1
1 |
UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
|
2 |
and
|
3 |
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
|
4 |
|
5 |
|
6 |
|
7 |
SHERMAN ACT SECTION 2 JOINT HEARING
|
8 |
UNDERSTANDING SINGLE-FIRM BEHAVIOR:
|
9 |
MISLEADING AND DECEPTIVE CONDUCT SESSION
|
10 |
WEDNESDAY, DECEMBER 6, 2006
|
11 |
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
HELD AT:
|
16 |
UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
|
17 |
601 NEW JERSEY AVENUE, N.W.
|
18 |
WASHINGTON, D.C.
|
19 |
9:30 A.M. TO 1:00 P.M.
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
Reported and transcribed by:
|
25 |
Susanne Bergling, RMR-CLR |
2
1 |
MODERATORS:
|
2 |
RICHARD B. DAGEN
|
3 |
Special Counsel to the Director
|
4 |
Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission
|
5 |
and
|
6 |
HILL B. WELLFORD
|
7 |
Counsel to the Assistant Attorney General
|
8 |
Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice
|
9 |
|
10 |
PANELISTS:
|
11 |
|
12 |
Michael F. Brockmeyer
|
13 |
George S. Cary
|
14 |
Susan A. Creighton
|
15 |
R. Preston McAfee
|
16 |
Gil Ohana
|
17 |
Richard P. Rozek
|
18 |
|
19 |
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
|
3
4
1 |
P R O C E E D I N G S
|
2 |
- - - - -
|
3 |
MR. DAGEN: Okay, good morning, everybody. I am
|
4 |
Richard Dagen, Special Counsel to the Director of the
|
5 |
Bureau of Competition and one of the moderators for this
|
6 |
session. My co-moderator is Hill Wellford, Counsel to
|
7 |
the Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust at the
|
8 |
Department of Justice. Before we start, I need to cover
|
9 |
a few housekeeping matters.
|
10 |
First, please turn off your cell phones,
|
11 |
BlackBerries and any other devices. Second, the
|
12 |
restrooms are outside the double doors and across the
|
13 |
lobby. There are signs to guide you. Third, one safety
|
14 |
tip, particularly for visitors, in the unlikely event
|
15 |
the building alarms go off, please proceed calmly and
|
16 |
quickly as instructed. If we must leave the building,
|
17 |
exit the New Jersey Avenue exit by the guard's desk, and
|
18 |
please follow the stream of FTC people to a gathering
|
19 |
point and await further instruction. Finally, we
|
20 |
request that you not make comments or ask questions
|
21 |
during the session. Thank you.
|
22 |
Now, today we are honored to have assembled a
|
23 |
distinguished panel of practitioners, consultants and
|
24 |
professors who are well versed in the issues we will
|
25 |
tackle today involving misleading and deceptive conduct. |
5
1 |
The hearing will be organized as follows: First, we
|
2 |
will hear an approximately 15-minute presentation from
|
3 |
each panelist. We will likely break after the fourth
|
4 |
panelist speaks, and after the break, hear from our
|
5 |
final two speakers. After the presentations, we will
|
6 |
have a round table discussion moderated by Hill Wellford
|
7 |
and me.
|
8 |
Our panelists today are Susan Creighton, who is
|
9 |
a partner at Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati and a
|
10 |
former director of the FTC's Bureau of Competition;
|
11 |
Preston McAfee, who is the J. Stanley Johnson Professor
|
12 |
of Business Economics and Management at the California
|
13 |
Institute of Technology; Gil Ohana, who is the Director,
|
14 |
Antitrust and Competition, Cisco Systems; Richard Rozek,
|
15 |
who is a senior vice president, NERA Economic
|
16 |
Consulting; Michael Brockmeyer, who is a partner at
|
17 |
Frommer Lawrence & Haug and an Adjunct Professor of Law
|
18 |
at the University of Maryland School of Law; and George
|
19 |
Cary, who is a partner at Cleary Gottlieb Steen &
|
20 |
Hamilton and a former Deputy Bureau Director of the
|
21 |
FTC's Bureau of Competition.
|
22 |
I want to thank the FTC and DOJ Section 2 staff
|
23 |
for organizing this session. This is the last Section 2
|
24 |
hearing for 2006, but the hearings will continue during
|
25 |
the first few months of 2007, so be sure to check the |
6
1 |
agencies' web sites for updates.
|
2 |
Second, I want to explain why a session entitled
|
3 |
Misleading and Deceptive Conduct is, in fact, a session
|
4 |
about Section 2 of the Sherman Act and not a hearing
|
5 |
being held by the FTC's Bureau of Consumer Protection.
|
6 |
Deceptive conduct is a type of exclusionary conduct that
|
7 |
has been the basis for antitrust liability under Section
|
8 |
2. The Federal Trade Commission defined deception in
|
9 |
1983, noting that the FTC "will find deception if there
|
10 |
is a representation, omission or practice that is likely
|
11 |
to mislead the consumer acting reasonably in the
|
12 |
circumstances to the consumer's detriment."
|
13 |
In In re Rambus, a matter involving conduct
|
14 |
before a standard-setting organization, the Commission
|
15 |
explained that the policy statement could be applied to
|
16 |
a Section 2 analysis, although it did not directly
|
17 |
equate the policy statement's definition of deception
|
18 |
with exclusionary conduct under Section 2. Consistent
|
19 |
with our general policy to avoid discussing cases during
|
20 |
the hearings that are currently in litigation, and
|
21 |
because the Rambus matter is still in administrative
|
22 |
litigation and there has not been a final appealable
|
23 |
judgment, we will not be discussing this case today.
|
24 |
There are a variety of scenarios under which
|
25 |
deceptive and misleading conduct may form the basis of a |
7
1 |
Section 2 antitrust violation, and this hearing is
|
2 |
designed to address many of them. Deception also may
|
3 |
encompass fraud, bad faith, falsehoods,
|
4 |
misrepresentations and misleading conduct. These terms
|
5 |
are related and sometimes used interchangeably. Such
|
6 |
conduct can occur in both the private and public sector.
|
7 |
Certain business torts and standard-setting activity may
|
8 |
provide the basis of Section 2 liability.
|
9 |
In one recent case, Conwood versus United States
|
10 |
Tobacco, the Sixth Circuit upheld a $1 billion treble
|
11 |
damages award. The allegations of exclusionary conduct
|
12 |
in Conwood included misrepresentations of sales data to
|
13 |
retailers as well as the destruction of competitors'
|
14 |
products and displays.
|
15 |
In United States versus Microsoft, the D.C.
|
16 |
Court of Appeals found that Microsoft engaged in
|
17 |
exclusionary conduct in violation of Section 2 when it
|
18 |
deceived Sun Microsystems and independent software
|
19 |
developers by offering them a set of Java implementation
|
20 |
tools that ostensibly would enable them to develop
|
21 |
cross-platform applications but could be executed only
|
22 |
by Microsoft's version of the Java runtime environment
|
23 |
for Windows.
|
24 |
Misleading and deceptive conduct in the context
|
25 |
of abuse of governmental processes can also be the basis |
8
1 |
for Section 2 liability. Such cases have included FDA
|
2 |
Orange Book listings and fraud on the Patent Office.
|
3 |
Now I would like to turn it over to Hill for a
|
4 |
few remarks.
|
5 |
MR. WELLFORD: Good morning. My name is Hill
|
6 |
Wellford. I am counsel to AAG Tom Barnett. The FTC and
|
7 |
DOJ are jointly sponsoring these hearings today to help
|
8 |
advance development of the law concerning the treatment
|
9 |
of unilateral conduct under the antitrust laws. This is
|
10 |
one of the most controversial areas even within Section
|
11 |
2, which is controversial enough on its own, and I think
|
12 |
we should have a very good panel today. I have seen
|
13 |
some of these presentations that have come in, and I am
|
14 |
very much looking forward to the remarks that will be
|
15 |
presented by the panel. Thanks to my colleagues at the
|
16 |
FTC and the Division for organizing this. I will hand
|
17 |
it back over to Rich.
