market power in a market, even an |
21 | act that has a small impact on the competitiveness of a |
22 | given market may be considered substantial. |
23 | In assessing the impact of a practice on |
24 | competition, the Bureau uses a "but for" test; namely, |
25 | but for the anticompetitive practice in question, would |
1 | there be significantly greater competition? This test |
2 | has recently been endorsed by our Federal Court of |
3 | Appeal in the Canada Pipe case, to which I will return |
4 | shortly. |
5 | Under this standard, the question is not simply |
6 | whether the relevant market would be competitive in the |
7 | absence of the impugned practice, nor whether the level |
8 | of competitiveness observed in the presence of the |
9 | impugned practice is acceptable; rather, the question is |
10 | whether, absent the anticompetitive acts, the market |
11 | would be characterized by materially lower prices, |
12 | greater choice, or better service. |
13 | Requiring a linkage between an act and an |
14 | anticompetitive effect also requires that the Bureau |
15 | consider all potential reasons for the maintenance or |
16 | enhancement of market power and isolate the effects of |
17 | the anticompetitive act in question. Thus, Section |
18 | 79(4) of the legislation compels the Tribunal to |
19 | consider, for example, whether the practice is a result |
20 | of superior competitive performance. This is not the |
21 | same as an efficiencies defense which exists in our law |
22 | with respect to merger review. The Bureau, as stated in |
23 | the Abuse Guidelines, takes the position that superior |
24 | competitive performance is only one factor to be |
25 | assessed in determining the cause of the substantial |
1 | lessening of competition. It is not a justifiable goal |
2 | for engaging in an anticompetitive act. |
3 | I'd now like to say a few words about the |
4 | remedies that exist under Canadian law where an abuse of |
5 | dominance has occurred. Before litigating an abuse of |
6 | dominance case, of course, the Bureau will often |
7 | approach the dominant firm whose conduct is being |
8 | investigated and see whether we can obtain a voluntary |
9 | change of behavior to address our concerns. Where |
10 | possible, alternate case resolution is pursued rather |
11 | than litigation. |
12 | However, once we're pursuing litigation and the |
13 | Tribunal has found that an abuse of dominance has |
14 | occurred, it may make an order prohibiting the |
15 | respondent from further engaging in the impugned |
16 | practice. It may also direct any respondent to the |
17 | abuse application to undertake any action, including the |
18 | divestiture of assets or shares, as are reasonably |
19 | necessary to overcome the effects in the marketplace, |
20 | but in practice, the Tribunal has never done so, so |
21 | essentially, the only remedies available to the Tribunal |
22 | are injunctive, with the one exception of the airline |
23 | industry, where there's provisions that allow for the |
24 | imposition of administrative monetary penalties. |
25 | We are on record, supported by others, such as |
1 | the OECD, that a lack of financial consequences for a |
2 | dominant firms found to have abused their position is a |
3 | significant shortcoming in our legislation. This |
4 | shortcoming is all the more acute in light of the fact |
5 | that only the Commissioner is able to apply to the |
6 | Competition Tribunal under Section 79, and civil damages |
7 | for injured parties are not available through the |
8 | ordinary court process for abuse of dominance. |
9 | There is limited case law on Section 79 since |
10 | only five contested cases have gone before the Tribunal |
11 | since 1986 when these provisions were introduced. Our |
12 | latest contested case, the Canada Pipe case, brought |
13 | some important clarifications and developments with |
14 | respect to the tests for abuse of dominance, and it is |
15 | the only decision that has been taken at the Federal |
16 | Court of Appeal level, and so I would like to spend a |
17 | few minutes on its findings. |
18 | Canada Pipe is a Canadian company which produces |
19 | and sells cast-iron drain, waste and vent products, DWV |
20 | products referred to. The practice at issue in this |
21 | case was Canada Pipe's Stocking Distributor Program, the |
22 | SDP program, which is described as a loyalty rebate |
23 | scheme. In contrast to a volume-based discount, under |
24 | the SDP, distributors of Canada Pipe's DWV products |
25 | obtain quarterly and yearly rebates as well as |
1 | significant point-of-purchase reductions in return for |
2 | stocking exclusively the cast-iron DWV products that are |
3 | supplied by Canada Pipe. Except for losing the yearly |
4 | and quarterly rebates, there are no penalties attached |
5 | to opting out of the SDP. |
6 | It was alleged that the SDP program enhanced and |
7 | preserved to a significant extent Canada Pipe's market |
8 | power in three relevant product markets. The Tribunal |
9 | found that Canada Pipe was, indeed, dominant in those |
10 | product markets. It also found that the SDP, though a |
11 | practice, was not anticompetitive, and regardless, did |
12 | not substantially lessen or reduce competition. |
13 | Consequently, the Competition Tribunal dismissed our |
14 | application under Section 79. |
15 | The Tribunal's decision was appealed to the |
16 | Federal Court of Appeal, and in June, the Commissioner's |
17 | appeal was allowed and the case was remanded back to the |
18 | Competition Tribunal for further consideration. Canada |
19 | Pipe has until September 22nd to decide whether or not |
20 | it will appeal the Federal Court of Appeal decision. |
21 | Now, as previously indicated, Section 79 sets |
22 | out three distinct elements that must be shown to exist |
23 | before a finding of abuse of dominant position can be |
24 | made. The Federal Court of Appeal clarified that the |
25 | applicable test under the multi-element structure of |
1 | Section 79 consists of three discrete subtests, each |
2 | corresponding to a different requisite element. The |
3 | most significant statements by the Federal Court of |
4 | Appeal relate to the second and the third elements. I |
5 | am going to go back over the ones I have just described |
6 | to you and explain to you how Canada Pipe fit into that |
7 | framework. |
8 | With respect to the second element, as |
9 | previously indicated, to be considered anticompetitive, |
10 | an act must have a predatory, exclusionary or |
11 | disciplinary negative purpose vis-a-vis a competitor. |
12 | As such, the inquiry under this part of the test focuses |
13 | upon the intended effects of the act against the |
14 | competitor, not the effects of those acts on the state |
15 | of competition in the marketplace or the general causes |
16 | thereof. As a result, some types of effects on |
17 | competition in the market might be irrelevant for the |
18 | purpose of this subtest if these effects do not manifest |
19 | through a negative effect on a competitor, or a negative |
20 | purpose, sometimes assessed through looking at the |
21 | effects. |
22 | The Federal Court of Appeal noted that the proof |
23 | of the intended nature of the negative effect on a |
24 | competitor can thus be established directly through |
25 | evidence of subjective intent or indirectly by reference |
1 | to the reasonably foreseeable consequences of the acts |
2 | themselves and the circumstances surrounding their |
3 | commission. It concluded that even though evidence of |
4 | subjective intent is neither required nor determinative, |
5 | intention remains an important ingredient of the second |
6 | element of the test under Section 79. |
7 | In particular, intention is relevant in the |
8 | sense that while a respondent cannot disavow |
9 | responsibility for the reasonably foreseeable |
10 | consequences of its act, a respondent might nevertheless |
11 | be able to establish that such consequences could not in |
12 | the context of a second element of the test be |
13 | considered the purpose or overall character of the acts |
14 | in question. |
15 | So, in appropriate circumstances, proof of a |
16 | valid business justification for the conduct in question |
17 | can overcome the deemed intention arising from the |
18 | actual or perceived ill-effects of the conduct by |
19 | showing that such anticompetitive effects are not, in |
20 | fact, the overriding purpose of the conduct in question. |
21 | In essence, a valid business justification provides an |
22 | alternative explanation as to why the impugned act was |
23 | performed. To be relevant in this case, a business |
24 | justification must be a credible efficiency or |
25 | procompetitive rationale for the conduct in general |
1 | attributable to the respondent which relates to and |
2 | counterbalances the anticompetitive effects or |
3 | subjective intents of the acts. |
4 | The Court clarified that the second element |
5 | relates to whether the impugned act exhibits the |
6 | requisite anticompetitive purpose vis-a-vis competitors, |
7 | while the third element concerns the broader state of |
8 | competition and whether the practice has the effect of |
9 | substantially lessening or preventing competition in the |
10 | market. The Court, on appeal, further clarified that |
11 | the but for test must be applied by the Tribunal in |
12 | assessing the impact of a practice of anticompetitive |
13 | acts on competition in the relevant market. |
14 | The Federal Court of Appeal judgment clarified |
15 | that the third element of the test is not whether the |
16 | markets would or did attain a certain level of |
17 | competitiveness in the absence of the impugned practice |
18 | or whether the level of competitiveness observed in the |
19 | presence of the impugned conduct was high enough or |
20 | otherwise acceptable. These are absolute evaluations, |
21 | while the statutory language of the effect of preventing |
22 | or lessening clearly demonstrates a relative and |
23 | comparative assessment. The Tribunal must therefore |
24 | compare the level of competitiveness in the presence of |
25 | the impugned practice with that which would exist in the |
1 | absence of the practice and then determine whether |
2 | preventing or lessening of competition, if any, is |
3 | substantial, and this comparison must be done with |
4 | respect to actual effects in the past, in the present, |
5 | as well as likely future effects. |
6 | In the few minutes remaining, I'd like to touch |
7 | on just some of the challenges that the Bureau has |
8 | experienced with respect to the abuse of dominant |
9 | position. Some of these issues were recently clarified |
10 | by our Federal Court of Appeal, and others remain to be |
11 | clarified, notably, joint dominance, the threshold for |
12 | dominance, essential facilities, and the regulated |
13 | conduct defense, RCD we'll call it. |
14 | Now, Section 79 contemplates the possibility |
15 | that one or more persons may be dominant in a market; |
16 | however, there have not been any contested cases |
17 | involving joint dominance. The Bureau takes the |
18 | position in cases of potential joint dominance that a |
19 | combined market share of equal to or exceeding 60 |
20 | percent would generally prompt further investigation. |
21 | In order for the Bureau to conclude that there has been |
22 | potential joint abuse of dominance, there must be |
23 | evidence to show coordinated behavior, albeit short of |
24 | conspiracy, covered by our criminal cartel provisions. |
25 | The Bureau will consider the following |
1 | questions. Is there evidence that the alleged |
2 | coordinated behavior is intended to exclude, discipline |
3 | or predate a competitor? Is there evidence of barriers |
4 | to entry into the group or barriers to entrance into the |
5 | relevant markets? Is there evidence that members of the |
6 | group have acted to inhibit intergroup rivalry? |
7 | The issue of essential facilities is another |
8 | area which is yet to be addressed in jurisprudence. |
9 | Section 78 contemplates circumstances under which the |
10 | withholding of facilities or resources essential to a |
11 | competitor might be seen as anticompetitive. The issue |
12 | of essential facilities is especially relevant in |
13 | network industries such as telecommunications that have |
14 | been or will be deregulated. It remains to be seen |
15 | under what market conditions, if any, the Tribunal would |
16 | make an order that required a dominant firm to provide a |
17 | competitor with reasonable access to its resource or |
18 | facility. Section 78 or 79, as written and as |
19 | interpreted by the Tribunal, are certainly broad enough |
20 | to tackle this difficult issue, and our Section 79 |
21 | guidelines clarify this. |
22 | This brings me to my final point on the |
23 | challenges of Section 79, and it's a fairly significant |
24 | one from our perspective, the regulated conduct doctrine |
25 | or RCD, which is similar in some way to the U.S. implied |
1 | immunity and state action doctrine. What happens when |
2 | the conduct that contravenes the Competition Act is, or |
3 | more importantly, could be regulated by another federal |
4 | provincial or municipal legislative regime? |
5 | Regardless of whether the RCD or some other |
6 | doctrine or defense immunizes the impugned conduct from |
7 | a provision of the Act, the Bureau will always consider |
8 | the regulatory context in which the conduct is engaged |
9 | where it is relevant to the application of the provision |
10 | of the act in question. We are currently in the process |
11 | of looking at telecommunications reform in Canada, and |
12 | one of the big issues has been when does the conduct, |
13 | leave the hands of the section-specific regulator and |
14 | when does it become the domain of the general |
15 | competition authority? |
16 | Our jurisprudence is minimal on the application |
17 | of the RCD for reviewable matters, such as the abuse of |
18 | dominant position. However, the Bureau will not refrain |
19 | from pursuing regulated conduct under the reviewable |
20 | matters provision, such as abuse of dominance, simply |
21 | because provincial law may be interpreted as authorizing |
22 | the conduct or as more specific than the act given that |
23 | the Bureau's mandate is to enforce the law as directed |
24 | by Parliament, not a provincial legislature or its |
25 | delegate. |
1 | Now, as mentioned, the Federal Court of Appeal |
2 | provided some much needed clarification on Section 79, |
3 | but there remain a number of frontiers left to be |
4 | explored. We will be continually seeking out cases |
5 | which test the boundaries of Section 79. That is one of |
6 | our priorities at the Bureau for this year, actively |
7 | seeking out these cases, particularly if we think the |
8 | case will provide valuable jurisprudence and a degree of |
9 | clarity to the business community as to the |
10 | circumstances in which the legislation would not be |
11 | respected. |
12 | The Competition Act, with its foundation in |
13 | modern economics, I believe has served as well since |
14 | 1986 and serves as an appropriate framework for us to |
15 | continue to explore these issues in the future. |
16 | Thank you very much. |
17 | (Applause.) |
18 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you, Sheridan, and thank you |
19 | to all our speakers. This is exactly the type of input |
20 | we were looking for to help inform our hearing process. |
21 | We will be continuing with a discussion period after a |
22 | short break. I'd like to thank all the speakers for |
23 | observing the time limitations, and I would ask you to |
24 | all do the same by returning to this room in ten |
25 | minutes, so let's start making your way back about |
1 | 11:20. Thanks. |
2 | (A brief recess was taken.) |
3 | MR. TRITELL: We are going to resume now, thank |
4 | you. |
5 | We are going to have our discussion period, and |
6 | we're going to begin by asking each of the panelists if |
7 | they'd like to spend a couple of minutes reacting to any |
8 | of the presentations that they've heard this morning. |
9 | So, we'll start with Philip Lowe, if you would |
10 | like to offer any observations. |
11 | MR. LOWE: The answer to that question is yes. |
12 | The first thing which struck me was the issue of |
13 | the scope of what we regard as potential action by |
14 | agencies against the possible anticompetitive conduct of |
15 | dominant firms, and also the way in which in some |
16 | jurisdictions the definition goes beyond issues of |
17 | dominance, the conduct of dominant firms, but to unfair |
18 | trade practices in general. |
19 | Now, I think it's fair to say that U.S. action |
20 | under Section 2 and EU action under 82, notwithstanding |
21 | the issues of price discrimination and excessive pricing |
22 | cases, which we have from time to time been engaged in, |
23 | has broadly restricted the scope of our attention to the |
24 | behavior of dominant firms and not to unfair trade |
25 | practices themselves, which are left to applications of |
1 | other aspects of law, and you can see in the German |
2 | Section 2, the distinction between the German cartel |
3 | legislation and the German unfair trade practices |
4 | legislation, and I think this distinction in U.S., |
5 | German and European traditions reflects -- indeed, we |
6 | hope confirms -- the orientation towards protecting the |
7 | competitive process with the ultimate objective of |
8 | enhancing consumer welfare. |
9 | Now, the second aspect of scope is, of course, |
10 | what several of my colleagues have referred to, which is |
11 | to what extent in recently liberalized sectors, public |
12 | utilities, the presumption has been made that because of |
13 | the significant market power of the privatized |
14 | corporations, it is impossible to rely on ex post |
15 | intervention in order to achieve a successful control of |
16 | the conduct of firms concerned, and even outside |
17 | liberalized sectors in non-U.S. jurisdictions, even in |
18 | the U.S., the power of the regulators also touches on |
19 | the issue of -- implicitly, at least -- of the |
20 | significant market power of those in network industries. |
21 | So, I think in all our jurisdictions, we share a |
22 | category of potential anticompetitive practice which we |
23 | decide needs to be dealt with by regulation, and it's |
24 | characterized in the European jurisdiction, telecom's |
25 | regulations, where we explicitly recognize competition |
1 | principles but particularly the issue of significant |
2 | market power, and we allow national regulators to impose |
3 | remedies if they can prove significant market power. |
4 | Now, this is relevant in particular to what |
5 | Sheridan's just said about the way in which there is an |
6 | interface between ex ante action and ex post action, and |
7 | in that sense we have in process, too, a review at the |
8 | moment as to whether there are categories of the |
9 | telecom's industry, for example, which can now no longer |
10 | be subject to ex ante regulation, and we do that, in |
11 | principle, by focusing on a list of markets where we |
12 | think there is still a potential problem and where price |
13 | control or price regulation and access regulation is |
14 | required up front. |
15 | So, the discussion on Section 2 and in our |
16 | discussion paper of Article 82 does not focus on these |
17 | unfair trade practices, nor does it focus on these |