|
18 |
MR. DAGEN: So, I would like to introduce your
|
19 |
first speaker. Susan Creighton, as I mentioned before,
|
20 |
is a partner at Wilson Sonsini. Between 2001 and 2006,
|
21 |
she served at the Federal Trade Commission first as
|
22 |
Deputy Director and then as Director of the Bureau of
|
23 |
Competition. While at the FTC, she played a key role in
|
24 |
developing antitrust policy and made important
|
25 |
contributions about, among other things, the |
9
1 |
intersection of antitrust and intellectual property.
|
2 |
She is a frequent author of antitrust articles,
|
3 |
including a 2005 Antitrust Law Journal article entitled
|
4 |
"Cheap Exclusion" dealing with many of the issues we
|
5 |
will be discussing today.
|
6 |
Susan?
|
7 |
MS. CREIGHTON: Good morning. Let's see if I
|
8 |
can figure out how to make this thing move. That
|
9 |
worked, okay.
|
10 |
So, courts and enforcers long have recognized
|
11 |
that deception can constitute unlawful exclusionary
|
12 |
conduct under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. With
|
13 |
respect to deception in the context of private business
|
14 |
arrangements, probably the two most recent prominent
|
15 |
decisions are the D.C. Circuit decision in Microsoft and
|
16 |
the FTC's decision in Rambus. The potential for
|
17 |
deception in government proceedings to serve as the
|
18 |
basis for Section 2 liability is reflected in cases
|
19 |
stretching as far back as the Supreme Court's decision
|
20 |
in Walker Process and more recently has been a major
|
21 |
part of the FTC's enforcement agenda, as Rick mentioned,
|
22 |
in cases such as UNOCAL and the Orange Book listing
|
23 |
cases.
|
24 |
In my view, these cases are correct in holding
|
25 |
that deception can constitute a basis for finding |
10
1 |
exclusionary conduct under Section 2. Indeed, as my
|
2 |
co-authors and I argued in the article that Rick
|
3 |
referred to in the Antitrust Law Journal entitled "Cheap
|
4 |
Exclusion," deception and other forms of cheap exclusion
|
5 |
are potentially a very effective form of anticompetitive
|
6 |
conduct and properly should be a core focus of
|
7 |
enforcement efforts by the FTC, the Antitrust Division
|
8 |
and the state enforcement agencies.
|
9 |
In particular, in our article, we highlighted
|
10 |
three characteristics of such cheap exclusion, including
|
11 |
deception. First, it is cheap in the sense that it
|
12 |
costs little to the firm engaging in it. False
|
13 |
statements made during a governmental standard-setting
|
14 |
proceeding may be virtually costless, for example,
|
15 |
particularly for a firm that would have participated in
|
16 |
the regulatory proceeding in any event. These de
|
17 |
minimus costs compare favorably to the high costs that a
|
18 |
firm might incur, for example, through the low-cost
|
19 |
pricing or potentially strategies such as exclusive
|
20 |
dealing.
|
21 |
Second, the conduct also is cheap in the sense
|
22 |
of lacking any redeeming virtue. Deceptive conduct
|
23 |
unambiguously fails to enhance any party's efficiency,
|
24 |
provides no benefits short or long term to consumers,
|
25 |
and its economic effect produces only costs for the |
11
1 |
victims and wealth transfers to the firms engaging in
|
2 |
the conduct fully apart from its potential contribution
|
3 |
to market power.
|
4 |
Finally, it is also cheap in the relative sense
|
5 |
that it is a strategy where the costs are often likely
|
6 |
to be far outstripped by the anticompetitive benefits.
|
7 |
As the Antitrust Division explained in its business
|
8 |
review letter, for example, "Early in the
|
9 |
standard-setting process, standard-setting members often
|
10 |
can choose among multiple substitute technological
|
11 |
solutions, some of which may be patented. Once a
|
12 |
particular technology is chosen and the standard is
|
13 |
developed, however, it can be extremely expensive or
|
14 |
even impossible to substitute one technology for
|
15 |
another." Misrepresentations that enable a firm to
|
16 |
charge higher discriminatory royalty rates after lock-in
|
17 |
therefore may enable the firm to enjoy substantial and
|
18 |
durable market power.
|
19 |
Because deceptive conduct ordinarily has no
|
20 |
efficiency or other procompetitive benefits, other forms
|
21 |
of cheap exclusion do not provide the same type of
|
22 |
trade-off that we see with respect to most other forms
|
23 |
of exclusionary conduct that have been the subject of
|
24 |
the previous hearings, predatory pricing, bundling,
|
25 |
exclusive dealing and the like. With respect to these |
12
1 |
forms of conduct, it is generally recognized that they
|
2 |
will often, maybe even overwhelmingly often, be
|
3 |
procompetitive rather than anticompetitive. The
|
4 |
challenge, therefore, is to distinguish the times when
|
5 |
the conduct might be anticompetitive without unduly
|
6 |
chilling the procompetitive conduct.
|
7 |
With respect to deceptive or other opportunistic
|
8 |
conduct, however, there is no similar concern that we
|
9 |
will be unduly chilling deception or opportunism. In
|
10 |
fact, sort of phrased that way, I do not think we
|
11 |
generally sort of think of being concerned about
|
12 |
chilling deception. In this context, cheap exclusion
|
13 |
may be viewed as something like the Section 2 analog to
|
14 |
Section 1 price fixing; that is, we are not unduly
|
15 |
concerned with overdeterrence of this behavior, and it
|
16 |
is at the same time at the far end of the spectrum for
|
17 |
Section 2 purposes from predatory pricing.
|
18 |
If there is a category of conduct that we are
|
19 |
particularly concerned not to chill under Section 2, it
|
20 |
is price cutting. With respect to misrepresentations
|
21 |
and deception, by contrast, we have and should have no
|
22 |
such scruples.
|
23 |
Screening tests designed to find the single
|
24 |
exclusionary goat in the vast herd of procompetitive
|
25 |
sheep, therefore, are not well suited and should not be |
13
1 |
applied to exclusionary fraud or deception. The profit
|
2 |
sacrifice test, for example, originally conceived as a
|
3 |
means to screen out legitimate pricing behavior, does
|
4 |
not work well when applied to conduct that is not
|
5 |
legitimate, whether or not it is exclusionary.
|
6 |
For example, fraudulent regulatory filings that
|
7 |
can be made at de minimus costs may have powerful
|
8 |
exclusionary effects due to the operation of extrinsic
|
9 |
legal schemes. At the same time, such conduct also may
|
10 |
be profitable even if it does not result in the creation
|
11 |
of durable market power by harming competitors and
|
12 |
generating profits for the filing firms, yet the mere
|
13 |
fact of the profitability of this illegitimate behavior
|
14 |
tells us nothing about whether the behavior or the
|
15 |
fraudulent filing is legitimate efficiency-enhancing
|
16 |
behavior.
|
17 |
Now, if the balancing question typically raised
|
18 |
regarding Section 2 conduct is not present here, what
|
19 |
other concerns are raised regarding exclusionary fraud
|
20 |
or deception? It seems to me that there are three
|
21 |
concerns that are raised most frequently. The first is
|
22 |
causation. This issue underlies a considerable portion
|
23 |
of the Commission's legal analysis in Rambus, for
|
24 |
example, and I'll return to that. The second is that
|
25 |
antitrust should not be used as a kind of ex post |
14
1 |
gap-filler for poorly written standard-setting rules or
|
2 |
legal regulations. And the third is that we should not
|
3 |
use antitrust where other laws, such as business torts
|
4 |
and contract law, already can be used to reach and
|
5 |
prohibit the conduct.
|
6 |
Let me address each of these three objections
|
7 |
briefly in turn. First, with respect to causation, it
|
8 |
seems to me that contrary to the concern about causation
|
9 |
often expressed in this area, exclusionary deception, in
|
10 |
fact, often occurs in circumstances where the
|
11 |
environment is, in fact, conducive to the acquisition or
|
12 |
maintenance of durable market power. Indeed, for
|
13 |
deceptive conduct in the government context, it seems to
|
14 |
me that this is often likely to be the rule rather than
|
15 |
the exception.
|
16 |
The reason is simple. If the exclusion operates
|
17 |
by force of law, the exercise of market power will not
|
18 |
induce new entry, and the entry barriers created by the
|
19 |
need to change laws or regulations may be formidable
|
20 |
indeed. The UNOCAL case, for example, highlights these
|
21 |
effects. Now, that's in the government context.
|
22 |
In the private context, as the Commission
|
23 |
discussed in Rambus, profitable private ventures may
|
24 |
also often be conducive to the use of deception to
|
25 |
acquire or maintain durable market power. In instances |
15
1 |
where business relations are characterized by
|
2 |
cooperation rather than competition, for instance, the
|
3 |
Java development program in Microsoft or in instances of
|
4 |
private standard-setting activity, deception may be
|
5 |
difficult to deter or counter, and the resulting
|
6 |
lock-in, especially in network industries, may be
|
7 |
difficult or impossible to overcome once the deception
|
8 |
has been detected.
|
9 |
Now, in this regard, deceptive advertising,
|
10 |
where the statements are both ascertainable and
|
11 |
falsifiable, may actually be the exception rather than
|
12 |
the rule. In Caribbean Broadcasting, for example, the
|
13 |
alleged deceptive statement was one that was made
|
14 |
publicly, and it would appear to be one that would be
|
15 |
readily falsifiable. Did the company's broadcast, in
|
16 |
fact, reach the entire Caribbean region or not? That
|
17 |
seemed to be an answer that you probably could pretty
|
18 |
much figure out with a couple of guys and radios.
|
19 |
Now, by comparison, in Conwood, if I understand
|
20 |
the allegations correctly, the alleged deceptive
|
21 |
statements were made in private communications to
|
22 |
retailers. It is unclear how or when the plaintiff
|
23 |
would have been able to learn of them, and hence, to
|
24 |
counteract them.
|
25 |
One might also consider a statement that is less |
16
1 |
readily falsifiable. For example, statements claiming
|
2 |
patent infringement by a competitor's product without
|
3 |
any identification of the particular patents in issue or
|
4 |
anything sort of as formal as some kind of warning
|
5 |
letter that would make it possible to respond to the
|
6 |
allegation might be the kind of tipping event you could
|
7 |
expect potentially to have a forceful impact in network
|
8 |
industries.
|
9 |
Now, the second concern raised regarding
|
10 |
exclusionary deception is what I have called the
|
11 |
gap-filling problem. The concern here, as I understand
|
12 |
it, is that antitrust is effectively being used in these
|
13 |
circumstances to take care of problems that could have
|
14 |
been solved ex ante through more careful drafting,
|
15 |
either the Orange Book regulations or the
|
16 |
standard-setting rules.
|
17 |
Now, here I raise with some trepidation as a
|
18 |
lawyer on a panel with economists who may, in fact,
|
19 |
provide a more subtle understanding of this point, it
|
20 |
seems to me that the insight of transaction cost
|
21 |
economics is applicable here, and I have up here a quote
|
22 |
from Oliver Williamson. "The general rubric out of
|
23 |
which transaction cost economics works is that of hazard
|
24 |
mitigation through ex post governance. It being the
|
25 |
case that all complex contracts are unavoidably |
17
1 |
incomplete, the fiction of comprehensive contracting,
|
2 |
which concentrates all of the contracting action on ex
|
3 |
ante incentive alignment, is untenable."
|
4 |
Now, I have also referred in my slides here and
|
5 |
also in the "Cheap Exclusion" article by analogy to an
|
6 |
article written some time ago by former FTC chairman Tim
|
7 |
Muris regarding the judicial doctrine of the duty of
|
8 |
good faith and fair dealing. His point, as I understand
|
9 |
it, in the article was that parties to a contract cannot
|
10 |
adequately defend themselves ex ante against
|
11 |
opportunistic conduct that undermines the parties'
|
12 |
legitimate expectations, perhaps even the purpose of the
|
13 |
contract, at least not without incurring wasteful and
|
14 |
inefficient transaction costs of the type that
|
15 |
Williamson was describing.
|
16 |
So, the judicial imposition of good faith and
|
17 |
fair dealing is an efficient means of protecting parties
|
18 |
against conduct that is contrary to their legitimate
|
19 |
expectations but not necessarily contrary to the precise
|
20 |
language of the contract.
|
21 |
By analogy, the antitrust laws can and should
|
22 |
serve to protect against deceptive or opportunistic
|
23 |
misuse, for example, of collaborative ventures such as
|
24 |
standard-setting organizations where such conduct
|
25 |
defeats the very purpose of such arrangements and that |
18
1 |
which makes them acceptable under the antitrust laws.
|
2 |
That intuition, I think, for example, is what the
|
3 |
Supreme Court was driving at when it said in Allied Tube
|
4 |
that, "Private standard-setting by associations is
|
5 |
permitted under the antitrust laws only on the
|
6 |
understanding that it will be conducted in a nonpartisan
|
7 |
manner offering procompetitive benefits."
|
8 |
Now, although standard-setting organizations can
|
9 |
and should exercise self-help to the extent possible,
|
10 |
the insight of transaction cost economics is that no
|
11 |
amount of ex ante bargaining can ever perfectly secure
|
12 |
collaborative ventures or other government regulations,
|
13 |
such as the Orange Book, against opportunism in
|
14 |
circumstances where it turns the purpose of the
|
15 |
collaboration or the regulation on its head and in a way
|
16 |
that it threatens the creation of durable market power.
|
17 |
Moreover, in other contexts, such as the Java
|
18 |
development in Microsoft, the collaboration will not
|
19 |
even be pursuant to elaborate written contracts. In
|
20 |
such circumstances, antitrust law in my view properly
|
21 |
provides part of the ex post governance structure that
|
22 |
helps ensure ex ante that such collaborations and
|
23 |
regulations achieve their intended procompetitive
|
24 |
purposes.
|
25 |
Now, finally, sometimes the question whether |
19
1 |
deceptive exclusion should be subject to Section 2 gets
|
2 |
posed wrongly in my view as whether the conduct at issue
|
3 |
is a business tort, and if it is, why then do we need to
|
4 |
subject it to the antitrust laws? I think that this
|
5 |
asks the question through the wrong end of the
|
6 |
telescope. The right question to ask is, is an
|
7 |
inefficient exclusionary act that is likely to have
|
8 |
caused market power nonetheless excused under Section 2
|
9 |
because it also violates another law or statute?
|
10 |
Now, the reason it is important to ask the right
|
11 |
question is the old true saying, the wrong answer is
|
12 |
what the wrong question begets. Here, asking first
|
13 |
whether the conduct is tortious and then why do we need
|
14 |
antitrust is likely to be misleading in at least three
|
15 |
ways.