18 | categories of sectors where we've decided ex ante |
19 | regulation is necessary. |
20 | Now, in the area of abuse of a dominant |
21 | position, there has been some discussion among our |
22 | economists in Europe and elsewhere as to whether, in |
23 | fact, if you prove the existence through an |
24 | effects-based analysis of abuse, isn't this sufficient? |
25 | Why do you need to go through the whole process of |
1 | defining dominance and defining significant market |
2 | power? I know that some people in this room, including |
3 | eminent members of the two agencies, have written on |
4 | this subject, and thankfully, I am comforted that by |
5 | their views, which are our views, that as agencies, we |
6 | need to focus our activity on areas where there is |
7 | likely to be the most competitive harm and where |
8 | consumer welfare is paramount ultimately, and the |
9 | screening through the test of dominance is essential for |
10 | us to proceed. |
11 | Having said that, one of the things which struck |
12 | me in listening to my colleagues, too, is that we've |
13 | concentrated very much on the issue of liability, what |
14 | are the conditions for confirming the existence of |
15 | abusive behavior of a dominant firm, and we have gone on |
16 | less but, you know, at least two of my colleagues have |
17 | referred to it as the issue of what the appropriate |
18 | remedies are to any problem. |
19 | Now, we have had, in the last five years, maybe |
20 | ten important cases under Article 82, and I do not need |
21 | to remind you of all of them, but under the heading of |
22 | predatory pricing, there's the very celebrated case in |
23 | Europe against the German Postal Service for abusive |
24 | pricing on mail parcel services, concentrating on issues |
25 | of whether the incremental costs were really covered, |
1 | and Warner, too, which was about margin squeeze, was |
2 | effectively about pricing below average variable costs, |
3 | where effectively, too, we looked at the issue of |
4 | recoupment, although we say we do not, and Virgin BA, |
5 | which is still in front of the Board of Justice, Mission |
6 | 2, related to rebates, and trying to control the |
7 | distinction between what is an abusive rebate due to |
8 | quantity or loyalty or what is aggressively competitive. |
9 | We have the cases of what is described as |
10 | Brandenburg Foods, which is otherwise known as Unilever, |
11 | and about whether the tying of a supplier to small |
12 | outlets for impulse ice cream -- impulse ice cream is |
13 | ice cream which you immediately eat, or at least spit |
14 | out -- but there was an exclusivity provision on use of |
15 | freezers and a ban on purchase of other ice creams by |
16 | the shops. When we attacked that, then the rule changed |
17 | to no other ice cream can be put in the freezers, but |
18 | eventually, we won that case. |
19 | In Coca-Cola, which Eduardo referred to -- and |
20 | we didn't sanction the company. We reached a settlement |
21 | with them, an extensive global -- in fact, global |
22 | settlement, on the abandonment of individually set |
23 | target rebates. And in the Prokent complaint against |
24 | Tomra, which is the -- Tomra is the world's -- you may |
25 | not know this, but Tomra is the world's dominant |
1 | supplier of reverse vending machines, in which you put |
2 | empty bottles into. It may sound trivial, but it's a |
3 | very, very important industry, and they had individual |
4 | rebates and bonus systems which we condemned as |
5 | anticompetitive. |
6 | MR. TRITELL: Philip, I want to give the others |
7 | a chance, but I think we will have a chance to come back |
8 | to a lot of these points in the discussion period. |
9 | Thanks very much. |
10 | MR. LOWE: Sorry, I just wanted to mention some |
11 | of these cases. |
12 | MR. TRITELL: I was glad to hear about the |
13 | impulse ice cream case. |
14 | We are going to turn to a couple of the |
15 | panelists, and I forgot to say, we have been asked by |
16 | our court reporter to speak right into the microphone. |
17 | Mr. Nakajima, would you like to make any |
18 | comments? |
19 | MR. NAKAJIMA: Let me make my comment very |
20 | brief. Since Mr. Lowe kindly referred to the Japanese |
21 | unfair trade practices, I feel that I need to respond to |
22 | his comments on this. |
23 | First of all, as I said, unfair trade practices |
24 | has multiple functions; not only it tends to prevent |
25 | private monopolization at the early stage, but also it |
1 | is tasked with protection of SMEs and consumers |
2 | functions. |
3 | Second of all, this is my personal view. |
4 | Whenever we compare Japanese law with Sherman Act of |
5 | United States or Article 81, 82 of EU, I feel that it is |
6 | not so fair, because in the case of United States, there |
7 | are 50 states. The 50 states or most of the states have |
8 | maybe their own competition laws, and in the case of EU, |
9 | of course, 25 countries -- I don't know how many of |
10 | them, but most of them, I suppose -- |
11 | MR. LOWE: It's getting that way. |
12 | MR. NAKAJIMA: -- but that is not the case for |
13 | Japan. So, under the framework of competition law or |
14 | under our antimonopoly law, it serves multiple functions |
15 | required to be fulfilled, and actually, when we spoke |
16 | with people in Asian countries, the concerns that people |
17 | had in those countries may be some types of unfair trade |
18 | practices. That's what I wanted to say on what Mr. Lowe |
19 | commented on about our unfair trade practices. |
20 | Also, I feel I need to address the comment of |
21 | Mr. Lowe about EU's discussion paper on Article 82. |
22 | Actually, JFTC highly appreciates that discussion paper |
23 | since it tends to enhance predictability, transparency, |
24 | certainty, through sound economic analysis. |
25 | We are looking forward to seeing the forthcoming |
1 | draft guidelines which will be issued I heard within |
2 | this year. In this respect, let me take up one specific |
3 | issue of concern I have. As Mr. Lowe mentioned, |
4 | discussion paper emphasized more focus on effects-based |
5 | approach, but we concerned that such focus on |
6 | effects-based approach rather than a form-based approach |
7 | may undermine or compromise predictability or |
8 | transparency or certainty in the application of Article |
9 | 82. |
10 | So, again, we are looking forward to seeing how |
11 | the guideline will address such issue of potential |
12 | conflict or trade-off between risk-based approach on the |
13 | one hand and enhanced predictability or quality on the |
14 | other hand, though. Mr. Lowe already touched upon some |
15 | ways of reaching a possible solution on this issue by |
16 | referring to creating a safe harbor based upon the |
17 | economic analysis. |
18 | Thank you very much. |
19 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you. |
20 | Eduardo? |
21 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Thank you. |
22 | Just briefly, Randy, I'd like to take two points |
23 | that were starting to be discussed by Philip. One has |
24 | to do with the case of regulation. By the Mexican law, |
25 | in regulated sectors, we basically have an ex post |
1 | application of the instrument. So, actually, before you |
2 | regulate prices, you have to ask yourself if there is a |
3 | lack of competition conditions in that particular |
4 | market. |
5 | For instance, in airports, you have to first -- |
6 | but exactly, you should not say anything unless you find |
7 | that that particular airport, for instance, doesn't have |
8 | enough competition from other airports which are |
9 | relatively close. So, you have to make the analysis if |
10 | there is a lack of competition. If there are no |
11 | conditions of competition in that particular situation, |
12 | then you have to make a declaration on the lack of |
13 | competition conditions, and then the regulator will have |
14 | the ability in that particular case to regulate those |
15 | prices. So, that's -- we produce more of an ex post |
16 | type of analysis in those cases. |
17 | And just one word on the Coca-Cola case. |
18 | Actually, we tried to negotiate a settlement with |
19 | Coca-Cola. We were basically using the argument that |
20 | Coca-Cola had already reached an agreement with the |
21 | European Commission, and we said, well, why not try in |
22 | the case of Mexico? |
23 | But my impression, and this is my really |
24 | personal impression, is that external lawyers in this |
25 | case, especially on the bottlers' side of Coca-Cola, |
1 | were not so interested in closing the case, and I guess |
2 | the incentives were just not there to try to stop the |
3 | litigation and it was impossible. So, we had to impose |
4 | the sanction. |
5 | As I said, it was the strongest sanction we have |
6 | ever imposed, because there were cases for each and |
7 | every bottler. So, the accumulation of the sanction was |
8 | relatively high. |
9 | But besides that, I would have to say that the |
10 | case became very public in Mexico because one of the |
11 | correspondents, I think it was from Associated Press, he |
12 | just discovered that there was this small grocery store, |
13 | the one that started the case against Coca-Cola, which |
14 | is something I even didn't know myself, because I got |
15 | the case a little bit late. I just went into the office |
16 | two years ago, and this case had been gong on for about |
17 | five years already, so once this cable went around, the |
18 | public opinion and the public impact on Coca-Cola in |
19 | this particular case, because of the situation that the |
20 | sanctions were basically -- I mean, that the original |
21 | case started with this sort of -- this kind of case, it |
22 | just went around, around the world. The kind -- the |
23 | declarations of these -- the owner of this small grocery |
24 | store, because the exclusive dealings of Coca-Cola and |
25 | so on. |
1 | So, my impression in the end is that the cost |
2 | for Coca-Cola, from the public exposure of this case, |
3 | was much higher than the sanction that we imposed. Even |
4 | if they had paid the sanction and forget about the |
5 | situation, it would have been cheaper than what they |
6 | paid finally in terms of legal costs and so on. |
7 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you, Eduardo. |
8 | Sheridan, any reactions? |
9 | MS. SCOTT: Just two quick comments. |
10 | One, just following up on Philip and Eduardo's |
11 | comments on regulation and how we see handling companies |
12 | that have been formed into monopolies or whatever and |
13 | the progression towards proper alignment for the |
14 | sector-specific regulator and the competition authority. |
15 | As I've understood Philip and Eduardo to address this, |
16 | one should first of all apply competition tests to |
17 | determine whether there should be deregulation. |
18 | One of the issues we have is whether the |
19 | sector-specific regulator will actually apply the same |
20 | sorts of tests of SMP that we would as competition |
21 | authorities, and part of our job in Canada is using our |
22 | advocacy ability to speak to the regulator to persuade |
23 | them that they should be applying proper competition |
24 | tests, because we will then be reassured that if they |
25 | deregulate only where there's an observance of market |
1 | power, we will then be in a position to rely on the |
2 | general Competition Act on an ex post basis and not |
3 | worry about whether we will require ex ante regulation |
4 | due to the continuing market power. |
5 | So, that remains important to us, not to have |
6 | sector-specific provisions in our Competition Act to try |
7 | to assist the sector-specific regulator in taking |
8 | competition principles into account. One of the things |
9 | we're working are on telecom-specific guidelines that |
10 | will be using examples from the telecom sector but with |
11 | a law of general application, which is what the |
12 | Competition Act is. So, we feel that's part of our |
13 | responsibility as a competition authority, to have |
14 | guidelines generally about abuse, and then to try to |
15 | find some sector-specific examples to provide guidance |
16 | to parties, because we think this guidance is extremely |
17 | important. |
18 | Now, our legislation -- I think -- legislation |
19 | seems to me is a bit like ours, is more explicit than |
20 | the general provisions you find in the EU and Japan and |
21 | the U.S. I would see all the more reason for you to |
22 | have guidelines explaining to people how you interpret |
23 | legislation, but even in the case of Canada, where we |
24 | have a number of tests specifically set out in the |
25 | legislation, I think we have a responsibility to provide |
1 | clarity to the business community through enforcement |
2 | guidelines. |
3 | MR. TRITELL: Thanks. |
4 | We are going to move into our question period. |
5 | We would like to allow a little time for discussion, so |
6 | if you will bear with us, we may run over until 10 or 15 |
7 | past 12:00, and I would like to turn to Jerry Masoudi to |
8 | begin our questions. |
9 | MR. MASOUDI: Thanks. |
10 | I would like to ask a question about remedies, |
11 | and Sheridan, you went into that issue in some detail, |
12 | stating that injunctive remedies are available on the |
13 | public side, no monetary remedies and no private |
14 | enforcement, and then, Mr. Nakajima, you suggested that |
15 | there were criminal penalties available in Japan, but |
16 | they have not been implemented in the past, and Philip, |
17 | you discussed the issue of remedies somewhat. |
18 | I wonder if we could at least start with Eduardo |
19 | and Mr. Nakajima to talk about both private and public |
20 | enforcement, the remedies that are available to either |
21 | private parties or to enforcers, and then allow Sheridan |
22 | and Philip to add anything further that they would like |
23 | to say on the matter. |
24 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Well, in the Mexican case, the |
25 | Federal Commission of Competition has both regulatory |
1 | and adjudicative powers, and they are concentrated just |
2 | in the Commission. There is no direct private right of |
3 | action, and that is, the private party harmed by |
4 | anticompetitive conduct that violates the law cannot |
5 | really file their case directly with a court of the |
6 | judicial system. They must bring their complaint before |
7 | the Commission, and only after the Commission resolves |
8 | in their favor, they may claim a damage before a court. |
9 | So, that's how we work. |
10 | MR. NAKAJIMA: Yes, in Japan, compared to the |
11 | United States, private enforcement of competition law |
12 | has not been so active; however, recently, more and more |
13 | damage actions have been brought, particularly by local |
14 | governments regarding bid-rigging cartels, reflecting a |
15 | growing concern by the local public on the damage caused |
16 | by such cartels and most of those actions are formal |
17 | actions of the JFTC's dispositions. |
18 | Regarding private monopolization cases, the |
19 | number of the private action is quite limited; however, |
20 | in the case of Hakodate Shimbun, which I just discussed |
21 | in my presentation, Hakodate Shimbun actually brought |
22 | this action before the Tokyo High Court ruled against |
23 | Hokkaido Shimbun for damages caused by Hokkaido |
24 | Shimbun's unlawful act. The case is still continuing. |
25 | Also, in addition to such damage action, on |
1 | occasion of recent amendment of the Act, the Dict |
2 | requested the government to expedite the consideration |
3 | of possible introduction of so-called collective action, |
4 | particularly for injunction of unfair trade practices. |
5 | Now, we are seeking the views of legal experts |
6 | and making research on such systems in other |
7 | jurisdictions. We plan to come up with a conclusion on |
8 | this issue by the end of the next year, that is, by the |
9 | end of 2007. |
10 | That's all. Thank you. |
11 | MR. MASOUDI: Philip, I don't know, or Sheridan, |
12 | if you have anything further to add on the issue of |
13 | remedies. |
14 | MS. SCOTT: I guess one of the issues we discuss |
15 | sometimes is the value of having a specialized court |
16 | that determines these matters, where you would have |
17 | judges. As I said, our Competition Tribunal has a |
18 | combination of judges and laypersons, and the lay |
19 | persons have background in economics and accounting and |
20 | business, and we debate sometimes whether, if there were |
21 | damage provisions introduced into our legislation, would |
22 | it be more appropriate for the damages to be assessed by |
23 | the ordinary court or would it be more appropriate, |
24 | because these are economic issues, for the damages to be |
25 | assessed by a specialized tribunal. |
1 | MR. LOWE: Just to make one distinction, once we |
2 | have established liability, then there is a sanction, |
3 | and the sanction itself acts presumably in most |
4 | instances as a deterrent to future action of the same |
5 | kind, and normally speaking, it would be accompanied by |
6 | a cease and desist order on the particular practice |
7 | concerned. |
8 | Now, if we impose a fine, the assumption is that |
9 | the corporation itself should reasonably have been aware |
10 | that it was in infringement of Article 82; therefore, it |
11 | is incumbent on us to prove that there was either |
12 | negligence or, indeed, intention in pursuing certain |
13 | practices. |
14 | As to the remedies, well, if you intervene to |
15 | solve a market failure caused by an anticompetitive |
16 | practice and you think that practice cannot be resolved |
17 | and competition conditions cannot be restored to their |
18 | situation ex ante simply by a cease and desist order, |
19 | then it is incumbent on us to indicate what the remedy |
20 | should be, and that forms part of our decision. We have |
21 | done that in Microsoft. We haven't done it in 6 Tomra/ |
22 | Prokent because the cease and desist order was |
23 | sufficient, and for AstraZeneca, which was an historical |
24 | situation. So, we have to assess whether the remedy |
25 | will be effective. |
1 | By the way, if a remedy cannot be identified as |
2 | effective, then that, in itself, could cause an agency |
3 | to bring a case to an end. |
4 | Finally, on private enforcement, you know that |
5 | it's very underdeveloped in Europe, that we are trying |
6 | to develop that. Clearly, if we have proved an abuse, |
7 | then the possibility of a follow-on action by private |
8 | corporations or individuals increases the complex of |
9 | deterrents which exists against anticompetitive |
10 | behavior. |
11 | MR. MASOUDI: Eduardo, in your present -- |
12 | MR. NAKAJIMA: May I just -- |
13 | MR. MASOUDI: Sure, Mr. Nakajima. |
14 | MR. NAKAJIMA: Let me make a short comment about |
15 | what Sheridan mentioned. Regarding damage action, the |
16 | Antimonopoly Act has provisions that a court dealing |
17 | with a private damage action can request the comments |
18 | from JFTC on the damage or assessment of damages. |
19 | Actually, in case of Hokkaido Shimbun, I just |
20 | referred to, after Hakodate Shimbun brought the damage |
21 | action to the Tokyo High Court, Tokyo High Court |
22 | requested JFTC to make a comment on how to assess the |
23 | damages caused by the action of Hakodate Shimbun and |
24 | then we submitted a comment to the Tokyo High Court. |