|
16 |
First, these business torts and contract rights
|
17 |
vindicate the rights of the wrong people. In a
|
18 |
standard-setting organization, for example, we are not
|
19 |
concerned ultimately with the rights of the
|
20 |
standard-setting organization or its participants, but
|
21 |
consumers. As Ted Gephart has written about,
|
22 |
standard-setting organizations and their participants
|
23 |
may or may not have interests that coincide with those
|
24 |
of consumers, but simply because they might be
|
25 |
indifferent to the anticompetitive consequences of the |
20
1 |
deceptive conduct, for example, because they will be
|
2 |
able to pass through price rises to consumers, does not
|
3 |
address what antitrust is concerned with, namely,
|
4 |
whether the conduct harms consumers.
|
5 |
Now, similarly, business torts and contract law
|
6 |
provide the wrong measures of causation and harm. A
|
7 |
standard-setting participant who is able to pass along
|
8 |
price increases may not have been harmed and should not
|
9 |
be able to recover for the nonetheless real harm that
|
10 |
consumers will have suffered.
|
11 |
Finally, business torts may have elements that
|
12 |
do not fit well with the proper issue from an antitrust
|
13 |
perspective, or conversely, may be missing elements
|
14 |
necessary to answer the antitrust claim. The intent
|
15 |
element in fraud, for example, may or may not be apt to
|
16 |
the proper antitrust question in a particular factual
|
17 |
setting.
|
18 |
Now, underlying this question, I think,
|
19 |
ultimately really is a different issue, which is the
|
20 |
hostility to private rights of action under Section 2,
|
21 |
particularly their treble damage provisions, and a
|
22 |
concern regarding unjustified suits. That issue,
|
23 |
however, in my view properly should be dealt with
|
24 |
directly and not by wrongly manipulating substantive
|
25 |
standards under Section 2. |
21
1 |
For the reasons that I have explained, I think
|
2 |
that, in fact, this is an area that should be a
|
3 |
priority, not a backwater for federal and state
|
4 |
antitrust agencies. The importance of the substantive
|
5 |
area should not be obscured or the barriers to effective
|
6 |
enforcement heightened by an effort to cut off private
|
7 |
litigation whose flaws lie elsewhere, not in their
|
8 |
substantive antitrust claims, but rather, in procedural
|
9 |
rules that govern private Section 2 actions.
|
10 |
Thank you very much.
|
11 |
(Applause.)
|
12 |
MR. DAGEN: Thank you, Susan.
|
13 |
Our next speaker is Preston McAfee. He's the
|
14 |
J. Stanley Johnson Professor of Business Economics and
|
15 |
Management at the California Institute of Technology
|
16 |
where he teaches business strategy, managerial
|
17 |
economics, and principles of economics. Preston is the
|
18 |
author of over 70 articles published in scholarly
|
19 |
economics journals and co-author of the book Incentives
|
20 |
in Government Procurement. He served as one of four
|
21 |
economists who edit the American Economic Review for
|
22 |
over nine years.
|
23 |
Preston?
|
24 |
DR. McAFEE: Thank you. Thank you, Susan, for
|
25 |
actually providing the lead-in for what I would like to |
22
1 |
talk about today, and let me also apologize for being
|
2 |
still on California time and so only about 60 percent
|
3 |
awake.
|
4 |
So, I would like to talk about the right of
|
5 |
private action under the antitrust laws and connect that
|
6 |
to deception and fraud as follows. Whatever is decided
|
7 |
about deceptive practices and the right to sue under the
|
8 |
antitrust laws will be abused in private suits if those
|
9 |
are permitted, and let me warm up with VeriSign. So,
|
10 |
VeriSign is the registrar of .com and .net, and in 2003,
|
11 |
they began redirecting mistyped addresses to their own
|
12 |
advertising site. The ISPs objected and asked the ruler
|
13 |
of the internet to stop the practice, and VeriSign
|
14 |
contended that that was an illegal conspiracy. The
|
15 |
judge threw this out, which I think was the right
|
16 |
answer.
|
17 |
One thing that is a really interesting question
|
18 |
about this particular antitrust suit is actually, what
|
19 |
is somewhat of a principle, I guess, is it is often hard
|
20 |
to fit modern industries into traditional economic
|
21 |
analysis of antitrust, and this is a really nice poster
|
22 |
child for that, because what is the quantity here? Is
|
23 |
it the number of mistyped addresses? Well, that is
|
24 |
something that is not affected by anyone's behavior,
|
25 |
because that is just purely, you know, when consumers |
23
1 |
make a mistake will determine that.
|
2 |
On the other hand, you might think it is the
|
3 |
number of advertisements, or in this case, is it the
|
4 |
number of Viagra ads that are produced? Well, here is a
|
5 |
situation where, in fact, we would like to reduce the
|
6 |
quantity. That is, it would be welfare-enhancing to
|
7 |
actually reduce the quantity that is produced by the
|
8 |
industry. It does not quite stop there.
|
9 |
So, another company that buys expired domains
|
10 |
and then redirects them to its own advertising site sued
|
11 |
VeriSign, that is, the plaintiff in the previous
|
12 |
antitrust suit, saying that the existence of VeriSign's
|
13 |
site finder itself violated the antitrust laws, and that
|
14 |
suit, last time I looked, which was a week ago, seems to
|
15 |
still be continuing. So, one thing is is that these
|
16 |
suits concern the same behavior, that is,
|
17 |
sitefinder.com, one saying that it was required and the
|
18 |
other saying that it is prohibited by the antitrust
|
19 |
laws, and so it makes for an interesting challenge.
|
20 |
So, here are the things I would like to talk
|
21 |
about. I have already talked about one example, and I
|
22 |
am going to mention a couple more. I want to then talk
|
23 |
about some research on for what purposes are private
|
24 |
antitrust claims brought, who has an incentive to sue,
|
25 |
and report on some research on that, and then conclude. |
24
1 |
The Colorado Chiropractic Council sent hospitals
|
2 |
requests for privileges and included in their request
|
3 |
the threat of a lawsuit if denied. Nine of the
|
4 |
hospitals did not admit the Colorado Chiropractic
|
5 |
Council, and these hospitals were all, in fact, sued for
|
6 |
restraint of trade. The suit was thrown out, but the
|
7 |
message I want to bring to this is 21 hospitals admitted
|
8 |
them, and while it is not demonstrated, it appears that
|
9 |
the threat of an antitrust suit was, in fact, an
|
10 |
effective threat.
|
11 |
Antitrust actions outnumber or private suits
|
12 |
outnumber government suits nine to one. Some of the
|
13 |
reasons that they are given, I spoke with an attorney
|
14 |
who says he tried to convert every contract suit into an
|
15 |
antitrust suit as his first action, because it gives him
|
16 |
access to treble damages, recovery of legal fees, and it
|
17 |
is easier to survive summary judgment. So, private
|
18 |
actions have grown. Canada, actually, did not permit
|
19 |
private litigation until 1976, and they are still rare,
|
20 |
probably because they do not have treble damages.
|
21 |
So, the general idea which I think Susan
|
22 |
reflected for me is that the incentives for private
|
23 |
antitrust litigation are not guided by consumer welfare.
|
24 |
The firms bringing the suit, consumer welfare generally
|
25 |
is not their goal or motivation. So, what I want to |
25
1 |
look at is, what are the actual motives of firms engaged
|
2 |
in private antitrust action and assess to what extent
|
3 |
the law can be used strategically, and then hopefully
|
4 |
that will give us some insight into crafting the laws to
|
5 |
minimizing the damage that is actually brought.
|
6 |
Some of the uses to which the antitrust laws are
|
7 |
brought -- private suits are put are harassment, harm
|
8 |
and extortion, and harassment and harm can actually be
|
9 |
used to induce cooperation, and this is especially
|
10 |
effective because it is often cheaper to sue than it is
|
11 |
to defend, and if you want to ensure cooperation, what
|
12 |
you want is a punishment that is easy to mete out but
|
13 |
expensive for the punished, and if it is symmetric, this
|
14 |
is actually the economic theory of cooperation or
|
15 |
collusion, actually, the same theory, suggests that that
|
16 |
is the kind of punishment you would like to use. In
|
17 |
addition, extortion reduces the returns to investment.
|
18 |
That is clearly chilling -- chilling effect on
|
19 |
investment.
|
20 |
Surveying a large number of private antitrust
|
21 |
suits, we have come up with seven different reasons for
|
22 |
private litigation, and I have color-coded them to what
|
23 |
extent they are opposed to the interests of consumers.
|
24 |
So, two quite common reasons are extorting funds from a
|
25 |
successful rival, and I want to especially point to |
26
1 |
follow-on suits. So, when the Government brings a suit,
|
2 |
generally there is an entire group of people who follow
|
3 |
on. Microsoft, of course, has been subject to many of
|
4 |
those follow-on suits.
|
5 |
In addition, changing the terms of a contract,
|
6 |
antitrust suits can be effective means of doing that on
|
7 |
occasion, and as I said, some contract attorneys prefer
|
8 |
antitrust suits because they think that it makes the
|
9 |
defendant more likely to settle. Something that is
|
10 |
speculative on our part is that it can be used to punish
|
11 |
noncooperative behavior. Of course, no one is going to
|
12 |
admit to this, because by and large you have then
|
13 |
admitted to violating the antitrust laws directly, but
|
14 |
from a theoretical perspective, that would be a reason
|
15 |
for private antitrust litigation.
|
16 |
Responding to an existing lawsuit and preventing
|
17 |
a hostile takeover are common reasons. These do not
|
18 |
actually have any direct negative effect on competition.
|
19 |
They depend on whether the existing lawsuit was itself
|
20 |
pro or -- procompetitive or not or the existing hostile
|
21 |
takeover, and I would point to those as being in some
|
22 |
sense neutral. Where the antitrust -- where private
|
23 |
suits turn the antitrust laws on their head is when they
|
24 |
discourage the entry of a rival, such as in the Utah Pie
|
25 |
case, or that they prevent a successful firm from |
27
1 |
competing vigorously.
|
2 |
Now, this, of course, is one of Microsoft's
|
3 |
defenses. I am not going to comment on that directly,
|
4 |
but independent service organizations often bring these
|
5 |
suits to prevent manufacturers from offering service and
|
6 |
competing successfully. So, in that sense, they can
|
7 |
quite turn the antitrust laws on their head.
|
8 |
Now, let me turn to some theoretical research.
|
9 |
This is not based on the survey of antitrust suits. The
|
10 |
question is, who has the incentive to actually bring a
|
11 |
private antitrust suit that is, in fact,
|
12 |
anticompetitive? And to assess that, we look at a
|
13 |
procompetitive action. So, this is a cost-reducing
|
14 |
action that will give a firm an advantage in the
|
15 |
marketplace versus an anticompetitive action, so this is
|
16 |
raising your rivals' costs without lowering anyone's
|
17 |
costs, and ask, holding constant the likelihood of
|
18 |
prevailing, who would benefit more from bringing the
|
19 |
suits?
|
20 |
And we actually, in the context of the sort of
|
21 |
standard work horse model, the Cornell model, the
|
22 |
standard economic model that is used most frequently in
|
23 |
antitrust evaluation, we find something I think quite
|
24 |
surprising, which is that it is the small firm in a
|
25 |
dispersed market who actually relatively benefits from |
28
1 |
bringing an antitrust suit that is anticompetitive
|
2 |
relative to a procompetitive suit, and the reason for
|
3 |
this is the loss from a procompetitive rival's action
|
4 |
actually gets larger as the number of firms grows,
|
5 |
whereas the loss from an anticompetitive action
|
6 |
decreases as the number of firms grows, so that in the
|
7 |
limit, it is the small firm and not the large firm who
|
8 |
tends to bring the action.
|
9 |
So, to conclude, antitrust laws are often used
|
10 |
not to encourage competition -- at least private
|
11 |
antitrust suits -- but to reduce the level of
|
12 |
competition. Clearly an outright ban on private
|
13 |
antitrust litigation would solve that problem, but it
|
14 |
may create other problems that are worse. Some
|
15 |
alternatives may actually improve the situation as it
|
16 |
stands today.
|
17 |
One would be a gate-keeper, using government
|
18 |
agencies as a gate-keeper for private litigation, but I
|
19 |
am actually leery of that as a solution mainly because I
|
20 |
judge the EEOC to be a failure as a gate-keeper in
|
21 |
employment, and the gate-keeper model has not worked
|
22 |
very well.
|
23 |
One could also ask the agencies to weigh in on
|
24 |
private litigation, and that may have more of an effect.
|
25 |
Another proposal is to allow for additional support |
29
1 |
beyond what is already created, in particular financial
|
2 |
support for agency litigation. That, of course, risks
|
3 |
capture and so would be a risky strategy for different
|
4 |
reasons. Something that -- modeling in Canada, you have
|
5 |
a -- there is a -- is decoupling the damages from the
|
6 |
awards. It may be that you want to have high damages as
|
7 |
a way of deterring behavior but low awards to reduce the
|
8 |
number of lawsuits, and there are plenty of worthy
|
9 |
agencies who would love to have the difference between
|
10 |
the damages and awards.
|
11 |
And then finally, something that from my own
|
12 |
experience in litigation I would find useful is to
|
13 |
provide experts to the court to reduce the uncertainty
|
14 |
associated with antitrust suits.
|
15 |
Let me conclude with three remarks on deceptive
|
16 |
practices. One is is that not every misleading
|
17 |
statement is intentional. There are many
|
18 |
well-intentioned corporations that make mistakes, and
|
19 |
the law should not have zero tolerance. So, this is in
|
20 |
some sense a counter to remarks of Susan's, that there
|
21 |
is no downside. There are statements that are made.
|
22 |
Generally, if you run a corporation, it is hard to
|
23 |
ensure zero probability of a misleading statement ever
|
24 |
being made. People have -- make errors on occasion.
|
25 |
One of the things I would say about Oliver |
30
1 |
Williamson is that reading Oliver Williamson is very
|
2 |
much like reading the Bible. When you read it
|
3 |
selectively, he provides support for every point of
|
4 |
view.
|
5 |
The second point that I would like to make is
|
6 |
that traditional economic analysis where a market -- and
|
7 |
by that I mean the analysis of antitrust -- where
|
8 |
markets are either monopolies or competitive, is the
|
9 |
sort of general situation, that kind of model is very
|
10 |
poorly suited to evaluating deceptive practices, and
|
11 |
there are lots of -- the problem is, often it is the
|
12 |
case that you can have a large effect on a small number
|
13 |
of people or a small effect on a large number of people,
|
14 |
and then what seems like an inconsequential difference,
|
15 |
so a small compatibility problem which is easily
|
16 |
remedied may still be fatal if it is something that
|
17 |
consumers will not remedy. These are situations where
|
18 |
it is not either a monopoly or a competitive
|
19 |
marketplace, and as a result, we in some sense need to
|
20 |
bring new economic models to the evaluation of deceptive
|
21 |
practices.
|
22 |
And then finally, I also want to say, in my
|
23 |
view, the patent system is broken. The system itself is
|
24 |
anticompetitive. It creates entry barriers. Many firms
|
25 |
cannot enter because -- so, firms with a good idea, who |
31
1 |
have invented a new technology and go and get it
|
2 |
patented, find that because there are many patents that
|
3 |
have some similarities, they are blocked from entry by
|
4 |
existing patent pools. Patent pools, in addition, have
|
5 |
the effect of encouraging collusive conduct.