25 | MR. MASOUDI: Eduardo, in your presentation, you |
1 | discuss how typification can provide legal certainty, |
2 | and, of course, there are two kinds of typification that |
3 | one can imagine, the first being to say that certain |
4 | kinds of conduct are abusive, and another type of |
5 | typification, of course, would be to say that certain |
6 | kinds of conduct will not be found to be abusive, and |
7 | Philip, in your presentation, you touched on the issue |
8 | of safe harbors, and I wonder if, perhaps starting with |
9 | Sheridan down at the end, if each of you could discuss |
10 | what, if any, safe harbors do you have in place, and |
11 | what, if any, safe harbors has industry suggested to you |
12 | might be helpful in allowing them to engage in |
13 | procompetitive conduct without fear of enforcement? |
14 | MS. SCOTT: I think the issue of safe harbors is |
15 | all about predictability for the business community, in |
16 | a sense, so that because so many of these Section 79 |
17 | type, abuse of dominance type acts, can be very |
18 | procompetitive, and so when we think about safe harbors, |
19 | we think, first of all, about market shares, because |
20 | those are relatively easy to calculate, not completely |
21 | easy, but relatively easy, and so there is some guidance |
22 | that we issue through our enforcement guidelines and |
23 | also that the Tribunal has put in place. I mentioned |
24 | those in my remarks. The 35 percent and 50 percent are |
25 | critical market share figures for us. |
1 | But I think one can think about safe harbors |
2 | also through the clarification of the law, the clearer |
3 | what will be a contravention of our provisions is and |
4 | the clearer it is to the business community where we are |
5 | going to take enforcement actions, that, too, acts like |
6 | a form of safe harbor that the business communities can |
7 | look to, and that's why we find this most recent |
8 | decision of the Federal Court of Appeal useful, because |
9 | it has gone into much more detail about how to look at |
10 | those specific tests that exist during legislation than |
11 | perhaps ever before. |
12 | Now, I personally have never had any requests |
13 | for specific safe harbors or specific guidance, but I do |
14 | know that the business community is very interested in |
15 | having as much predictability and understanding of where |
16 | we are enforcing the law as possible, and we certainly |
17 | see that as part of our responsibilities. |
18 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you. |
19 | Eduardo? |
20 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Yeah, well, actually, in our |
21 | case, our law system obliges us to work in a very |
22 | detailed way in the legal text, and this is precisely |
23 | why we lost some cases by the courts, because in the |
24 | article -- that was Article 10, which is the one that |
25 | typifies the relative practices, in the seventh |
1 | paragraph, it had a broad definition. So, it said |
2 | something like "some other practices that could be found |
3 | by the Commission," and those were specified in the |
4 | rulings. So, the Court said, nope, that's not possible. |
5 | By the Constitution, you have to have each particular |
6 | practice very well defined in the law. |
7 | So, partly I think this is just because of |
8 | clarity, legal certainty for economic operators. |
9 | Another is just because our legal system obliges us to |
10 | do it that way, but, of course, there is always a |
11 | problem that one has at least to put up with, which is |
12 | the fact that there is an evolution of economic |
13 | operators, and there is always a creativity going on, |
14 | and there are, of course, new practices that could be |
15 | created over time, and that's the challenge that you |
16 | have as a regulator, which is how to deal with new |
17 | circumstances, with new ideas, with talented business |
18 | people who create some other mechanisms to displace |
19 | competitors and that create an economic cost in the |
20 | society. |
21 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you. |
22 | Mr. Nakajima? |
23 | MR. NAKAJIMA: Thank you. |
24 | As I already mentioned, JFTC has designated |
25 | several types of practices as unfair trade practices, |
1 | and also, we have issued a series of guidelines which |
2 | clarified what kind of specific single-firm conduct |
3 | falls under unfair trade practices. |
4 | In addition, as Sheridan mentioned, accumulation |
5 | of relevant cases is, I think, helpful in further |
6 | enhancing predictability and legal certainty. Thank |
7 | you. |
8 | MR. MASOUDI: Philip, I don't know if you have a |
9 | quick point to add to your previous comment. |
10 | MR. LOWE: Well, I think this goes to not just |
11 | legal certainty, which dominates the guidelines, and |
12 | safe harbors, but also the focus of the work of the |
13 | competition agency. You have to decide, frankly, which |
14 | cases or investigations to concentrate on and in which |
15 | depth, and it seems to me that in the end, we will be |
16 | distinguishing between three broad categories of cases, |
17 | those where we can offer a safe harbor in the sense of |
18 | we will not be investigating, for example, cases below X |
19 | percent market share, because we believe that at that |
20 | level of market power, insofar as market share is an |
21 | indication of market power, there would be no prima |
22 | facie case of dominance, and therefore, abuse. |
23 | The second category, nevertheless, is situations |
24 | where there could be, based upon market shares and other |
25 | indicators, a significant market power, but |
1 | nevertheless, the level at which it is -- it could be |
2 | appraised could lead us to some control of specific |
3 | indicators and parameters which could be given as a |
4 | guideline to the business and legal community as to if |
5 | these parameters can be checked, then there would be a |
6 | presumption that there would be no problem. |
7 | And then as a third area, where we would |
8 | certainly have to investigate thoroughly, and, of |
9 | course, I have omitted also the black, per se, rule |
10 | possibility, which could exist, because we've got to |
11 | look at the combination of degrees of market power and |
12 | the abuse concerned, but there could in certain |
13 | categories be some types of abuse with a certain degree |
14 | of market power which we could say from the start would |
15 | be unacceptable, and the bright light of Areeda-Turner |
16 | and the AKZO (ph) rules in our jurisdiction is an |
17 | indication of how we can do that in predation. |
18 | We have tended in our discussion paper to leave |
19 | things slightly too open in our view and just to reserve |
20 | on the possibility of the need to intervene. I don't |
21 | think we need to be quite so prudent in our final |
22 | drafting of guidelines. |
23 | MR. TRITELL: Thanks. |
24 | I'll ask two concluding questions and get brief |
25 | reactions, the first on defenses, in particular |
1 | efficiencies, which several of you have touched on in |
2 | your presentations. Maybe we can go a little bit deeper |
3 | into how you analyze efficiencies and when they come |
4 | into the analysis; in particular, whether you regard the |
5 | analysis of efficiencies as integrated into the |
6 | examination of whether there has been an abuse or |
7 | whether, having found an abuse, efficiencies come in as |
8 | a defense, and if so, by what standards you determine |
9 | whether the efficiencies are sufficient to overcome what |
10 | would otherwise be a finding of abuse. |
11 | I'll invite anyone who would like to make any |
12 | comments on that point. |
13 | Sheridan? |
14 | MS. SCOTT: Sure, I'm happy to start on that. |
15 | This is actually part of any decision that we found |
16 | particularly valuable. |
17 | As I was explaining, there are three elements to |
18 | our test. There is first a dominance element. The |
19 | second element -- and one should see these as sort of |
20 | screens, I guess, running through the assessment of |
21 | Section 79. The second one is looking at the purpose of |
22 | the Act, and I was mentioning in my remarks that we look |
23 | at whether the purpose has an exclusionary, disciplinary |
24 | or predatory effect or impact vis-a-vis competitors. |
25 | There is always a worry, we shouldn't be looking at |
1 | competitors, and certainly at the Bureau, we are looking |
2 | at lessening competition but that's the third element of |
3 | our test. |
4 | The second element is the screen we put out |
5 | looking at whether the purpose is vis-a-vis a |
6 | competitor, and what the Court does, it looks at the |
7 | overall purpose of the act to decide whether the purpose |
8 | is exclusionary, disciplinary or predatory, and then it |
9 | will look at subjective intent, which is hard to find. |
10 | It then looks at the effects on the competitor, because |
11 | one is assumed to intend the consequences of one's act, |
12 | and if we find that the person has an exclusionary, |
13 | predatory or disciplinary purpose against a competitor, |
14 | in effect, that's when efficiencies come into play. |
15 | So, the defendant can say, no, no, the purpose |
16 | of the act was not exclusionary, disciplinary or |
17 | predatory; the purpose of the act was procompetitive or |
18 | the rationale is a greater efficiency. So, it comes in |
19 | at this second element, and it can then be used to |
20 | defeat that second element of the three-part test that |
21 | we have. So, it goes to the purpose of the act. |
22 | I think this is sort of along the same |
23 | wavelength as the no economic sense test that one |
24 | sometimes sees. You're trying to get at the same sort |
25 | of matters. Why did this act take place? Does it have |
1 | any economic sense? Well, we sort of look at it saying, |
2 | well, if it has an exclusionary, disciplinary or |
3 | predatory purpose, that's suggesting to us that it |
4 | didn't have an economic purpose, but then the company in |
5 | question is allowed to come back to explain -- no, it |
6 | did make economic sense because we had some efficiency |
7 | reasons or some procompetitive reasons for carrying out |
8 | this conduct. |
9 | MR. PEREZ MOTTA: Well, in our case, |
10 | efficiencies analysis were part of the reform that was |
11 | just made recently, and it comes in two ways. First, |
12 | that the conduct positively influenced the process of |
13 | competition and free market access, that's the first |
14 | analysis that you have to make, and second, that the |
15 | benefits for consumers, to consumers, outweigh the |
16 | anticompetitive effects which could arise from these |
17 | practices. So, that's how, in our law, the analysis of |
18 | efficiencies is approached. |
19 | Of course, the details of all of this will have |
20 | to come in the rulings which we are in the process of |
21 | developing. So, we have the reforms of the law. We |
22 | will need to change the rulings, and the case for that |
23 | will have to take place in those rulings. |
24 | MR. NAKAJIMA: In our country for private |
25 | monopolies or unfair trade practice, it is essential to |
1 | determine whether specific conduct has substantially |
2 | restricted competition in the market or attempted to |
3 | impede fair competition in the market. As such, in our |
4 | nation, in the case of private monopolization or unfair |
5 | trade practices, an efficiency is not something which we |
6 | directly evaluate. |
7 | However, of course, in considering relevant |
8 | factors comprehensively, we need to pay due attention to |
9 | the issue of whether concerned conduct is actually a |
10 | legitimate or normal business behavior, business |
11 | activities, though I would say in our nation, efficiency |
12 | is not so much paid attention so far in our cases. |
13 | Thank you. |
14 | MR. LOWE: I've referred initially to the need |
15 | for a test of dominance as a prima facie -- at least a |
16 | screen for a subsequent in-depth analysis of alleged |
17 | abuse, and I say this perhaps more personally than my |
18 | agency for the moment, because we haven't written the |
19 | final version of our guidelines. We would regard the |
20 | assessment, in-depth assessment of an alleged abuse of a |
21 | dominant firm and its possible objective justification |
22 | of efficiencies, as an integrated one but not |
23 | necessarily one which has a specific chronology. It |
24 | nevertheless is an iterative process. |
25 | It starts off with the plaintiff and/or the |
1 | agency alleging abuse, affording evidence, collecting |
2 | evidence with respect to the anticompetitive effect with |
3 | consumer harm of the practice concerned. Then it is |
4 | certainly incumbent on the defendant to show that the |
5 | practices cannot be regarded as abuses because they have |
6 | either an objective justification or they have |
7 | efficiencies which are passed on to consumers. |
8 | In the final analysis, it is for the agency, if |
9 | it is to uphold a decision against the firm, to balance |
10 | the probability of the actual likely anticompetitive |
11 | effects against the supposed benefits which the |
12 | defendant firm puts forward. So, in a sense, |
13 | intellectually speaking, this is an integrated |
14 | assessment. There is no specific chronology as to how |
15 | one reaches the final result; however, there are |
16 | specific responsibilities on the agency and the |
17 | plaintiff and on the defendant and finally on the agency |
18 | to balance the process. |
19 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you. |
20 | I think given the time, we will close this |
21 | morning's session, which I have found extremely valuable |
22 | and I know will be very valuable in informing our |
23 | hearings process. At this point we will adjourn. We |
24 | will reconvene at 1:30. I hope you will be able to join |
25 | us for what will be a superb panel with four members |
1 | from the private sector. So, at this point I would just |
2 | ask you to join Jerry and me in expressing our |
3 | appreciation to our excellent panel this morning. |
4 | (Applause.) |
5 | (Whereupon, at 12:14 p.m., a lunch recess was |
6 | taken.) |
7 | |
8 | |
9 | |
10 | |
11 | |
12 | |
13 | |
14 | |
15 | |
16 | |
17 | |
18 | |
19 | |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
1 | AFTERNOON SESSION |
2 | (1:30 p.m.) |
3 | MR. TRITELL: Thank you for assembling back |
4 | promptly at 1:30 as we begin the second session of our |
5 | hearings today. I apologize to those who have already |
6 | endured these announcements this morning, but I am |
7 | compelled to repeat them, so here we go. |
8 | Again, I am Randy Tritell, the Assistant |
9 | Director for International Antitrust at the Federal |
10 | Trade Commission, and I will be moderating this session |
11 | along with Jerry Masoudi, the Deputy Assistant Attorney |
12 | General from the Department of Justice, which is |
13 | co-sponsoring these hearings with the FTC. |
14 | For our housekeeping matters, I ask everybody |
15 | again to turn off cell phones, Blackberries, and other |
16 | devices. The restrooms may be found outside of the |
17 | double doors across the lobby. If you hear alarms, |
18 | proceed calmly to the lobby, follow the FTC employees to |
19 | their gathering point, and wait for further |
20 | instructions. |
21 | This afternoon will consist of presentations by |
22 | our panelists and interchange with the moderators, but |
23 | we will not be able to provide an opportunity for any |
24 | audience interchange at this session. |
25 | I want to reiterate the thanks of this morning |
1 | to all the FTC and DOJ staff who worked hard to organize |
2 | this hearing. |
3 | This afternoon, we are very honored to have a |
4 | distinguished panel of practitioners and academics. |
5 | They are going to provide their perspectives on how |
6 | multinational companies deal with diverse antitrust |
7 | regimes around the world, especially as they relate to |
8 | the application of antitrust laws to single-firm conduct |
9 | and abuses of dominance. |
10 | We have with us George Addy, Margaret Bloom, |
11 | Phil Lugard, and Jim Rill, who Jerry will introduce at |
12 | greater length, and I also direct your attention to the |
13 | packet of biographical materials that are outside the |
14 | room. |
15 | This is the fourth in the series of ongoing |
16 | hearings by the agencies, looking at single-firm |
17 | conduct. We've had an opening session on June 20th, |
18 | followed by a session on June 22nd on predatory pricing |
19 | and predatory buying, and on July 18th, on unilateral |
20 | refusals to deal. There are transcripts and other |
21 | materials from those sessions available on the DOJ and |
22 | the FTC web sites. |
23 | We are going to ask each of our panelists to |
24 | speak for about 10 to 15 minutes to make an initial |
25 | presentation. We will then take a break. When we |
1 | return from the break, we will invite the panelists to |
2 | react to both what they've heard this morning from the |
3 | government session and to each other's presentations, |
4 | followed by a discussion that Jerry and I will |
5 | co-moderate, and we're scheduled to wind up at about |
6 | 4:00. |
7 | So, with that, let me turn the podium over to |
8 | Jerry Masoudi. |
9 | MR. MASOUDI: Our first speaker today will be |
10 | George Addy. George heads the Competition and |
11 | International Trade Group at Davies Ward Phillips & |
12 | Vineberg, LLP in Toronto. Before joining the firm, |
13 | Mr. Addy was head of the Mergers Branch of Canada's |
14 | Competition Bureau from 1989 to 1993 and was appointed |
15 | by the Canadian Cabinet to head the Competition Bureau |
16 | in 1993. He's a director of the Canadian Chamber of |
17 | Commerce and chairs its Policy Committee. He's also a |
18 | Vice-Chairman and Member of the Executive Board of |
19 | Business and Industry Advisory Committee to the OECD, |
20 | otherwise known as BIAC. |
21 | Mr. Addy? |
22 | MR. ADDY: Thank you. |
23 | Thank you, Jerry. It's indeed an honor for me |
24 | to be here today, and it's also an honor to share the |
25 | spotlight with such a distinguished panel, so thank you. |
1 | I would just add that I am going to try to bring |
2 | to my comments a perspective not only from my public |
3 | sector experience but private sector experience and |
4 | business experience. Hopefully my comments will either |
5 | inform the debate or at the very least be provocative. |
6 | At the outset, it's important for us to recall |
7 | the role of antitrust or competition agencies and their |
8 | related institutions, and I roll into "related agencies" |
9 | that the courts and tribunals and so on, are to play, |
10 | and I think Chairman Majoras on the first day put it |
11 | well. She said the FTC and Antitrust Division have the |
12 | responsibility to "ensure that competition in U.S. |
13 | markets is free of distortion and that consumers are |
14 | protected not from markets but through markets |
15 | unburdened by anticompetitive conduct and |
16 | government-imposed restrictions," and that last bit is |
17 | something I'll come back to. I would include within |
18 | "government-imposed restrictions" overly aggressive |
19 | enforcement in this area of the law, and I'll tell you a |
20 | bit more about that in a moment. But that type of |
21 | characterization of what the roles of the institutions |
22 | are applies equally to Canada, and frankly, I expect in |
23 | other jurisdictions. |