|
6 |
With a broken patent system -- and this, I
|
7 |
think, echos a point that Susan made -- I do not think
|
8 |
it is appropriate to try to fix the patent system using
|
9 |
the antitrust laws. Instead, it would be desirable to
|
10 |
fix the patent system directly. So, let's craft
|
11 |
antitrust laws that promote competition and a patent
|
12 |
policy that justly rewards the efforts to innovation.
|
13 |
Thank you.
|
14 |
(Applause.)
|
15 |
MR. DAGEN: Our next speaker is Michael
|
16 |
Brockmeyer. He's a partner at Frommer Lawrence & Haug,
|
17 |
where his practice concentrates on antitrust and
|
18 |
consumer protection law with particular emphasis on
|
19 |
intellectual property financing agreements and the
|
20 |
pharmaceutical industry. Before entering private
|
21 |
practice, Michael served as chair of the Multistate
|
22 |
Antitrust Task Force of the National Association of
|
23 |
Attorneys General and was a chief of Maryland's
|
24 |
Antitrust Division. He is a frequent author and
|
25 |
lecturer on antitrust matters, and he is also an Adjunct |
32
1 |
Professor at the University of Maryland School of Law,
|
2 |
teaching antitrust law.
|
3 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Thanks, Rick. Good morning,
|
4 |
everyone.
|
5 |
For my opening remarks this morning, I want to
|
6 |
focus on abusive governmental processes, in particular
|
7 |
with respect to deception in the intellectual property
|
8 |
setting, and then I am going to briefly touch on
|
9 |
tortious conduct.
|
10 |
I find it helpful, however, that before going
|
11 |
into those subjects, we should remind ourselves of
|
12 |
certain basic principles that should apply when we look
|
13 |
at any one of the subjects that we are talking about,
|
14 |
and so, for example, and what we take for granted today
|
15 |
I would assume, everyone, that aggressive competition on
|
16 |
the merits serves consumer welfare. Even if done by a
|
17 |
monopolist, competition on the merits is not
|
18 |
exclusionary. If we do not permit that, then we deprive
|
19 |
consumers the benefit of that competition.
|
20 |
Now, that is a principle that has become well
|
21 |
accepted in antitrust law, but we must remember that
|
22 |
that principle is not one that necessarily underlies
|
23 |
certain state laws that deal with deception or tortious
|
24 |
conduct.
|
25 |
The antitrust laws should not provide a remedy |
33
1 |
for conduct that violates the common law or another
|
2 |
statutory scheme and injures individual competitors
|
3 |
unless the conduct substantially harms the competitive
|
4 |
process. In my view, such conduct that violates the
|
5 |
common law or another statutory scheme is not
|
6 |
competition on the merits, but the question is, is
|
7 |
whether often the conduct is sufficient enough to say
|
8 |
that it harms the competitive process.
|
9 |
In my view, the principle should be that that
|
10 |
conduct substantially harms the competitive process when
|
11 |
it allows, permits, durable pricing above competitive
|
12 |
levels or there exists a dangerous probability that such
|
13 |
supra-competitive pricing will occur. In my view, when
|
14 |
you have this sort of conduct, the competitors, the
|
15 |
injured competitor, cannot be passive. The competitor
|
16 |
must have attempted to counteract, must have done so in
|
17 |
a reasonable manner evaluated in the context of what
|
18 |
would be a competitive market, and again, the harm
|
19 |
should be measured in the context of ability to price
|
20 |
above competitive levels.
|
21 |
When deciding whether that conduct is
|
22 |
exclusionary, that is, giving rise to a Section 2 claim,
|
23 |
I believe that it is essential that deciding whether
|
24 |
there is substantial harm to the competitive process
|
25 |
must be undertaken first before any balancing against |
34
1 |
any procompetitive justification, much as what Susan
|
2 |
said, it is very difficult for much of this conduct to
|
3 |
have a "procompetitive justification."
|
4 |
The concern from a principles standpoint is if
|
5 |
you quickly, say under a Microsoft type analysis,
|
6 |
shifted the burden for procompetitive justification and
|
7 |
there was none, you may end up penalizing under the
|
8 |
antitrust laws tortious conduct that does not
|
9 |
substantially harm the competitive process.
|
10 |
Finally, when a monopolist's exclusionary
|
11 |
conduct is subject to another regulatory scheme designed
|
12 |
to promote competition, the antitrust laws should
|
13 |
provide a remedy for such conduct only after taking into
|
14 |
account the structure of the market and the significance
|
15 |
of the regulatory scheme to the workings of the market.
|
16 |
This is going to be particularly important when we are
|
17 |
talking about Hatch-Waxman, as Preston was talking about
|
18 |
in the patent arena, or even one explanation for
|
19 |
Conwood, because we must remember that because there are
|
20 |
virtual bans on advertising, the conduct there was such
|
21 |
that it was difficult for Conwood to counteract the
|
22 |
activity because it could not do so by traditional
|
23 |
advertising in the regulatory scheme that we have with
|
24 |
respect to tobacco advertising prohibited that.
|
25 |
With that, let me now first go to abuse of the |
35
1 |
government processes through deception, and the first,
|
2 |
of course, is Walker Process, and in the 41 or so years
|
3 |
since Walker Process was decided, much has been said
|
4 |
about Walker Process, and the issue with, of course,
|
5 |
Walker Process is that we start with the principle that
|
6 |
the patentee is immune from antitrust liability
|
7 |
generally when the patentee seeks to enforce its patent,
|
8 |
and so the question in Walker Process was, when would we
|
9 |
remove that immunity, and the Court said, well, when
|
10 |
there was fraud on the Patent Office, and if there was
|
11 |
fraud on the Patent Office, there was not then a per se
|
12 |
violation of the antitrust laws.
|
13 |
Indeed, when I read the opinion again, I believe
|
14 |
the Antitrust Division or -- I do not know whether the
|
15 |
Federal Trade Commission joined -- actually had urged
|
16 |
the per se rule, which the Court rejected there; that
|
17 |
is, that once fraud on the Patent Office is shown, the
|
18 |
plaintiff merely is now in the door and has to show
|
19 |
other -- an otherwise violation of the antitrust laws.
|
20 |
I believe the importance of Walker Process,
|
21 |
however, is Justice Harlan's concurrence, and in
|
22 |
particular, he wanted to make clear that this was not
|
23 |
going to open the door or should not open the door for
|
24 |
all sorts of plaintiffs' suits where a patent is found
|
25 |
to be unenforceable or otherwise invalid, and thus, he |
36
1 |
concluded that the private antitrust remedy, which the
|
2 |
Court was allowing as a result of the Walker Process
|
3 |
case, should not be deemed available to reach Section 2
|
4 |
monopolies carried on under a nonfraudulently procured
|
5 |
patent.
|
6 |
Well, when we think about that sentence, I want
|
7 |
to remind you on a little bit of history. Noerr had
|
8 |
been decided prior to Walker Process, but California
|
9 |
Transport had not. California Transport comes six or
|
10 |
seven years after Walker Process, and so we end up in a
|
11 |
situation where -- and let me just sort of finish with
|
12 |
Walker Process for a moment -- that with Walker Process,
|
13 |
the standard is if you do have fraud on the Patent
|
14 |
Office, it is exclusionary conduct actionable under
|
15 |
Section 2 on the assumption that the patentee otherwise
|
16 |
possesses monopoly power or there is a dangerous
|
17 |
probability that the patentee will obtain monopoly
|
18 |
power.