24 | The issue we're dealing with is obviously a |
25 | serious one. We wouldn't be having these hearings if it |
1 | wasn't. We live in a world and era characterized by |
2 | globalized markets and increasing concentration levels |
3 | in many sectors. Ensuring the right approach to |
4 | assessing allegations of abuse in this context is |
5 | critical. It's not only important from the perspective |
6 | of economic rents, who gets them, but it also poses a |
7 | challenge, the globalization of entities and conduct |
8 | poses a challenge to domestic antitrust agencies, |
9 | competition agencies, who must enforce their domestic |
10 | law in that environment, and there are many challenges |
11 | that flow from that. |
12 | One of the issues in trying to grapple with that |
13 | challenge is trying to balance the tension that arises |
14 | between the desire for very defined and detailed and |
15 | predictable rules that will readily identify an |
16 | unacceptable abusive conduct and the fact that most of |
17 | the conduct that falls within this gray zone is, |
18 | frankly, procompetitive and should not be inadvertently |
19 | chilled. So, the theme of my remarks today is |
20 | essentially as consideration is given to the various |
21 | presentations at these hearings, one should be very |
22 | cautious about what you do with that information by the |
23 | way of changing your enforcement practices. So, with |
24 | that backdrop, a few brief comments. |
25 | First, a few cases are obvious in this area, |
1 | obviously problematic, most are not. The practice or |
2 | behavior that we are trying to target is conduct which |
3 | lies in the gray zone between acceptable and |
4 | unacceptable. The cases outside the zone, frankly, |
5 | everybody can spot them. What we're dealing with here |
6 | is this gray zone, and I think when you compare these |
7 | provisions to other provisions of the competition laws, |
8 | be they conspiracy provisions or even merger provisions, |
9 | there's a lot more gray in the spectrum when you're |
10 | dealing with potentially abusive behavior than there is |
11 | in some of the these other areas. |
12 | That grayness was recognized by our Canadian |
13 | Parliament in 1986 when they decriminalized the |
14 | provision and converted it into what we call a |
15 | reviewable practice, and Sheridan Scott took you through |
16 | some of that background this morning. There is no |
17 | presumption in our law, rebuttable or otherwise, that |
18 | any particular conduct is unlawful. Market behavior is |
19 | subject to study by the Commissioner, and if the |
20 | Commissioner has a problem with the behavior, the |
21 | behavior is then brought before an administrative |
22 | tribunal for an adjudication in an adversarial, |
23 | litigious process, and that tribunal in Canada is a |
24 | mixture of lay and judicial members. |
25 | The choice of the Tribunal being structured that |
1 | way in Canada was not accidental; it was deliberate. |
2 | Given the nature of the conduct subject to challenge |
3 | under the Act, Parliament thought it wise to have the |
4 | adjudication benefit not only from judicial members |
5 | bringing the legal expertise to the table, but also the |
6 | business people who would be perhaps closer to the world |
7 | of business and business decision-making. |
8 | As a side observation, one of the criticisms I |
9 | would bring to the way the model has worked to date is |
10 | we haven't heard enough from the lay members of the |
11 | Tribunal. It tends to be a very, very judicialized |
12 | process, perhaps overly so. |
13 | The second comment I would make is that there is |
14 | going to be a tension or a battle between a desire for |
15 | predictability and the need for some flexibility or |
16 | uncertainty. It will, indeed, be difficult to reconcile |
17 | the desire of many participants, and among those are |
18 | included counsel, business people, even competition |
19 | agencies, to have clear and detailed rules that provide |
20 | predictability of treatment of behavior under antitrust |
21 | scrutiny with the need for some flexibility on the part |
22 | of the agencies and creative competition and freedom and |
23 | a healthy measure of uncertainty in the marketplace. |
24 | Trying to develop general principles to guide |
25 | agencies and businesses faced with this behavior with a |
1 | better understanding is a very, very worthwhile pursuit, |
2 | and the principles outlined earlier on in these hearings |
3 | by Chairman Majoras and Assistant AG Barnett are an |
4 | excellent place to begin, and perhaps those principles |
5 | can be refined even further, but I don't think we should |
6 | expect the kind of detail or precision that some |
7 | proponents might advocate. |
8 | There's already been testimony earlier in these |
9 | proceedings about potential problems associated with |
10 | various tests, whether it's the "but for," the "no |
11 | economic sense" or any other test. There's also been |
12 | evidence of some problems with the tools used. The |
13 | transcripts of those proceedings were actually quite |
14 | entertaining to read in preparation for today, whether |
15 | it's marginal or variable cost or what have you. |
16 | I think what that tells you is that whatever |
17 | tool you pick, there's going to be controversy and |
18 | there's not going to be the certainty that some people |
19 | might be seeking. There is no -- as somebody mentioned |
20 | this morning -- there is no Holy Grail. So, while many |
21 | of the tools and screening devices will be helpful, and |
22 | frankly, they will probably keep many of us in |
23 | government and the private sector gainfully employed for |
24 | the foreseeable future, I think we shouldn't lose |
25 | sight -- and particularly in this post-Enron/ WorldCom |
1 | environment we shouldn't lose sight of the fact that |
2 | understanding business behavior is a lot more than just |
3 | doing arithmetic, and whatever screening device you use, |
4 | cost measure or otherwise, you have to be very, very |
5 | sensitive to the broader needs of the analysis, and one |
6 | of those issues obviously is intent. |
7 | There's also, as I mentioned, a lot of merit in |
8 | providing guidance through guidelines or elaborating on |
9 | general principles, just as the competition regimes of |
10 | the world have proliferated, and that has driven an |
11 | increase in the need for guidance across the sector, the |
12 | business communities, counsel, et cetera, on what the |
13 | law is meant to do. |
14 | It's also provided a lot of learning to people |
15 | on potential strategic uses of competition law, and to |
16 | the extent that guidelines or safe harbors can be |
17 | developed, I think it would serve a dual purpose of |
18 | informing people who want to engage in legitimate |
19 | behavior and also perhaps foreclose strategic litigation |
20 | in this area. |
21 | In Canada, as Sheridan mentioned, we do not have |
22 | private actions in this area of the law. I think part |
23 | of the resistance behind that is the concern about the |
24 | chill and strategic use of that type of litigation. |
25 | Indeed, when the Act was amended a few years ago to |
1 | allow very limited private access to the Tribunal, |
2 | procedural screens were developed and limitations on |
3 | remedies were introduced to minimize the strategic |
4 | litigation type of risk. |
5 | My third comment is that the risk of chill is |
6 | real, and the economic costs associated with |
7 | inappropriate or inadvertent chilling of legitimate and |
8 | competitive conduct is in my view significant, but I |
9 | readily admit it's very, very difficult to measure. I |
10 | will give you just one little illustration, and to |
11 | protect the innocent it won't be in the antitrust area. |
12 | It has to do with in the telecom field, |
13 | actually, when I was a senior executive with a teleco in |
14 | Canada, we were at a meeting and we had to decide what |
15 | to do. We had about a hundred million dollars to |
16 | invest, and the discussion came up about where are we |
17 | going to invest that money. It wasn't a long |
18 | discussion, and the decision was ultimately made -- |
19 | Margaret, you will appreciate this -- to invest in the |
20 | UK. And why? The decision wasn't that the rate of |
21 | return from the investment would be better. The main |
22 | driver behind the decision was the perception -- and I |
23 | think a valid one -- that at that time, at least, the UK |
24 | teleco regulators were a lot more business and market |
25 | friendly than the Canadian ones. |
1 | I use that illustration to underscore how |
2 | important the perception of the enforcement of this area |
3 | of the law is to business and decision-makers. I think |
4 | it was Doug Melamed who mentioned, and I echo his views, |
5 | that the signals you send to the business community are |
6 | much more important, frankly, than whether the case is |
7 | right or wrong. I want to underscore the importance of |
8 | that chilling. |
9 | The chill not only affects the parties who may |
10 | be subject to that particular enforcement action or |
11 | their affiliates or competitors in the same field, but |
12 | it also extends to those observers of the trade, people |
13 | in other markets, people in other industries, counsel, |
14 | advisers, who see the outcome of these proceedings and |
15 | are then chilled in their behavior, you know, "I don't |
16 | want to get drawn into that lengthy kind of litigation |
17 | by even coming close to what may or may not be |
18 | permissible." So, that's another type of chill that we |
19 | have to watch out for. |
20 | I just want to be sensitive to time here. I |
21 | guess we have heard from many witnesses today as well |
22 | that the goal of antitrust is to protect competition and |
23 | not competitors. That theme is well enshrined in the |
24 | guidelines that Sheridan was mentioning earlier today, |
25 | and to make it patently clear, "the objective of the |
1 | abuse provisions is to promote efficient competition, |
2 | effective competition, and not the interests of any one |
3 | competitor or group of competitors. The provisions are |
4 | not intended to be used to attempt to tilt the playing |
5 | field in favor of market participants, who, for example, |
6 | lack the ability to compete with a more efficient or |
7 | better managed rival." |
8 | The take-away from that in this portion of my |
9 | remarks is that only in the clearest cases should |
10 | enforcement agencies intervene. To the extent that |
11 | there's any doubt as to the competitive legitimacy of |
12 | some behavior, I think more often than not the doubt |
13 | should be resolved in favor of the potential defendant |
14 | or target. |
15 | So, in response to Assistant Attorney General |
16 | Barnett's question, whether agencies should be more or |
17 | less aggressive in this area, I would urge caution, and |
18 | I will answer that as a yes, they should tend towards |
19 | being less aggressive. |
20 | This notion of risk was also addressed in one |
21 | case by the Competition Tribunal, language that sort of |
22 | tracks Trinko, where they said, "It would not be in the |
23 | public interest to prevent or hamper even dominant firms |
24 | in an effort to compete on the merits. Competition, |
25 | even tough competition, is not to be enjoined by the |
1 | Tribunal but rather only anticompetitive competition. |
2 | Decisions by the Tribunal restricting competitive action |
3 | on the grounds that the action is of overwhelming |
4 | intensity would send a chilling message about |
5 | competition, that is, in our view, not consistent with |
6 | the purposes of the Act." |
7 | The statistics on enforcement history in Canada |
8 | I think reflects this concern about dominance. The |
9 | earlier cases -- and if people want to hear about them, |
10 | we can deal with them later -- were clearly ones in my |
11 | mind that were at the obvious end of the scale. They |
12 | weren't even -- they may have been charcoal but |
13 | definitely not gray, and we have had five contested |
14 | cases in the 20 years since the legislation was adopted. |
15 | Orders were issued in four. The fifth is under -- is |
16 | the one, the Canada Pipe case, and it's likely -- how |
17 | can I put this -- it's likely that an appeal to the |
18 | Supreme Court of Canada will be sought in that case. |
19 | The last comment I will share with you is, as |
20 | Sheridan Scott took you through the tests, is there |
21 | dominance, is there an anticompetitive purpose, has it |
22 | reached the effects threshold, that this concern about |
23 | the chill is reflected in that section, because at the |
24 | very end, even if you've met all of these three tests, |
25 | the Tribunal is still left with the discretion not to |
1 | issue an order. It's not a "shall." It's "the Tribunal |
2 | may." So, I think that's reflective of concern by |
3 | Parliament of this chill, and with that, I will turn the |
4 | mike over to Margaret. |
5 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, George. |
6 | (Applause.) |
7 | MR. MASOUDI: Our next speaker will be Margaret |
8 | Bloom. Margaret is a visiting professor in the School |
9 | of Law at King's College of London and is Senior |
10 | Consultant at Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer. Between |
11 | 1998 and 2003, Ms. Bloom was Director of Competition |
12 | Enforcement at the United Kingdom's Office of Fair |
13 | Trading, where she headed the Competition Enforcement |
14 | Division. Before joining OFT, Ms. Bloom worked in the |
15 | United Kingdom's Cabinet Office and Department of Trade |
16 | and Industry on Privatization, Competition Policy, and |
17 | Public Sector Finance. She was Vice-Chair of the OECD |
18 | Competition Committee for six years, and she is a |
19 | Commander of the Order of the British Empire based on |
20 | her work at the Office of Fair Trading. Very |
21 | impressive, Margaret. |
22 | MS. BLOOM: Thank you, Jerry. I'm pleased to be |
23 | here today to present some experience from overseas. |
24 | There are three areas I am going to talk about. |
25 | Firstly, look at the question of whether all |
1 | jurisdictions should have the same approach to |
2 | single-firm conduct, then look at some action to |
3 | increase convergence worldwide in the treatment of |
4 | single-firm conduct, and then spend a bit more time in |
5 | drawing some lessons which come from all the discussion |
6 | there's been in Europe on the review of Article 82. |
7 | So, turning to the first question, should all |
8 | jurisdictions who are addressing single-firm conduct |
9 | take the same approach? Let's make the assumption -- |
10 | and it's just an assumption -- that every jurisdiction |
11 | applying single-firm conduct is seeking to maximize |
12 | consumer welfare. I know that's not necessarily the |
13 | position, but assume it is. In that circumstance, |
14 | should they all approach single-firm conduct in exactly |
15 | the same way, or should there be some differences in |
16 | order to maximize consumer welfare worldwide? I think |
17 | there are some small differences, though I think they're |
18 | not nearly enough to explain the different approaches |
19 | between jurisdictions. |
20 | My first set of differences is, if you compare |
21 | the United States with Europe and you look at the market |
22 | structures, in Europe, there are a fair number of |
23 | powerful companies that were formerly state-owned |
24 | monopolies. They did not become powerful; they didn't |
25 | become dominant because they were so successful through |
1 | rivalry in the marketplace. They were awarded a state |
2 | monopoly. |
3 | Secondly, if you look at Europe, many of the |
4 | markets are just national markets, so they are quite |
5 | small. Certainly in some of the Member States, you may |
6 | have very few significant players in these smaller |
7 | markets. If you have that sort of market structure |
8 | compared with the U.S., where the big firms have more |
9 | won their position by being successful in the |
10 | marketplace and there's much more rivalry within a |
11 | market, should enforcers take a closer look at |
12 | single-firm conduct in Europe? Probably yes. Should |
13 | they intervene a bit more readily? Possibly. I think |
14 | there could be some grounds for it. |
15 | Let's look at a second point. A number of |
16 | commentators have said that in the U.S., because of the |
17 | attraction of treble damages suits, the courts have |
18 | sought to narrow the application of Section 2. We |
19 | haven't had the same pressure in Europe. There are very |
20 | few private actions before the courts. If there are |
21 | more private actions in the future, might that lead the |
22 | national courts to seek to narrow the application of |
23 | Article 82? Possibly, but we're never going to have |
24 | anything like the extent of private actions, I guess, |
25 | that you have here. |
1 | As I say, I think these are relatively small |
2 | reasons for the differences. The main reason for the |
3 | differences between jurisdictions probably lies with the |
4 | different judgment over what's the right balance between |
5 | false negatives and false positives. Personally, I |
6 | think the U.S. is right to be duly nervous about false |
7 | positives. I think in Europe, we're a bit too ready to |
8 | intervene too often. |
9 | Okay, let's look at the next area. What action |
10 | might be taken to increase convergence worldwide? |
11 | Clearly there's already a lot of work being done through |
12 | the ICN, the OECD, the U.S. agencies and others. I just |
13 | want to touch on three areas which from my personal |
14 | experience are particularly valuable in terms of |
15 | increasing convergence. |
16 | The first one is training and sharing |
17 | experience. I think the direct training and sharing |
18 | between enforcers so that they can work with other |
19 | enforcers in other jurisdictions is extremely valuable. |
20 | It's a very good way of helping to understand why other |
21 | countries and other jurisdictions are doing things |
22 | differently and maybe make you think, well, perhaps I |
23 | should learn from that one, and two examples of this are |
24 | in the area of cartels and in mergers. |
25 | Firstly, in cartels, the International Cartel |
1 | Enforcers workshops that were initiated by the |
2 | Department of Justice, then a year later, the Office of |
3 | Fair Trading in the UK hosted the workshop, and the |
4 | following year, the Canadian Bureau in Canada. They |
5 | were all involved enforcers exchanging experience |
6 | actively among each other. On the merger side, my |
7 | example is from the ICN Investigative Techniques for |
8 | Mergers workshop. |
9 | The second area is guidelines. The ICN Merger |
10 | Guidelines Workbook that was launched this year at the |
11 | annual conference in Capetown, is an extremely good |
12 | document. It was put together through extensive work by |
13 | experienced agencies and the private sector. It's been |
14 | very well received, not only by developing countries, |
15 | but also by experienced individuals in developed |
16 | countries, and I know of at least one law firm in which |
17 | the associates find it very useful in knowing how to |
18 | address competitive effects in mergers. |
19 | So, thinking about that workbook, I was |
20 | reflecting on the fact, how do other countries learn |
21 | about the good U.S. practice in relation to single-firm |
22 | conduct? I know you have plenty of case law with |
23 | judgments and opinions, and you've got lots and lots of |
24 | books and articles, but there's no user friendly |
25 | guideline. It is actually remarkably difficult for |
1 | people overseas, unless they are going to spend a long |
2 | time reading a lot of material, to get a proper feel of |
3 | how one should go about conducting a single-firm conduct |
4 | analysis, what kind of cases you should take and you |
5 | shouldn't take. |
6 | You should not overestimate the knowledge |
7 | overseas of what is taking place in the United States, |
8 | and I know that the American Bar Association is strongly |
9 | encouraging the European Commission to issue guidelines |
10 | on Article 82 when the current discussion is complete. |
11 | The last area is staff exchanges, and in that |
12 | I'm talking about exchanges of staff between agencies. |
13 | That's quite common in Europe. It may either be between |
14 | the national agencies and staff may move for a |
15 | relatively small period of time, or it may be between |
16 | the national agencies and the European Commission. It's |
17 | another very good mechanism in increasing knowledge and |
18 | understanding. If it was possible for the American |
19 | agencies to take part in that I think it would be very |
20 | valuable. I recognize it's quite a challenge, but it |
21 | would be very valuable if it's possible. |
22 | Let me then turn to the lessons. These lessons |
23 | are from the Article 82 review. They are not |
24 | necessarily all going to be adopted in the review, but |
25 | they are lessons which I've personally drawn in terms of |
1 | thinking about what would be some sound rules for good |
2 | single-firm conduct enforcement. There are eight of |
3 | these. |
4 | The first one is you need clear objectives on |
5 | what you're seeking to do. The Article 82 discussion |
6 | paper says that the objective is to enhance consumer |
7 | welfare and efficiency. Theses are clearly good |
8 | objectives. Though I must admit that throughout the |
9 | discussion paper, it isn't entirely obvious in places |
10 | that those objectives are the ones that would be |
11 | achieved by some of the proposals in the paper. |
12 | More of a problem, and Philip Lowe mentioned |
13 | this this morning, is the fact that much of the European |
14 | case law is influenced by other objectives, in |
15 | particular, protecting the structure of competition and |
16 | protecting the rights and opportunities of market |
17 | operators, not obviously a perfect match for enhancing |
18 | consumer welfare. |
19 | Lesson number two, before any intervention, |
20 | there should be a plausible theory of consumer harm. |
21 | This may be actual harm, possibly it will be likely |
22 | harm, because that's easier to demonstrate than actual |
23 | harm, but you must have a plausible theory before you |
24 | should be able to intervene or before a plaintiff will |
25 | succeed in a court. |
1 | The third lesson, avoid overly complicated |
2 | rules. Even if the economics indicate that a perfect |
3 | rule, for example, for discount would be some rather |
4 | complicated measure, that's not going to work |
5 | effectively for business, and also it will probably be |
6 | difficult for a agency. |
7 | Fourth, efficiency benefits should be assessed, |
8 | but they should be a part of the analysis of conduct. |
9 | They shouldn't be just a limited defense. |
10 | Number five, use safe harbors rather than |
11 | presumptions of dominance or presumptions of monopoly |
12 | power or presumptions of abuse. The reason why I would |
13 | suggest safe harbors rather than presumptions is that as |
14 | long as the safe harbors are large enough, they are |
15 | going to give business certainty. On the whole, it's |
16 | likely to be more economically rational to have a safe |
17 | harbor than a presumption. Also, if there is a |
18 | presumption, you should not reverse the burden of proof |
19 | and then put it on the company or on the defendant. |
20 | Let me just give you two examples of safe |
21 | harbors in the question of substantial market power, |
22 | dominance or monopoly power. Assuming you can define |
23 | the market in single-firm conduct, and that's a pretty |
24 | tough assumption, but say you have got a reasonable idea |
25 | of the market. If the firm has a low market share, it |
1 | cannot have substantial market power because you've got |
2 | plenty of existing competitors. But if a firm has a |
3 | high market share, it is not a safe presumption that it |
4 | has substantial market power. There may be low barriers |
5 | to entry so that they've got potential competitors. |
6 | There might be buyer power. |
7 | If you turn to abuses in single-product loyalty |
8 | discounts and predation, a useful safe harbor would be |
9 | price above average avoidable cost, or if you prefer, |
10 | average variable cost, but I think average avoidable |
11 | cost is probably a better measure and better for |
12 | business to assess. |
13 | The sixth question, it should not be too easy to |
14 | find a firm is dominant or it has monopoly power. |
15 | Again, my preference would be to follow the U.S. |
16 | approach rather than the EC approach, where it is too |
17 | easy to find a firm is dominant and this puts too many |
18 | companies at risk of being found to have abused a |
19 | dominant position, because you don't need much market |
20 | power before you're found to be possibly dominant. |
21 | The last two lessons. First of all, number |
22 | seven, avoid what I've called "abuse shopping." |
23 | Different abuses will have the same economic effect, but |
24 | in Europe, these different abuses may well have |
25 | different tests or different cost benchmarks, although |
1 | the economic effect is the same, and sometimes, it's |
2 | easier to prove one form of abuse than another. That |
3 | shouldn't be the position. It should not enable the |
4 | agency to abuse shop, to use the easiest form of abuse |
5 | to prove. |
6 | If you look at predation and single-product |
7 | loyalty discount, same economic effect, but one is much |
8 | easier to prove than the other in Europe. Or if you |
9 | look at a margin or price squeeze (the difference |
10 | between the price upstream and the price downstream at |
11 | the retail level), you can either address the margin or |
12 | you could look at predation downstream in the retail |
13 | market or refusal to deal upstream. They would have |
14 | different tests, and some of them are easier to prove |
15 | than the others. |
16 | Then the last and the eighth lesson, we may need |
17 | more than one test of harm to cover different types of |
18 | exclusionary conduct. That seems to me not a problem |
19 | provided that it is absolutely clear which test of harm |
20 | is going to be used for which exclusionary conduct. If |
21 | we're only going to have one test of harm, on balance, I |
22 | would prefer the no economic sense test to the equally |
23 | efficient competitor, because I think the former is |
24 | probably easier or less difficult for business to |
25 | understand and to apply. Also, I think it's less likely |
1 | that agencies will intervene as readily in the no |
2 | economic sense test as with the equally efficient |
3 | competitor test. |
4 | Thank you. |
5 | (Applause.) |
6 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, Margaret. |
7 | Our next presenter will be Paul Lugard. Paul is |
8 | the Global Head of Antitrust of Royal Philips |
9 | Electronics NV. He is a member of the editorial board |
10 | of two Dutch magazines on competition law and regularly |
11 | publishes himself, recently on intellectual property |
12 | licensing and patent pools, nonhorizontal mergers, the |
13 | Article 81(3) notice, and exclusive dealing under |
14 | Article 82. |
15 | He represents Royal Philips Electronics in the |
16 | European Round Table and is a Co-Chair of the Commission |
17 | for Competition of the Dutch Employers' Association |
18 | VNO-NCW. He is a Vice-Chair of the ICC Competition |
19 | Commission and chairs the ICC Task Force on Vertical and |
20 | Conglomerate Mergers of the ICC Competition Commission. |
21 | Thank you, Paul. |
22 | MR. LUGARD: Thank you. |
23 | Good afternoon. My perspective is that of an |
24 | in-house antitrust practitioner working for a technology |
25 | company with activities in the U.S., Europe and Asia. I |
1 | appreciate that I'm the only person from a company, and |
2 | I will try not to be intimidated this afternoon. |
3 | The nature of Philips' international activities |
4 | in part explains my concern about diverging standards |
5 | between jurisdictions, not only between the EU on the |
6 | one hand and the U.S. on the other hand, but to an |
7 | increasing extent also with Asia. I believe that the |
8 | divergence in the area of unilateral conduct is larger |
9 | than in any other area of antitrust or merger control |
10 | law. At the same time, the need for convergence in this |
11 | specific area is most pressing, because different and |
12 | inaccurate standards for exclusionary conduct involving |
13 | firms with significant market power, are most likely to |
14 | defeat procompetitive conduct, that ultimately benefits |
15 | consumers. |
16 | The problem is that convergence in this area is |
17 | most difficult to achieve not only because of the |
18 | problems inherent in convergence and convergence |
19 | initiatives, but also because in key jurisdictions, |
20 | there is no clear analytical framework to assess |
21 | unilateral conduct. |
22 | In other words, if the U.S. agencies and DG COMP |
23 | would be able to come up with a more refined analytical |
24 | framework, then I believe that convergence will be much |
25 | easier to achieve. I'm very much in favor of the |
1 | initiatives that are taking place within the framework |
2 | of the ICN and also the ECD, and I can only say that |
3 | there's not enough of those initiatives, but as I said, |
4 | I believe that a clearer analytical framework both on |
5 | this continent and for Europe would spur convergence |
6 | initiatives even more. |
7 | The experience I have with the transactions that |
8 | my company is involved in makes one thing clear to me. |
9 | We need a proper analytical framework that takes account |
10 | of both static and dynamic effects, and if the agencies |
11 | would be able to tell us how, in particular, dynamic |
12 | efficiencies could be factored into the analysis of |
13 | unilateral conduct, that would be an immense step |
14 | forward. So, in my view, there is an urgent need for |
15 | the two key jurisdictions, the EC and U.S., to align |
16 | their approach towards unilateral firm behavior. But I |
17 | believe that there is an even clearer and more urgent |
18 | need to first develop a coherent and clear framework |
19 | analysis in both of the home jurisdictions. |
20 | I would hope that since both agencies, the two |
21 | U.S. agencies and the European Commission, are at the |
22 | same point in time reflecting on the proper approach |
23 | towards dominant firm behavior, the U.S. agencies would |
24 | be inclined to even more participate in the debates with |
25 | Europe on the proper scope of Article 82 and vice versa. |
1 | So, if there is a need for a clearer analytical |
2 | framework, then the question arises, why doesn't that |
3 | framework exist already? I am talking about the U.S. |
4 | Coming from Europe, I am, of course, a little bit on |
5 | thin ice here, but there may be two reasons. |
6 | The one reason might be that in the U.S., |
7 | Section 2 offenses are litigated in courts, which in |
8 | most cases means that one party either loses or wins |
9 | depending on whether the other party meets its burden of |
10 | proof. I believe that the court in Microsoft mentioned |
11 | that, in the end courts may be called upon to balance or |
12 | to determine the net effect of dominant firm behavior. |
13 | However, the reality is also that balancing or trying to |
14 | assess and quantify that negative effect in practice |
15 | hardly ever takes place. |
16 | The second reason might be that in many courts, |
17 | as well as outside courts, if we talk about exclusionary |
18 | behavior, there is too much, "I know it when I see it," |
19 | and that doesn't help to come up with a proper general |
20 | framework or methodology. |
21 | To me, the proper benchmark is long-term |
22 | consumer surplus. If one of the standards that is |
23 | currently proposed would be able to distinguish good |
24 | from bad behavior and would be able to distinguish |
25 | whether consumer surplus goes up or down, then that |
1 | would be wonderful. I don't think that the business |
2 | community would mind whether there is more than one test |
3 | to discriminate between those types of behavior, but if |
4 | it's true that all these tests are either over-inclusive |
5 | or under-inclusive, then I ask myself whether it |
6 | wouldn't be more logical to look at what's happening in |
7 | the market, certainly in ex post evaluations, and then |
8 | try to assess whether consumers are benefited or not |
9 | from the behavior at issue. |
10 | I was very impressed by Professor Salop's recent |
11 | reflections on the consumer welfare effects standard in |
12 | the Antitrust Law Journal, I believe it was the July |
13 | issue of this year, although I believe that much can be |
14 | said about his suggestion to apply that standard on an |
15 | ex ante basis only and the application of that test to |
16 | "more efficient" firms. |
17 | Now, if we were to assume that the consumer |
18 | surplus test in some form is the right thing, then a |
19 | number of issues are required. First, we need to know |
20 | whether the agency or plaintiff should not only prove |
21 | some kind of output reduction or other loss of |
22 | efficiency as a result of the exclusionary conduct, but |
23 | in addition, also to quantify that loss, and I know that |
24 | in the U.S., quantification is probably not a strict |
25 | standard, but oddly enough, the EU approach is |
1 | different. You may recall, that there were some remarks |
2 | on the Article 83 Notice this morning, and I would also |
3 | take the position that the Article 82 discussion paper |
4 | itself is based on the assumption that consumer surplus |
5 | and negative effects on consumers could, to some extent, |
6 | be quantified and could be used as a tool to distinguish |
7 | good from bad behavior. |
8 | Secondly, we would need to know how agencies and |
9 | courts balance foreclosure effects against dynamic |
10 | efficiency effects. How do we arrive at the effective |
11 | identification of the net effect? Obviously this is |
12 | particularly important in sectors that undergo rapid |
13 | technological changes, because it is in those sectors |
14 | where dynamic efficiencies may be most important. |
15 | Thirdly, to ensure that courts arrive at the |
16 | right outcome, and perhaps as an additional safeguard |
17 | against false positives, there should be a requirement |
18 | that there is a clear articulation of the theory of |
19 | harm. Many of the post-Chicago economic theories that |
20 | seek to explain anticompetitive effects arising from |
21 | exclusionary conduct require the presence of some sort |
22 | of externality, and interestingly enough, in July of |
23 | 2005, a report was issued by the EAGCP, a think tank, if |
24 | you wish, reporting to the European Commission that |
25 | recommended that in each case where the Commission |
1 | identifies exclusionary conduct, it should be forced to |
2 | identify the externality at work, so that there would be |
3 | an additional requirement to identify the theory of harm |
4 | causing the negative effects on competition. |
5 | I was interested to hear Philip Lowe's remark |
6 | this morning about the likely effects which would |
7 | require some sort of articulation of the theory of harm, |
8 | but that that might not necessarily be required if the |
9 | evaluation of is of an ex post nature. In that case, |
10 | there would be actual effects in the markets, and it |
11 | should be much easier to be capable of finding a |
12 | violation. My sense is that still in an ex post |
13 | evaluation, it would be needed to come up with a |
14 | plausible theory of harm. |
15 | There are other subjects that should be |
16 | reflected upon in the context of Section 2. In the |
17 | U.S., there is the Doctrine of Patent Misuse. There is |
18 | no such an equivalent in Europe. Especially for |
19 | European companies doing business in the U.S., it would |
20 | be helpful if there would be some sort of alignment to |
21 | the Section 2 policy and the policy of patent misuse. |
22 | Secondly, it would be helpful if more clarity |
23 | would be given with respect to the difficult subject of |
24 | incompatible design changes, technological tying cases, |
25 | and an explanation how those cases should be analyzed in |
1 | the framework of a consumer surplus or other standards. |
2 | And finally, what should be done about the soon |
3 | to be effective Chinese antimonopoly law? China |
4 | proposes legislation that contains a number of vague and |
5 | elusive definitions regarding both dominance and abuse, |
6 | in particular in the field of intellectual property, and |
7 | I would hope that the Chinese authorities would obtain |
8 | input both from DOJ and FTC, as well as DG COMP for a |
9 | rational implementation of those concepts. |
10 | Thank you very much. |
11 | (Applause.) |
12 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, Paul. |
13 | Our final panelist is Jim Rill. Jim is a |
14 | partner at Howrey LLP here in Washington, D.C. He's |
15 | served as the Assistant Attorney General in charge of |
16 | the Antitrust Division at the Department of Justice from |
17 | 1989 to 1992 and was chair of the ABA's Antitrust |
18 | Section from '87 to '88. While he was Assistant |
19 | Attorney General, Jim negotiated the U.S.-European Union |
20 | Antitrust Cooperation Agreement of 1991. In 1997, |
21 | Attorney General Janet Reno and Assistant Attorney |
22 | General Joel Klein appointed Mr. Rill to serve as |
23 | Co-Chair of the United States Department of Justice's |
24 | International Competition Policy Advisory Committee. |
25 | Jim, thank you for joining us. |
1 | MR. RILL: Thank you, and let me echo the |
2 | comments of the prior panelists, that I'm honored and |
3 | grateful to be a participant in this round table, both |
4 | with the eminent enforcers that appeared this morning |
5 | and my distinguished colleagues this afternoon. |
6 | I can't resist some preliminary comments to the |
7 | thoughts and suggestions I would make and perhaps set a |
8 | pattern for the issues that we're confronting. One, |
9 | with the increasing proliferation of antitrust |
10 | authorities across the world and the dynamics of the |
11 | modern economy imbued with a high level of intellectual |
12 | property and cross-border technology, the actions of an |
13 | agency in one jurisdiction cannot help but have |
14 | ramifications beyond that jurisdiction and throughout |
15 | the rest of the world. |
16 | I remember in a Conflicts of Law textbook I had |
17 | a picture on the front page was, "Can the laws of the |
18 | island of Tobago protect and preserve the laws of the |
19 | entire British Empire?" I think we're faced with a |
20 | greater challenge than that today, although I don't |
21 | pretend to be an expert on the laws of Tobago. |