|
19 |
One area where I would disagree with the Federal
|
20 |
Circuit, the Federal Circuit has said that in order to
|
21 |
bring a Walker Process case, there must have been
|
22 |
enforcement of the patent before the claim can be
|
23 |
brought. In my view, Walker Process, if there has been
|
24 |
fraud on the Patent Office, a Walker Process claim
|
25 |
should be available even if the monopolist patentee has |
37
1 |
not attempted to enforce its patent. Now, I understand
|
2 |
that in virtually all circumstances, knowledge of the
|
3 |
claim and ability to bring the claim will be in the
|
4 |
context of either a counterclaim or where there has been
|
5 |
a cease and desist or some other letter, a declaratory
|
6 |
judgment action being brought, such that there has been
|
7 |
either actual or attempted enforcement. The difficulty
|
8 |
is that there are circumstances -- and this goes a
|
9 |
little bit to Preston's point, I believe -- where
|
10 |
someone will come and ask for a review of the current
|
11 |
patent law or current state of intellectual property, an
|
12 |
opinion by a law firm may be given to say, well, your
|
13 |
particular process will infringe. There is not
|
14 |
knowledge of the fraud on the Patent Office, and someone
|
15 |
who would otherwise come to market may not come to
|
16 |
market simply because that firm does not want to risk
|
17 |
the disruption of an enforcement action by the patentee
|
18 |
who has procured the patent by fraud. So, in my view,
|
19 |
the standard should not be one where Walker Process is
|
20 |
available only when there is enforcement.
|
21 |
Back to where I was going with Justice Harlan,
|
22 |
and the question becomes this, and something that I am
|
23 |
seeing in my practice, is where there is an allegation
|
24 |
that a patent is unenforceable by reason of inequitable
|
25 |
conduct before the Patent Office. Now, where there is |
38
1 |
inequitable conduct, there is intent, there is
|
2 |
materiality, there is a weighing, but the basic issuance
|
3 |
of the patent is not in issue; that is, in a Walker
|
4 |
Process, where there is fraud, the patent is void ab
|
5 |
initio, where that is not the case with respect to
|
6 |
inequitable conduct. And here, in the Noble Pharma
|
7 |
case, the Federal Circuit distinguished between in the
|
8 |
case Walker Process fraud and inequitable conduct, and
|
9 |
the key for that distinction is in a Walker Process
|
10 |
fraud, there must be a fraud on the Patent Office, and
|
11 |
but for the fraud, the patent would not issue.
|
12 |
In my view -- and my time is getting short --
|
13 |
the problem is that where there is inequitable conduct,
|
14 |
there is often then a claim of sham litigation; that is,
|
15 |
that the litigation is brought with the patentee knowing
|
16 |
that its patent is unenforceable by reason of the
|
17 |
inequitable conduct. In my view, the standard there
|
18 |
should be one where the litigation must be sham, that
|
19 |
is, meeting the PRE test, and the sham litigation itself
|
20 |
must have substantially harmed the litigation; that is,
|
21 |
the focus of the inquiry should be on the sham
|
22 |
litigation and not the patentee's conduct before the
|
23 |
Patent Office.
|
24 |
Let me very quickly go to the issue of listings
|
25 |
on the Orange Book. The Orange Book, as many of you may |
39
1 |
know, created under the Hatch-Waxman Act, a brand will
|
2 |
list those patents that cover the branded drugs which it
|
3 |
is marketing, and as we also know that the FDA plays
|
4 |
only a ministerial act, meaning it lists what is
|
5 |
presented to it.
|
6 |
One point that I want to make is that listing in
|
7 |
the Orange Book does have procompetitive attributes.
|
8 |
While listing in the Orange Book means that when a
|
9 |
generic sues, that there is a 30-month stay before the
|
10 |
generic can -- its ANDA can be approved by the FDA, it
|
11 |
also has a procompetitive attribute because it will
|
12 |
encourage the generics to sue because of the 180
|
13 |
exclusive for the first to file. So, we must be mindful
|
14 |
that listings in the Orange Book do have procompetitive
|
15 |
attributes, and where the FTC has sued in BristolMyers
|
16 |
and Biovale, in both of those circumstances, the
|
17 |
allegation was, in the case of BMS, it knew or could not
|
18 |
have reasonably believed that the listing was
|
19 |
appropriate or that Biovale was aware that the patent it
|
20 |
listed did not cover the drug that it marketed.
|
21 |
In Organon, I will pass through this, there is a
|
22 |
suit that said the court had no antitrust liability,
|
23 |
because Arganon had a reasonable basis for submission on
|
24 |
its patent in the Orange Book.
|
25 |
In my view, the standard should be that |
40
1 |
something may be actionable exclusionary conduct under
|
2 |
Section 2 only when the decision to list the patent was
|
3 |
objectively baseless; that is, the test on whether to
|
4 |
list should be objective, and it should be looking to
|
5 |
where the brand could have reasonably believed that the
|
6 |
listed patent could be asserted against a generic that a
|
7 |
manufacturer would want to bring to the market.
|
8 |
Finally, on the tortious conduct, in my view, a
|
9 |
monopolist's misleading and deceptive tortious conduct
|
10 |
that's illegal in common law or another regulatory
|
11 |
scheme could be treated, may be treated, as
|
12 |
exclusionary, but only when the conduct is
|
13 |
institutional, pervasive and substantially harms the
|
14 |
competitive process.
|
15 |
Institutional, to me, goes to the question that
|
16 |
Preston raised of mistakes. This must be one where the
|
17 |
company has purposefully looked to undertake a campaign
|
18 |
that involves misleading and deceptive conduct. It must
|
19 |
be pervasive, that is, you measure it in the context of
|
20 |
the relevant geographic market. We have to, you know,
|
21 |
deal with the rogue employee who may be engaged in some
|
22 |
tortious conduct in some area, but we should not visit
|
23 |
antitrust liability.
|
24 |
It must impair the competitive process, and
|
25 |
finally, as has been suggested, in my view, there should |
41
1 |
be no rebuttable de minimus presumption -- I know there
|
2 |
has been the suggestion in several -- I believe the
|
3 |
Sixth and the Ninth Circuits have adopted the notion of
|
4 |
a de minimus rebuttable presumption. I believe there
|
5 |
should not be one. The plaintiff in my view has the
|
6 |
initial burden, the initial burden being to present a
|
7 |
prima facie case of substantial harm to competition.
|
8 |
Thank you.
|
9 |
(Applause.)
|
10 |
MR. DAGEN: Our next speaker is Richard Rozek.
|
11 |
He is a senior vice president at NERA Economic
|
12 |
Consulting. After starting his career as an Assistant
|
13 |
Professor at the University of Pittsburgh, Richard
|
14 |
worked for over six years in the Bureau of Economics at
|
15 |
the Federal Trade Commission in a series of senior staff
|
16 |
positions, including Deputy Assistant Director for
|
17 |
Antitrust. Since joining NERA in 1987, Dr. Rozek has
|
18 |
worked on projects affecting many different industries,
|
19 |
including the pharmaceutical industry. His work has
|
20 |
appeared in a number of journals.
|
21 |
Richard?
|
22 |
DR. ROZEK: Well, I want to thank Pat
|
23 |
Schultheiss for inviting me to come here and talk today
|
24 |
about the pharmaceutical industry. It is an industry
|
25 |
that I spend a fair amount of my time studying, and the |
42
1 |
work I do at NERA is focused on the pharmaceutical
|
2 |
industry as well as other industries, but I want to
|
3 |
begin by summarizing some of the interesting
|
4 |
characteristics or structural characteristics of the
|
5 |
industry that make it so interesting to study. Not only
|
6 |
that, we live in a world with laws regarding patents,
|
7 |
copyrights, trademarks and trade secrets that along with
|
8 |
the effective enforcement mechanisms have contributed
|
9 |
substantially to economic growth and development in the
|
10 |
United States. Nowhere is this effect of the
|
11 |
intellectual property laws more pronounced than in the
|
12 |
health care industry, specifically for pharmaceuticals.