22 | Secondly, the different approaches of the |
23 | different antitrust agencies across the world provide a |
24 | daunting task to the ability of multinational firms, |
25 | firms practicing and doing business, operating in more |
1 | than one jurisdiction, to plan business strategies with |
2 | any confidence that they will avoid antitrust challenge. |
3 | As a result, there's a definite threat of a chill, the |
4 | least common denominator approach in business counseling |
5 | that can discourage procompetitive business activity and |
6 | adversely affect consumer welfare. |
7 | Thus, the very complexity in the analysis of |
8 | single-firm conduct calls on us to take significant |
9 | caution and challenges the steady approach towards |
10 | convergence and certainly that we have seen in such |
11 | areas, for example, as horizontal mergers, especially |
12 | since I'd suggest that in the area of single-firm |
13 | conduct, particularly where one is dealing with a highly |
14 | innovative, procompetitive, dominant firm, there's a |
15 | real tendency, an appetite, for competitors who are hurt |
16 | by efficiency and procompetitive conduct to engage in |
17 | forum shopping, or as Hew Pate put it in a recent speech |
18 | when he was in office, to take an opportunity for every |
19 | agency across the world to have at least one whack at |
20 | the pinata to see if the competitor can't find an agency |
21 | somewhere, somehow, that's going to go after the pro -- |
22 | what is, I would submit, arguably, is the procompetitive |
23 | conduct. |
24 | So, the thought I'd like to address today is the |
25 | crying need, if you will, for transparency, at a minimum |
1 | certainty, and at least some mechanisms for the ability |
2 | of agencies to achieve, in time, convergence in |
3 | single-firm or dominant firm, if you will, conduct |
4 | across borders, and I would suggest that in those areas, |
5 | mechanisms should be employed to establish safe harbors, |
6 | which was discussed this morning, and in more complex |
7 | areas where safe harbors seem not to be appropriate. |
8 | Where more intense analysis is required, the agencies |
9 | should focus on principles towards certainty and |
10 | transparency, and there are institutional mechanisms |
11 | which already exist that can be implemented and followed |
12 | in greater depth to promote these ends. |
13 | There has not been nearly the progress towards |
14 | certainty, transparency, much less convergence, in the |
15 | area of single-firm conduct as in, for example, in the |
16 | case of horizontal mergers. Thus, our job as |
17 | counselors, to have some confidence that we're giving |
18 | advice that can be used across the world concerning |
19 | antitrust risk, is very challenging, particularly in the |
20 | areas of pricing, intellectual property licensing, |
21 | marketing programs and so forth. |
22 | Even where at least most agencies would agree |
23 | that consumer welfare is an abiding and generally |
24 | applicable principle, the term itself has ambiguous |
25 | meanings. Does consumer welfare mean simply enhanced |
1 | rivalry? Are we talking about consumer welfare in terms |
2 | only of above marginal cost -- marginal cost pricing, or |
3 | are we talking about consumer welfare in the sense of |
4 | total welfare, or are we simply giving lip service to |
5 | the term "consumer welfare" as we go on about |
6 | protectionist policies? |
7 | The application of this concept, even where it's |
8 | agreed upon, and it's not universally agreed upon, to |
9 | dominance, to market definition, is ambiguous in many |
10 | jurisdictions, and when it's applied to conduct, the |
11 | challenge is exacerbated. When one looks at refusals to |
12 | deal -- look at the laundry list we saw this morning in |
13 | one agency, that single-firm conduct can be challenged |
14 | where it's a tied sale, exclusive dealing, refusals to |
15 | deal, predation, discounts, cross-subsidization or |
16 | raising rivals' costs. |
17 | Now, apply that, if you will, to a situation |
18 | where you are trying to advise or you are a company |
19 | trying to maximize your own legitimate business |
20 | strategies and run that laundry list and see what those |
21 | meanings have, and also, when we see in the concepts |
22 | underlying many of the statutory provisions relating to |
23 | single-firm conduct terms such as "unfair." I remember |
24 | George Will in a speech recently said, "In my family, we |
25 | eliminate the four-letter word starting with F, fair." |
1 | Unfair, unjust, preference, undue advantage. When you |
2 | try and apply those in a concrete sense, frustration |
3 | abounds. |
4 | Let me suggest this: There is a need for at |
5 | least safe harbors for several purposes. One, they |
6 | certainly contribute to certainty and minimize |
7 | unwarranted frustration and procompetitive conduct. |
8 | Two, they can spare enormous expense, if you will, to |
9 | business in attempting to identify all levels of conduct |
10 | or baseline minimal levels of conduct that take place |
11 | across borders or can have ramifications across borders. |
12 | And three, they can actually help the agencies focus |
13 | their own resources in areas where those resources need |
14 | to be arrayed in order to prevent or at least |
15 | investigate practices that carry the real threat of |
16 | anticompetitive effect. |
17 | First, let's look at structural safe harbors, |
18 | and a two-step approach is called for here, market |
19 | definition and market share, and as I say that, and I'm |
20 | very well aware that market definition is only a proxy |
21 | for market power and an inexact proxy and one that some |
22 | practitioners, myself not included, think should be done |
23 | away with. Static market share becomes even more |
24 | unreliable in today's economy where industries are |
25 | traditionally characterized by overnight transformation |
1 | of market position and market innovation. So, |
2 | nonetheless, market share and market definition remain |
3 | an informative indicator to the potential for a firm to |
4 | exercise unilateral market power, and I say, somewhat |
5 | from a practical standpoint, market definition and |
6 | market share is produced by the agencies as a starting |
7 | point for their analysis, so I shouldn't really ignore |
8 | what they're doing. |
9 | But having said that, of course, there are a |
10 | variety of approaches, and I don't need to get into them |
11 | today, a variety of analytical approaches, an array of |
12 | different terminology used to define markets, and in |
13 | addition to the analytical divergence, there's a |
14 | practical divergence in the evidentiary basis that is |
15 | used for the definition of the markets, and they vary |
16 | from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. |
17 | One, high market share -- I mean, let's be very |
18 | clear in this proposal, that a high market share should |
19 | not be an indicator -- certainly not an exclusive |
20 | indicator or a reliable or terribly important indicator |
21 | of the existence of market power. It can, however, |
22 | serve as a minimal tool, a realistic minimum, that would |
23 | provide a safe harbor and certainty for all the reasons |
24 | that have been mentioned certainly. The benefit of it |
25 | is many competition agencies, at least some competition |
1 | agencies, already employ a structural safe harbor. |
2 | The selection of an appropriate level is needed |
3 | to be -- evokes a continuing dialogue. If the threshold |
4 | is too low, there are two dangers. One, it's too low, |
5 | so it provides no realistic certainty. Two, the bottom |
6 | line can become the -- the top line can become the |
7 | bottom line, so anything then above the safe harbor as a |
8 | practical matter could be employed by the agency to |
9 | stimulate unnecessary investigation and possible |
10 | challenge. In short, the threshold as low as 20 percent |
11 | or 10 percent, as we've heard, really isn't going to |
12 | provide much guidance, much comfort, much help to the |
13 | enforcement agency or, for that matter, the businesses. |
14 | Structural safe harbors are not enough. |
15 | I was very encouraged today in reading the |
16 | discussion draft on Article 82 of the effects analysis |
17 | approach in the EU. The question simply at the conduct |
18 | level of the safe harbor is what's the exclusion, who is |
19 | excluded, and what is the anticompetitive effect. Some |
20 | conduct should be characterized categorically as a safe |
21 | harbor type of conduct. We made approaches to this in |
22 | the U.S. and elsewhere in the area of predatory pricing, |
23 | and work in this area is being done by Greg Werden, and |
24 | comments were made by Philip Lowe in the area as well of |
25 | the development of conduct safe harbors, and it |
1 | suggested candidates for safe harbors would consist of |
2 | patently procompetitive conduct that include new product |
3 | introduction, improved product quality, cost reducing |
4 | innovation, energetic market penetration, successful |
5 | research and development, and the potential for the |
6 | development Paul Lugard was talking today about an |
7 | appropriate measure. |
8 | How do we get there? First, as Margaret |
9 | mentioned earlier, there's much room for improved |
10 | case-by-case cooperation. That cooperation, at least |
11 | between the U.S. and the EU, is underway and has been |
12 | very effective in the merger area with working groups |
13 | and actual cooperation on particular cases. Business |
14 | can facilitate this cooperation by properly designed or |
15 | properly limited waivers in confidentiality. The OECD |
16 | round tables and the OECD work has been highly useful in |
17 | this area. |
18 | There have been programs on single-firm conduct. |
19 | The OECD seminal work with the business community on |
20 | merger procedure is a good litmus to be followed in this |
21 | area. The 30 OECD countries submit their papers on the |
22 | types of conduct that will be considered both illegal |
23 | that are case based and also conduct that might fall |
24 | within safe harbors. One benefit here would be if those |
25 | jurisdictions would be more forthcoming and in depth as |
1 | to why a particular course of conduct would be |
2 | considered unlawful single-firm conduct, again, back to |
3 | the concept of who was excluded and why. |
4 | Some of the cases that I saw this morning, I |
5 | wanted to reach out and say, okay, so you're prescribing |
6 | a particular bid formula or prescribing particular |
7 | specifications, and? That was unlawful because? And I |
8 | think having more forthcoming descriptions of where that |
9 | exclusion occurred and why would be very helpful in the |
10 | context of the OECD. |
11 | I want to commend the International Competition |
12 | Network's launch of a working group on single-firm |
13 | conduct. I think the group has made progress already on |
14 | developing a sound work plan which promises to be highly |
15 | beneficial in spearheading more transparency and |
16 | ultimately convergence in this area. I think in that |
17 | area, the stock taking would be very useful, taking it |
18 | in depth and analyzing with some degree of thoroughness. |
19 | Guidelines have been mentioned. I must say I |
20 | haven't read the Canadian Guidelines, but I will have to |
21 | run home and do that, but I worry in principle -- not |
22 | referring to the Canadian Guidelines -- some people |
23 | might stop me, but I think that one thing that could be |
24 | said is that guidelines can unduly sometimes stultify |
25 | and set in concrete the wrong decision. I would not |
1 | want to live today with the Turner Guidelines For |
2 | Horizontal Mergers. |
3 | So, to come back to the basic principles, I |
4 | think that guidelines for transparency or convergence |
5 | can follow three basic principles. They need to be |
6 | workable and understandable; they need to be |
7 | sufficiently flexible to be adapted to changing, |
8 | improving, we like to think, economic thinking; and they |
9 | need to be based ab initio on the best sound legal and |
10 | economic thinking available today. |
11 | So, those are the steps I would recommend for |
12 | transparency, and thank you very much for allowing me to |
13 | be here. |
14 | (Applause.) |
15 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you very much to all of our |
16 | panelists for very interesting comments. I think what |
17 | we will do now is take a break for about 15 minutes, and |
18 | then we will reconvene when we'll have some discussion |
19 | by the panelists about each other's presentations as |
20 | well as some questions. So, let's reconvene at about I |
21 | guess ten minutes to 3:00. |
22 | (A brief recess was taken.) |
23 | MR. MASOUDI: Okay, I think we'll get started |
24 | again. We tried to offer some light into the room, but |
25 | apparently the shutters are set to turn down |
1 | automatically. |
2 | I think we'll get started now, and I think what |
3 | we will do is similar to what we did this morning. We'd |
4 | like to give each of the panelists an opportunity to |
5 | comment for a few minutes on what the others have said, |
6 | and we will start with you, George. |
7 | MR. ADDY: Thank you. |
8 | As much as I consider jurisprudence a public |
9 | good, and some would say we can never have enough of |
10 | that, I'm not advocating increased enforcement in this |
11 | area but I think greater clarity as to what the rules of |
12 | the game are would be useful, both to agencies and |
13 | businesses. |
14 | I'm not sure I would agree with Paul, though, on |
15 | this issue of convergence. I think there is a need, as |
16 | I say, for clarity, for clearly articulated rules, what |
17 | are rules of the game in country X, Y and Z, so that |
18 | business decisions can be made, but I think most of the |
19 | decision-making is typically done locally at the state |
20 | level in any event, although I recognize IP is a big, |
21 | big problem, and I don't know how you crack that nut, |
22 | frankly, but if you put that aside, I'm not sure how |
23 | much of even the globalized world, business |
24 | decision-making and conduct is done at the global level. |
25 | I think a lot of it's done at the local level. |
1 | And I think there's more scope in this area for |
2 | countries to reasonably disagree on what they consider |
3 | to be the prime policy drivers in attacking single-firm |
4 | conduct. With cartels, you know, countries, I think, |
5 | are much more aligned as to what the evil is there that |
6 | they're seeking to attack, and I think there's probably |
7 | a lot more room in the area of single-firm conduct for |
8 | different countries to reasonably disagree as to what |
9 | they want to attack, but I think that the most critical |
10 | point to advisers in the business community is to make |
11 | sure that the rules are clear and understandable. |
12 | MR. MASOUDI: Okay, Margaret? |
13 | MS. BLOOM: Okay, thanks, Jerry. There are four |
14 | quick points I'd like to make. |
15 | First of all, I think it's clear from this |
16 | morning and this afternoon that this is an area of law |
17 | where there is lots of change, so it is evolving. There |
18 | is a lack of case law generally, and there is an |
19 | increasing number of jurisdictions applying single-firm |
20 | conduct law, which means this is an increasing challenge |
21 | for business in relation to legal certainty. I do not |
22 | underestimate the importance of the chill factor. |
23 | The second point, I do not think that an |
24 | effects-based approach need necessarily be uncertain. |
25 | If you have good size safe harbors -- and I emphasize |
1 | the good -- if you have got decent sized safe harbors, |
2 | then the effects-based approach can also deliver legal |
3 | certainty. |
4 | I was very encouraged by Philip Lowe's reference |
5 | to the fact that he thought, in relation to Article 82 |
6 | in Europe, we should be less defensive. One point I was |
7 | just reflecting on, in relation to the size of the safe |
8 | harbors and the impact of the chill effect, I suspect |
9 | that in those jurisdictions (which is most of them |
10 | outside the United States), where the officials have not |
11 | been in business and they have not got the revolving |
12 | door, the enforcers probably underestimate the chill |
13 | factor. Certainly I have been more aware of it since I |
14 | have moved from being an enforcer to being in private |
15 | practice. |
16 | The third point, guidelines, I have stressed how |
17 | important I think they can be. We need to have |
18 | well-based guidelines, and I endorse the three rules |
19 | that Jim Rill had in relation to producing useful |
20 | guidelines, and I very much hope we will be seeing |
21 | guidelines in Europe. |
22 | And then the last point, the scope of the law |
23 | point that was raised this morning. Unfair trading and |
24 | protection of smaller firms was mentioned for Japan. |
25 | It's also in the laws a fair number of the European |
1 | Union Member States, and dare I mention it, the United |
2 | States has something called the Robinson-Patman Act. It |
3 | seems to me that this whole area might be one for the |
4 | ICN new working group to look at because it isn't just a |
5 | question of the abuse of dominant position Section 2 |
6 | type conduct, but it's what laws do countries have |
7 | against unfair trading as well. |
8 | Thank you. |
9 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, Margaret. |
10 | Paul? |
11 | MR. LUGARD: I think convergence is important, |
12 | but it is even more important to have a basic |
13 | understanding of the framework of analysis, even if this |
14 | means that there are different approaches in key |
15 | jurisdictions. I fully agree with Margaret that an |
16 | effects-based analysis doesn't necessarily mean that all |
17 | is unpredictable, and I believe that there is an urgent |
18 | need for the international business community to know |
19 | how it should assess its own conduct, even if that means |
20 | that it has to go through very difficult analyses. |
21 | There is a real chill factor in particular in |
22 | high technology markets. Perhaps we'll discuss that in |
23 | a second, and among the issues that need to be addressed |
24 | is certainly IP, and within that category, one of the |
25 | first things that needs to be thought about is |
1 | compulsory licensing, because that is where there's a |
2 | large degree of divergence, and in many of those cases, |
3 | the effects are not limited to one jurisdiction, but |
4 | instead, the decision of one agency might have worldwide |
5 | repercussions. |
6 | MR. MASOUDI: Okay, thank you, Paul. |
7 | Jim? |
8 | MR. RILL: It's always the danger of being the |
9 | fourth one that I tend to want to agree with everything |
10 | that everybody said, but I will say I think that the |
11 | need is for first transparency. Transparency can be |
12 | contributed to by safe harbors. I don't throw up my |
13 | hands or sit on them with the notion that convergence |
14 | over time is impossible. I think a great amount of |
15 | convergence has come with learning in the area of |
16 | horizontal mergers, but it takes time, it takes |
17 | dialogue, it takes effort. |
18 | I think we're a good ways away, Paul, from any |
19 | kind of convergence on dynamic versus static |
20 | efficiencies, of the appropriate definition of all the |
21 | important, critical factors to look at. |
22 | On this morning's program, I was taken with not |
23 | only the increasing interest and focus on dominant firm |
24 | conduct but the work that's being done in every |
25 | jurisdiction that spoke, also the U.S., on efforts to |
1 | study and add clarity to the principles being adopted by |
2 | or explored by the jurisdictions, rather, in that area. |
3 | The Canadian Guidelines, the Japanese study group, the |
4 | discussion draft process in the EC, the statutory |
5 | revisions in Mexico, all underscore the efforts that are |
6 | being made in the jurisdictions to bring clarity and |
7 | sound principles into the application of the law to |
8 | dominant firm conduct. Nonetheless, a lot remains to be |
9 | done. |
10 | I also picked up from this morning there's a |
11 | debate -- and I use that in the European sense -- |
12 | between Japan and the EC on whether an effects-based |
13 | approach adds sufficient clarity. I think it could. I |
14 | think it does, properly applied, and I think even if we |
15 | sacrifice some clarity for sound economic approach, it's |
16 | a sacrifice that I for one would be willing to make over |
17 | a more traditional, formalistic approach. We still have |
18 | to deal with concepts and statutes that have concepts |
19 | such as unfair, unjust, exclusive advantage, terms that |
20 | I can't just at first blush add much flesh to, and I |
21 | think all these moves are in the right direction. |
22 | I was a little perplexed about this morning's |
23 | panel. There was very little discussion given to the |
24 | question of convergence and the instruments that are |
25 | available for at least transparency across |
1 | jurisdictional lines in convergence, and I attribute |
2 | that to the fact that the agencies this morning were |
3 | quite properly focused on what was going on in their own |
4 | jurisdictions, but I think it's an area where, through |
5 | the ICN and the OECD, that the agencies can, are and |
6 | should do more work in the area of bringing about |
7 | cross-border transparency, and I suggest ultimately |
8 | convergence. |
9 | MR. MASOUDI: Thank you, Jim. |
10 | Now we will move on to some questions, and I |
11 | will hand the microphone to Randy. |
12 | MR. TRITELL: Thanks, Jerry. |
13 | Before I begin with the questions, two of the |
14 | speakers suggested that the U.S. agencies be engaged |
15 | with, for example, the EC and China on their work in |
16 | this area, and I just want to note that we are engaged |
17 | in and have been engaged in discussions with our |
18 | colleagues in Brussels about the Article 82 exercise and |
19 | remain engaged in discussions with the Chinese on the |
20 | evolution of their law, including in the dominance area. |
21 | Let me start out by tossing out a broad |
22 | question, which is what kind of trends do you observe, |
23 | looking around the legal landscape around the world, in |
24 | the single-firm conduct area? Do you see trends towards |
25 | convergence, for example, even in the basic objectives |
1 | of unilateral conduct laws, towards consumer welfare, or |
2 | is there still work to be done there, or in the |
3 | analysis? |
4 | Where would you want to see more convergence, |
5 | and for those who think it's less important, are there |
6 | areas where you think it is still important for agencies |
7 | to be largely on the same page, and areas where that is |
8 | less important? |
9 | It also relates to the question that Margaret |
10 | asked, if you assume a consumer welfare objective, |
11 | should we all do it the same way? |
12 | Margaret, let me give you an opportunity to add |
13 | to your remarks, if you want to answer that question in |
14 | any way. |
15 | MS. BLOOM: Okay, would you like me to start, is |
16 | that -- |
17 | MR. TRITELL: Yes, please. |
18 | MS. BLOOM: Okay. In terms of your first |
19 | question about what kind of trends, I think, first of |
20 | all, you've got more agencies with powers to apply |
21 | single-firm conduct. Every time you add a new agency, |
22 | then that is a tension, in a sense, to a degree away |
23 | from convergence, because you have got new staff |
24 | learning how to apply the law. |
25 | On the other hand, you have got, going the other |
1 | way, more efforts being made, for example, through the |
2 | OECD, through the ICN. You have already got the |
3 | European Union, which is now 25 Member States, going up |
4 | to 27, and the European Union itself is clearly a force |
5 | for convergence between those states, so you have got |
6 | tensions going in either direction. |
7 | On your question about should there be more |
8 | convergence, yes, I think there should be as much |
9 | convergence as will achieve maximum consumer welfare. |
10 | I'm an advocate of having that as your objective. |
11 | As I said earlier, I think there are some small |
12 | reasons for differences between jurisdictions, and I |
13 | give the example of the U.S. against Europe. There's |
14 | another example I can think of with a similar sort of |
15 | issued. If you have a very small market, say you're an |
16 | island, say Iceland, for example, is your approach to |
17 | single-firm conduct different from the approach that |
18 | should be taken in the United States with a large market |
19 | with many players? It might be. I don't know what the |
20 | answer is. I think there is an argument that you could |
21 | have a reason for being slightly more interventionist. |
22 | Maybe you need to have a price regulator, although I |
23 | know a permanent regulator is very much a second best. |
24 | MR. TRITELL: I invite anybody else who would |
25 | like to comment on that. |
1 | MR. RILL: Let me just say, I see two somewhat |
2 | conflicting trends going on right now. I think we see |
3 | the trend towards more cooperation, if not convergence, |
4 | and clarity. I think that the very formation of an ICN |
5 | working group on single-firm or dominant firm conduct is |
6 | evidence of that. I see a conflicting trend, barely |
7 | visible but nonetheless visible, particularly in a |
8 | dynamic economic world where innovation creates fair |
9 | competitive advantages that may be short-lived, |
10 | competitors trying to game the system, to do forum |
11 | shopping, to take a number of whacks at the pinata, to |
12 | try and play on divergence to find an agency somewhere |
13 | that will accept their complaint. I applaud the ICN for |
14 | establishing the working group that will hopefully |
15 | address that issue. |
16 | What would I like to see more of? I think the |
17 | movement, at least in the U.S. enforcement agencies, and |
18 | from what I understand from Philip's remarks this |
19 | morning, towards an analysis of what is the effect of a |
20 | particular course of conduct, an in-depth probing of |
21 | that effect of, if it's exclusionary conduct that's |
22 | being addressed, who is excluded, what is the meaning of |
23 | that exclusion, and how does the conduct promote that |
24 | level of exclusion, with sound economic reasoning and |
25 | transparency of the analysis in the results achieved. I |
1 | think that's the most desirable step that I would like |
2 | to see taken. |
3 | The second step, of course, is the proper role |
4 | of efficiencies in analysis, which Paul commented on |
5 | earlier. |
6 | MR. LUGARD: I agree with Jim that there is much |
7 | more cooperation between agencies, and I think that that |
8 | cooperation is generally producing positive effects; |
9 | also, for example, within the EC and European |
10 | Competition Network, and, of course, the ICN although |
11 | that's perhaps less formalized. There's more economics, |
12 | and perhaps paradoxically, I think a lot of the |
13 | convergence that we're speaking about today comes from |
14 | economists that tell us about the newest insights in |
15 | theories of harm that discipline indirectly the |
16 | decision-making processes of agencies. |
17 | I think there should be more reflection on the |
18 | evaluation of static and dynamic effects in one single |
19 | framework of analysis. I hope that the OECD round table |
20 | of October this year will stimulate that discussion, and |
21 | for the EC, I think that there is a specific issue that |
22 | needs to be addressed which relates to the burden and |
23 | allocation of proof. Again, that issue doesn't occur in |
24 | the U.S. because of the institutional setting, but that |
25 | problem is very real in Europe, and I can only hope that |
1 | DG COMP will be able to come up with a sensible and |
2 | practical way to solve that problem. |
3 | MR. ADDY: If I can just piggyback on those |
4 | comments, and I'll try not to repeat, I think on the |
5 | positive trend side, the increased discussion and debate |
6 | in public, in a very transparent fashion, amongst |
7 | agencies and people in the trade about the issues |
8 | surrounding single-firm conduct is a very positive |
9 | trend. |
10 | Issues of concern, I would highlight what Paul |
11 | was saying. To the extent that people are developing |
12 | frameworks for analysis, I'm concerned about the use of |
13 | rebuttable presumptions, because even with the right |
14 | framework, with rebuttable presumptions, you are |
15 | creating this chill that I'm absolutely paranoid about |
16 | and I think is really, really underestimated. So, I |
17 | don't think that's the way to go. |
18 | And I wouldn't want the increased dialogue and |
19 | work, which I think is positive, to then lead to, a |
20 | notion that having done all this work, we better bring a |
21 | lot more cases. So, I would be concerned that there may |
22 | be a reaction that now that we have got this creature, |
23 | whatever this guideline is or this clarification, let's |
24 | use it. |
25 | MS. BLOOM: Perhaps I could just add one further |
1 | thought. |
2 | One interesting impression, which I've noticed |
3 | in Europe, is that some of the large companies which |
4 | were former state-owned monopolies in their home |
5 | territory are arguing for minimal intervention, but in |
6 | the other Member States, where they're new entrants, |
7 | they're arguing for the maximum intervention. |
8 | MR. TRITELL: Given that we don't have complete |
9 | convergence at this time, what can we learn about how |
10 | businesses and their counselors react to different legal |
11 | regimes regarding single-firm conduct? George mentioned |
12 | the possibility of decentralizing decisions, but is that |
13 | really an option when you have global products and |
14 | markets, or does it result in what I believe Jim |
15 | referred to as a lowest common denominator, where a firm |
16 | would adapt itself to the most rescriptive rules? |
17 | Let's start, if we could, with Paul from the |
18 | point of view of company advisor. |
19 | MR. LUGARD: In many cases, it is possible to |
20 | decentralize decisions, and in many cases, it is not |
21 | necessary to adopt a certain conduct all over the globe. |
22 | In other cases, in particular in the IP sector, you may, |
23 | as a company, have to adapt yourself to local |
24 | circumstances, to a specific jurisdiction where the law |
25 | is not well articulated yet or where you are forced to |
1 | take another course or direction, but then in some |
2 | circumstances, that local decision will then have |
3 | worldwide repercussions, and that is a major problem. |
4 | I do not think that overall companies are |
5 | looking for a way to centralize decisions. In many |
6 | cases, as I said, you can decentralize, but it will be |
7 | very costly in many cases, and it may result in |
8 | suboptimal solutions which may not be good for a company |
9 | and which may also harm consumers. |
10 | MR. ADDY: If I could jump in now, the issue I |
11 | was getting at about local decision-making and |
12 | businesses being primarily market-driven, so if you're |
13 | selling a widget in country A, you're going to take into |
14 | account the market circumstances in deciding your |
15 | business conduct. An example might be if I'm a |
16 | global -- I don't know, pick one -- automotive |
17 | manufacturer and I have suppliers and I have plants all |
18 | over the world and suppliers all over the world, the |
19 | text of my supplier exclusivity agreement in country A |
20 | may be quite different from the agreement in country B. |
21 | So, the notion that there's a huge impediment to |
22 | business there, I'm not convinced yet. It might be |
23 | there. I just haven't seen any evidence of that, with |
24 | the exception that Paul was addressing, IP issue. |
25 | Frankly, I just don't know how to get my hands around |
1 | the IP issues. That is a very, very difficult area. |
2 | MR. RILL: I think there is also a question that |
3 | is probably unavoidable given the proliferation of |
4 | agencies with somewhat different approaches, a question |
5 | of transaction costs, which is huge, that we have |
6 | certainly run into and I'm sure everyone else has who |
7 | has done cross-border work, and that is just simply |
8 | identifying the course of conduct with some reasonable |
9 | confidence that it is not illegal over a multiplicity of |
10 | jurisdictions, and quite frankly, with some of the newer |
11 | antitrust regimes, it is very difficult to identify -- |
12 | not true in the U.S. -- but very difficult to identify |
13 | counsel who have any experience with the legal regimen, |
14 | even in their home country, and be confident of the |
15 | advice. |
16 | I think decentralized decision-making from the |
17 | legal standpoint is necessary but needs -- I think Paul |
18 | would agree with this -- needs some centralized control |
19 | at the level of the Paul Lugards of the world. |
20 | MS. BLOOM: I was just going to endorse |
21 | everything that Paul said. For example, if you are |
22 | talking about discounts, then it would be possible to |
23 | have a different discount structure in different |
24 | jurisdictions. It might not benefit the business or |
25 | consumers, but that is possible. But for IP or the |
1 | criteria of products, it may well not be possible to |
2 | differentiate between jurisdictions. |
3 | There is another issue. If you are thinking of |
4 | making a change in response to one agency, you may wish |
5 | to be careful that there are not then copycat cases in |
6 | other agencies. There will be some cases which it |
7 | started in one agency, and then other agencies picked |
8 | them up. It may be there is an equal problem in all |
9 | those other jurisdictions, but maybe not. |
10 | MR. TRITELL: Well, let's revisit the question |
11 | of presumptions and safe harbors that all of you have |
12 | touched upon in one way or another. George has just put |
13 | on the table the proposition that presumptions should be |
14 | avoided even if they are rebuttable. We have had some |
15 | endorsement in general of safe harbors, but it might be |
16 | interesting to hear any specific recommendations that |
17 | you think should be incorporated into agency policies. |
18 | Jim tossed out a list of some of the often |
19 | suggested candidates for safe harbors, and we welcome |
20 | your thoughts on advice to the agencies on what type of |
21 | presumptions and safe harbors are to be encouraged or |
22 | are to be avoided. |
23 | Jim, why don't we start down on your end. |
24 | MR. RILL: Well, first of all, having changed |
25 | from likely to sue to a presumption that the Hirfendahl |
1 | level in the Merger Guidelines, I'm a little reluctant |
2 | to engage in self-flagellation in the establishment of |
3 | presumption, but nonetheless, we use those presumptions |
4 | very flexibly, and they are carried with the entire |
5 | case. |
6 | No, I think that the point that George makes |
7 | with presumptions is a good one. I think the world is |
8 | too dynamic right now to have any confidence in the |
9 | presumption of illegality perhaps beyond hard core |
10 | cartel activity. I think that even the presumption as |
11 | to tying has come under huge criticism, in which I join. |
12 | The safe harbor, on the other hand, if set at a |
13 | proper level, is a good point for all the reasons I |
14 | stated in my remarks. Where should it be? It should be |
15 | high enough so that it really is a safe harbor and not |
16 | something so low that it does not give any comfort at |
17 | all. I would throw out numbers like 70 percent market |
18 | share, that would just be a thought, but I think taking |
19 | into account the dynamics of the market, likelihood of |
20 | entry and expansion, just to mention a few items, but |
21 | beyond that, I think the point is it should not be |
22 | something around 10 percent, with all respect to our |
23 | friends in Japan, because it gives no safe harbor at |
24 | all. |
25 | I think the progress made in predation is a good |
1 | one. I think in both the U.S. and Europe, we are |
2 | looking at some level of cost, predatory pricing, and I |
3 | think that concept of a cost-based test can be applied |
4 | to a number of other practices, including bundle pricing |
5 | and loyalty discounts, because I think that kind of a |
6 | concept will approach the trilogy that I mentioned of |
7 | some sound economic thinking, some flexibility, and, |
8 | quite frankly, some understandability compared to some |
9 | of the other thinking that has gone on in that area. |
10 | I'll footnote this, on the bundled pricing, I |
11 | think there is a cottage industry of economists out |
12 | there in the bundled pricing area that are developing |
13 | wild theories of what might be illegal and holding |
14 | themselves out to be hired by firms saying, "Your |
15 | practice, however, doesn't meet my theory." |
16 | On that note, I'll pass. |
17 | MR. TRITELL: Why don't we pass to Paul, if he |
18 | would like to offer any observations. |
19 | MR. LUGARD: I would be less than thrilled to |
20 | support the idea of safe harbors as a matter of |
21 | principle, but in practical terms, I am probably |
22 | slightly more positive. We have a number of European |
23 | examples, for example, the 30 percent market share |
24 | threshold in the vertical work exemption regulation, |
25 | that seems to work well. The potential problem with |
1 | safe harbors is, of course, that it is uncertain what |
2 | happens when you are not in safe harbor, so that there |
3 | may be a counter-productive effect. |
4 | What I would support most is, as I mentioned, |
5 | the methodology of analysis. If, for example, we are |
6 | looking at the discussion paper on Article 82, then it |
7 | starts off really well, because the Commission has done |
8 | a remarkable effort in explaining how it seeks to |
9 | identify negative effects. The problem with the |
10 | discussion paper in Europe is that the second part of |
11 | the paper is less useful. So, I'm very much in favor of |
12 | a clear framework of analysis even if it is difficult to |
13 | apply. |
14 | MS. BLOOM: I already discussed this in my |
15 | remarks, so I will be brief. In terms of safe harbors, |
16 | if they are going to be useful, they need to be large |
17 | enough. I think Jim Rill's proposed 70 percent is very |
18 | tempting, but unrealistic for Europe. |
19 | MR. MASOUDI: It is not large enough. |
20 | MS. BLOOM: Okay, 90 percent. |
21 | In Europe, I would encourage the Commission to |
22 | go for 50 percent, but I recognize that is asking an |
23 | awful lot. What I would suggest is that it would be |
24 | better to have a higher safe harbor with a rider that |
25 | exceptionally the agency might intervene, than a lower |
1 | safe harbor. If it is too low, it is not of much use. |
2 | In the UK, prior to the modernization of |
3 | European Community Law and the European Competition |
4 | Network, the OFT used to have a 40 percent safe harbor |
5 | with a rider that exceptionally it might intervene. In |
6 | fact, it never did. |
7 | On abuses, one safe harbor that I would add to |
8 | my cost test on my slide is we should have, in Europe, |
9 | recoupment for predation. |
10 | MR. ADDY: The only comment I would add is just |
11 | an observation, that we can theoretically say that under |
12 | our guidelines in Canada, there is a 35 percent safe |
13 | harbor, market share safe harbor, yet all the cases that |
14 | have been taken have been at the 80-plus. So, you know, |
15 | is there room to move that harbor up? I would probably |
16 | say yes, but then you get into Margaret's suggestion. |
17 | You have got to make sure that it is a hard number with |
18 | only a very exceptional or a very limited exception to |
19 | action, any disciplinary action. |
20 | MR. TRITELL: Let's turn to the role of |
21 | economics in the analysis of single-firm conduct. What |
22 | trends are you seeing in the agencies around the world |
23 | in the use of economics and economic evidence? What do |
24 | you see as the proper role for use of economics? How |
25 | should agencies use economic evidence and economists in |
1 | investigations of single-firm conduct? |
2 | I will invite whoever would like to offer |
3 | remarks. Why don't we start, if you like, George, with |
4 | you and work down. |
5 | MR. ADDY: Sure. |
6 | I'm of two minds, frankly, on that -- on the |
7 | issue of the use of economists. There's probably -- |
8 | with apologies to the economists in the room, so hold |
9 | your fire -- by the time you get to trial, of course, |
10 | everybody's rolling out competing economists, and you |
11 | get into that duel situation, which is what the process |
12 | yields. I'm not sure the economists are used early |
13 | enough at the analytical stage before the matter ever |
14 | becomes litigious, so I think increased use of economics |
15 | is a good thing. |
16 | Then the only other observation on that would be |
17 | I found the discussion paper, for instance, that |
18 | Philip's group put out to be heavily -- too heavily -- |
19 | leaning towards the economics, some of the -- reading |
20 | that document and trying to advise a client as to what |
21 | this hypothetical, possibly as efficient competitor |
22 | might be doing a few years from now had they come into |
23 | the market is very troubling. I mean, that's going down |
24 | the other end of the scale. |
25 | MS. BLOOM: Perhaps I should say as an economist |
1 | I am all in favor of the use of more economics -- thank |
2 | you, George. There is a trend to use of more economics. |
3 | When people talk about that, some of them are talking |
4 | about the use of more economics for an effects-based |
5 | analysis in the actual analysis itself. Other agencies |
6 | say, "Oh, yes, yes, we use a lot of economics," but |
7 | economics is used in developing the rules, and then when |
8 | the rules have been established, they are applied in a |
9 | form-based approach. It's using economics in the |
10 | analysis of the effects which is most valuable, though |
11 | if you're drawing up rules, the more they are based on |
12 | experience in economics, the better. |
13 | There are tensions which will mean that in |
14 | certainly some jurisdictions it will be relatively slow |
15 | to adopt full use of modern economics. Firstly, the |
16 | case precedents are quite difficult to reconcile with |
17 | modern economics in a number of jurisdictions. |
18 | Secondly, appeal courts are not necessarily sympathetic |
19 | to economic analysis, which is a factor that agencies |
20 | need to take account of. And lastly, some agencies have |
21 | difficulty in having enough economists trained in modern |
22 | economics, in I/O economics. They may find it easier to |
23 | recruit lawyers than economists. |
24 | Thank you. |
25 | MR. LUGARD: Copying on Margaret, I am not an |
1 | economist, but I sometimes think that I should have been |
2 | an economist. |
3 | I think the role of economists is increasing, |
4 | and I believe that it's a good thing. Their proper role |
5 | might be to identify the most plausible theory of harm |
6 | in a particular case or to discredit the theory of harm |
7 | which is advanced by the agency, and secondly, to help |
8 | in analyzing the actual effects in a particular case. |
9 | If the agency takes the position that there is a |
10 | significant lessening of competition, then that |
11 | conclusion should be supported by economic evidence, and |
12 | obviously, the dominant company will then resort to |
13 | economists to try and falsify that conclusion, and I |
14 | think that that is a proper role of economists. |
15 | Thank you. |
16 | MR. RILL: I would, first of all, endorse the |
17 | wider use of economists and economic learning in |
18 | antitrust analysis. I think that from the agency |
19 | standpoint as well as from the private sector |
20 | standpoint, the earlier the integrated analysis between |
21 | the economists and the lawyers takes place, the better |
22 | the result is likely to be. |
23 | I know from some times that in history, the |
24 | economists and lawyers have worked in totally separate |
25 | paths, converging only at the top level of the agency. |
1 | That, fortunately, doesn't happen anymore here, and it |
2 | is well advised not to have it happen elsewhere. |
3 | One comment on economists is that they're |
4 | terribly creative, and I think some of the work that's |
5 | been done may bear little relevance to the real world, |
6 | particularly in some of the wilder econometric |
7 | simulation analyses, which if nothing else don't pass |
8 | the test of comprehensibility, but I think that the |
9 | later work that's been done in that area that emphasizes |
10 | the need for econometric analysis to be supportive of |
11 | and supported by, more particularly, actual anecdotal |
12 | evidence that's pertinent and in debt makes that work |
13 | very useful. |
14 | I'm suspicious of economic work that develops |
15 | elaborate theories of harm that could be adopted or |
16 | looked at with some credence but may have very little |
17 | relationship to the underlying facts of the market. |
18 | MR. ADDY: If I could just jump in on that, the |
19 | use of integrated case teams involving lawyers and |
20 | economists I think is great and to be applauded. One |
21 | thing about the use of economics in the actual trial of |
22 | a dominance case is economists suffer just as much as |
23 | any other type of evidence or witness: the passage of |
24 | time. So, if you're -- and we'll take the Canada Pipe |
25 | case as an example just from a chronological |
1 | perspective. |
2 | The practice at issue started in '98, early '98. |
3 | The Bureau was aware of it as it started. The challenge |
4 | was filed with the Tribunal in 2002, so it would have |
5 | been the fall of 2002. The trial was in June of '04. |
6 | The trial decision came out in February '05. The Court |
7 | of Appeal came after -- so, you see this passage of |
8 | time, and what I'm trying to underscore is the fact that |
9 | you might have, as Jim says, this very elaborate model |
10 | trying to second-guess a business decision that may have |
11 | been made four or five years earlier, you have got to be |
12 | very careful with that. |
13 | MR. MASOUDI: Okay, I'd like to follow up on |
14 | something Jim Rill mentioned in his comments. Jim |
15 | talked about how guidelines can give certainty and |
16 | predictability but also can lead to rules being, in |
17 | essence, set in concrete, and if the rule isn't right to |
18 | begin with and it gets stuck where it is, that may not |
19 | be a good result. |
20 | In the U.S., we had some recent experience with |
21 | this where the United States Supreme Court considered |
22 | the issue of whether in a tying case, ownership of |
23 | intellectual property gives rise to a presumption of |
24 | market power, and based in part on the change in |
25 | position taken by the U.S. agencies in their 1995 |
1 | intellectual property guidelines, the Court said that |
2 | there would not be a presumption of market power from |
3 | ownership of intellectual property. |
4 | So, the question then arises, should agencies |
5 | periodically reconsider the positions they've taken |
6 | either on safe harbors or on presumptions or whatever |
7 | the issue is in the area of single-firm conduct? Should |
8 | there be a periodic re-examination of those principles? |
9 | And if so, what are mechanisms by which that kind of |
10 | re-examination could occur? |
11 | Why don't we start with Jim. |
12 | MR. RILL: Thanks very much, Jerry. |
13 | I had an interesting discussion at the break |
14 | with Sheridan Scott on my comment on guidelines, and I |
15 | think my comment should be taken as one more of the |
16 | structure and administrative nature of guidelines as |
17 | they become more like rules, if you will, or |
18 | regulations, not as criticism of guidance. |
19 | I think in the U.S., we have gotten to the point |
20 | where guidelines, as such, tend to be more proximate to |
21 | rules, and you run the risk of getting it wrong, and I |
22 | think a lot of people thought that the DOJ got it wrong |
23 | on the Vertical Restraint Guidelines in '84, which were |
24 | subsequently abandoned. I won't get into any political |
25 | analysis of that particular series of events, but I |
1 | think that guidelines do change from time to time, but |
2 | they tend to be looked at here, and perhaps not |
3 | elsewhere, as having the nature structurally of rules, |
4 | and I think that's why I made the point that it's |
5 | important to get it right from the threshold. But maybe |
6 | in other jurisdictions, guidelines don't have that kind |
7 | of aura to them, or at least not treated by the courts |
8 | as having that kind of effect. |
9 | There are other ways of giving guidance. More |
10 | guidance is better. It can be given by agency speeches, |
11 | it can be given by statements of enforcement policy, it |
12 | can be given by, yes indeed, cases, particularly in |
13 | common law jurisdictions, although one wants to be a |
14 | little chary of some cases coming, for example, out of |
15 | the Third Circuit, but I don't want to get too |
16 | particular. |
17 | The fact of the matter is, I do have some |
18 | concern, at least with the extent to which guidelines |
19 | can become rules and the risk then of getting it wrong |
20 | and perhaps guiding the conclusion away from current |
21 | consumer welfare and market-oriented results. |
22 | MR. MASOUDI: Paul? |
23 | MR. LUGARD: I think nobody would deny that it's |
24 | important to periodically review guidelines. The |
25 | triggering event should be something as vague as |
1 | important events in or outside your own jurisdiction. |
2 | There is an interesting European example where the |
3 | European approach towards maximum reasonable price |
4 | maintenance was changed after the U.S. Khan case some |
5 | years ago. So, that's an example where the European law |
6 | approach, which was laid down in the Guidelines on |
7 | Vertical Restraints, was changed as a result of the U.S. |
8 | developments. So, yes, there should be a periodic |
9 | review of guidelines or any other instrument that seeks |
10 | to help businesses and their advisers on the |
11 | implementation of the law. |
12 | MR. MASOUDI: Margaret? |
13 | MS. BLOOM: Thank you. |
14 | I endorse both what Jim and Paul said and just |
15 | add the comment that, of course, in Europe, there are |
16 | perhaps more antitrust guidelines than in the U.S., I'm |
17 | not sure, but They have been regularly reviewed in other |
18 | areas, for example, those on vertical restraints, |
19 | horizontal agreements, and technology transfer. It |
20 | seems to me the only argument against reviewing and |
21 | changing is you shouldn't do it so frequently that it's |
22 | constantly a fluid guideline. Paul's description of |
23 | when you should review is a rather good one. |
24 | MR. MASOUDI: George? |
25 | MR. ADDY: Thanks. |
1 | Yes, I think there's no question that guidelines |
2 | deserve periodic updating. What that period should be |
3 | obviously, you know, people can differ on what they |
4 | consider to be reasonable, but Margaret is right, it |
5 | shouldn't be sort of the guidelines du jour, because |
6 | people are relying on them to adjust their business |
7 | behavior. |
8 | I share Jim's concern about the nature of |
9 | guidelines versus other means of being transparent as to |
10 | what their importance of weight would be. I think |
11 | courts would give much more credence to guidelines, by |
12 | way of example, than they would a speech. So, I think |
13 | there is a difference in how binding they are, how |
14 | important they are and how significant they are than |
15 | other means. I think they are different from sort of a |
16 | speech to a trade association on how the agency is going |
17 | to look at this industry as opposed to a particular |
18 | guideline. |
19 | MR. MASOUDI: There was some discussion this |
20 | morning about the nature of the types of remedies that |
21 | are available to public enforcers as well as to private |
22 | parties around the world, and then this afternoon, we |
23 | have had some discussion of how varying substantive |
24 | standards affect how companies might do business when |
25 | they're doing business in many markets, and I wonder, |
1 | Margaret, you commented on how the availability, for |
2 | example, of treble damages in the United States might |
3 | affect how courts interpret the rules, and I wonder if |
4 | each of you might comment on how the different types of |
5 | enforcement remedies that are available throughout the |
6 | world might affect how companies do business in a global |
7 | marketplace. |
8 | Why don't we start with you, George. |
9 | MR. ADDY: I think it can have an impact. I'm |
10 | not sure I can help you on quantifying it. The |
11 | remedies, there's a whole range, you know, from just |
12 | cease and desist/prohibition type orders to monetary |
13 | penalties or what have you. |
14 | I think one of the big differences is private |
15 | action versus state-only action or agency-only action, |
16 | and there I am of two minds, that on the one hand, as I |
17 | said earlier, I believe that, jurisprudence is a public |
18 | good and it helps move the law ahead when you have cases |
19 | and judgments and decisions coming out, but I am very |
20 | concerned about the incentives and the creativity of the |
21 | plaintiff's bar as sort of -- I guess it has no bounds, |
22 | and I'm concerned about the extent to which you create |
23 | an incentive for litigation that will chill behavior and |
24 | could even shift investment, from one country to another |
25 | because of a fear of that type of litigation. |
1 | MR. MASOUDI: Margaret? |
2 | MS. BLOOM: When you look at the treble damages |
3 | that are possible in the United States, they're a scale |
4 | order different from anything you'll see in any other |
5 | jurisdiction. So, I suggest we need to set that aside. |
6 | So, if you're looking at anything else, it's |
7 | more the likelihood that there's going to be |
8 | intervention than what is the remedy that is going to |
9 | concentrate the mind as to what business thinks about |
10 | the different jurisdictions. |
11 | There is one particular issue in relation to |
12 | remedies I would just like to flag up, and that is, you |
13 | may well have conflicting remedies. One jurisdiction |
14 | requires something of a company which then conflicts |
15 | with a remedy that's required in another jurisdiction. |
16 | That, of course, is very problematic for business and |
17 | consumers. |
18 | And lastly, there is this issue about what is a |
19 | suitable remedy for a very powerful company. As an |
20 | economist, I would argue, in a sense, a fine is not an |
21 | entirely rational remedy for a very powerful company, |
22 | because if it's sufficiently powerful, arguably, it can |
23 | pass on the fine to its customers. But we still fine |
24 | powerful companies in Europe. |
25 | MR. MASOUDI: Paul? |
1 | MR. LUGARD: Just a couple of loose remarks. |
2 | I believe that fines can be effective in the |
3 | sense that people that are considered to be responsible |
4 | for these fines may have a serious problem within the |
5 | firm going forward. On a more general level, I think |
6 | that whether private actions are available, yes or no, |
7 | is a very important variable, and so is the possibility |
8 | of criminal enforcement, but perhaps the most effective |
9 | remedy, if you wish, is the enforcement record of the |
10 | agency. |
11 | If the agency can prove that it consistently |
12 | takes enforcement action against a certain business |
13 | conduct, then that is a very powerful disciplinary fact |
14 | of life. |
15 | MR. MASOUDI: And finally, Jim. |
16 | MR. RILL: Two points. One, I think a very |
17 | strong case could be made for eliminating punitive, i.e. |
18 | treble damage type remedies for conduct beyond the hard |
19 | core cartel area, and I think an examination of the U.S. |
20 | would be very worthwhile on that score, and I think the |
21 | same sort of thing was proposed by former Assistant |
22 | Attorney General Pate. |
23 | On the question of criminal sanctions, I think |
24 | one of the best statements I've heard made in opposition |
25 | to the establishment of criminal sanctions for |
1 | single-firm conduct was made by Tom Barnett, current |
2 | Assistant Attorney General, at the most recent OECD |
3 | round table on remedies and sanctions in single-firm |
4 | cases. The effect, once again, back to the effect of |
5 | single-firm conduct, the effect of single-firm conduct |
6 | can be very ambiguous, could be very easily |
7 | procompetitive, and to hold out criminal sanctions in an |
8 | area that's not so well developed in jurisprudence I |
9 | think has much more of a chilling effect on |
10 | procompetitive conduct than it has a chilling effect on |
11 | anticompetitive conduct. |
12 | MR. MASOUDI: Okay, thank you. |
13 | That exhausts our questions, and surprisingly, |
14 | we will conclude a few minutes early. Thank you all for |
15 | coming. Thank you to our panelists, and we'll see you |
16 | at our next session. |
17 | (Applause.) |
18 | (Whereupon, at 3:44 p.m., the hearing was |
19 | concluded.) |
20 | |
21 | |
22 | |
23 | |
24 | |
25 |
1 | C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F R E P O R T E R |
2 | DOCKET/FILE NUMBER: P062106 |
3 | CASE TITLE: SECTION 2 HEARING |
4 | DATE: SEPTEMBER 12, 2006 |
5 | |
6 | I HEREBY CERTIFY that the transcript contained |
7 | herein is a full and accurate transcript of the notes |
8 | taken by me at the hearing on the above cause before the |
9 | FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION to the best of my knowledge and |
10 | belief. |
11 | |
12 | DATED: 9/25/06 |
13 | |
14 | |
15 | |
16 | SUSANNE BERGLING, RMR-CLR |
17 | |
18 | C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F P R O O F R E A D E R |
19 | |
20 | I HEREBY CERTIFY that I proofread the transcript |
21 | for accuracy in spelling, hyphenation, punctuation and |
22 | format. |
23 | |
24 | |
25 | SARA J. VANCE |
Updated January 2, 2024