|
13 |
Innovators in the pharmaceutical industry invest
|
14 |
hundreds of millions of dollars in research and
|
15 |
development or R&D for new medicines that address unmet
|
16 |
medical needs. Conducting R&D and obtaining approval
|
17 |
from the U.S. Food and Drug Administration or FDA to
|
18 |
sell a new medicine as a safe, effective treatment for a
|
19 |
particular disease usually requires 10 to 15 years of
|
20 |
research. Many research projects actually fail and do
|
21 |
not even result in the innovators submitting a new drug
|
22 |
application to the FDA.
|
23 |
For the few successful projects, the innovator
|
24 |
has, at the end of that 15-year period, a patent that
|
25 |
gives it exclusivity, not to be confused with monopoly |
43
1 |
power, for components of the product. The patent may be
|
2 |
a composition of matter, may be a process, may be a
|
3 |
method of use. Also, the innovator has a new drug
|
4 |
application approved by the FDA as a result of that R&D
|
5 |
investment, but there is no guarantee that the product
|
6 |
will be commercially successful.
|
7 |
The innovator must manufacture and distribute
|
8 |
the product. The innovator must inform patients,
|
9 |
physicians, pharmacists, and payers about the
|
10 |
therapeutic benefits of the improved product. He must
|
11 |
negotiate prices with specific payers, both public and
|
12 |
private. And in the end, many pharmaceutical products
|
13 |
may not even generate sufficient revenues to justify
|
14 |
their investment. Those products that are successful
|
15 |
provide resources in terms of retained earnings for the
|
16 |
innovator to fund its ongoing R&D efforts. So that if
|
17 |
we want to have cures for such medical problems as AIDS,
|
18 |
Alzheimer's disease, and cancer in our lifetime, we must
|
19 |
have public policy that provides the incentives for
|
20 |
innovators to invest resources in pharmaceutical R&D and
|
21 |
continue the work to solve these unmet medical problems.
|
22 |
Now, there have been some concerns raised about
|
23 |
practices that innovators engage in near the end of the
|
24 |
patent lives for their products, such issues as filing a
|
25 |
Citizen's Petition with the FDA, introducing new, |
44
1 |
improved versions of their products based on the
|
2 |
original chemicals, settling patent infringement cases,
|
3 |
introducing generic versions of their original branded
|
4 |
products, sometimes referred to as introducing an
|
5 |
authorized generic. These practices and others that we
|
6 |
have heard about today with regard to Orange Book
|
7 |
listings and so on, have been the focus of antitrust
|
8 |
scrutiny that the pharmaceutical industry has been
|
9 |
receiving.
|
10 |
This policy debate on whether or not these
|
11 |
practices are legitimate or the incentives to engage in
|
12 |
these practices somehow be altered are guided more by
|
13 |
emotion, rather than analyses that demonstrate that
|
14 |
there is actual harm to consumer welfare from these
|
15 |
practices. As a matter of fact, there are many
|
16 |
beneficial effects from these practices that often are
|
17 |
not the focus of the debate.
|
18 |
For example, filing a Citizen's Petition with
|
19 |
the FDA makes the FDA aware of scientific or public
|
20 |
health questions regarding its efforts to approve
|
21 |
additional products. Introducing a combination product
|
22 |
that combines two active ingredients or an extended
|
23 |
release product can actually provide benefits to
|
24 |
patients, increase compliance one pill instead of two.
|
25 |
Actually, for insured patients, it can result in lower |
45
1 |
co-payments. You have to buy a single pill, pay one
|
2 |
co-payment, instead of take two pills and make two
|
3 |
co-payments, so there can be a cost-reducing benefit.
|
4 |
Settling a patent case can reduce litigation
|
5 |
costs and can actually, in some cases, provide
|
6 |
additional entry into a marketplace. Introducing an
|
7 |
authorized generic product into the marketplace can
|
8 |
obviously increase competition. So, you see that there
|
9 |
are benefits to the practices that have been the subject
|
10 |
of these challenges, and there appears, on the other
|
11 |
hand, to be a lack of evidence that these actions harm
|
12 |
consumers.
|
13 |
Instead of talking about these types of
|
14 |
actions collectively, I'll talk about the authorized
|
15 |
generic issue, which has been the subject of some
|
16 |
debate. There has actually been legislation proposed
|
17 |
addressing authorized generics. There have been some
|
18 |
court decisions related to authorized generics and so
|
19 |
on. Most recently, to spur the debate, the Supreme
|
20 |
Court refused to hear the FTC appeal of the
|
21 |
Schering-Plough case. The Court of Appeals for the
|
22 |
Second Circuit denied a consumer group's request for a
|
23 |
rehearing in the Tamoxifen matter that involved Astra
|
24 |
Zeneca and Barr settling a patent case. Bruce Downey,
|
25 |
the Chairman and CEO of Barr, said in response to the |
46
1 |
Court of Appeals' decision, "We are pleased that our
|
2 |
patent challenge settlement related to Tamoxifen citrate
|
3 |
has been upheld as being pro-consumer and
|
4 |
pro-competition."
|
5 |
In spite of these court decisions and in spite
|
6 |
of the benefits to competition from introduction of an
|
7 |
authorized generic, the argument has been that
|
8 |
introducing an authorized generic is inconsistent with
|
9 |
the intent of the Drug Price Competition and Patent
|
10 |
Restoration Act of 1984, sometimes referred to as the
|
11 |
Hatch-Waxman Act. Specifically, the threat to launch an
|
12 |
authorized generic reduces the incentives provided to
|
13 |
generic companies to challenge patents listed in the
|
14 |
Orange Book and, thus, will reduce the number of future
|
15 |
generic alternatives.
|
16 |
Now, the problem is that there is no evidence
|
17 |
that the number of generic alternatives will be reduced
|
18 |
or that there are a lack of profit opportunities or
|
19 |
entry opportunities for generic firms. The Hatch-Waxman
|
20 |
Act actually encourages both innovation to solve those
|
21 |
unmet medical problems and competition or imitation by
|
22 |
sellers after patent expiration. It has generally been
|
23 |
a success because it has struck this balance between
|
24 |
innovation and imitation, and restricting options
|
25 |
available under the Hatch-Waxman Act to encourage |
47
1 |
innovation, to destroy the incentives to develop new and
|
2 |
improved medicines, will actually harm patients,
|
3 |
physicians, pharmacists, and payers.
|
4 |
Now, some of the entry opportunities that
|
5 |
exist -- and this should be of interest to the antitrust
|
6 |
community as well, because it is an issue that is a key
|
7 |
part of any antitrust inquiry -- is what are the entry
|
8 |
conditions into a marketplace? Is entry encouraged or
|
9 |
discouraged by certain actions? Well, the presence of
|
10 |
authorized generics, for example, actually creates new
|
11 |
entrants into the pharmaceutical marketplace. Obviously
|
12 |
innovator companies now have an opportunity to introduce
|
13 |
an authorized generic and enter that component of the
|
14 |
industry, as companies such as Pfizer, Novartis and
|
15 |
Schering-Plough have done. Pfizer has its generic
|
16 |
entity, Greenstone, Novartis has its generic affiliate,
|
17 |
Sandoz, and Schering-Plough has Warrick. These are
|
18 |
firms that now sell generic products. So, innovator
|
19 |
companies are entering the generic marketplace.
|
20 |
Companies that have traditionally been in the
|
21 |
generic marketplace and have launched their own generic
|
22 |
products or independent generics have also been involved
|
23 |
in participating in the authorized generic portion of
|
24 |
the industry. Mylan, Barr, Par, Watson, Ivax/Teva,
|
25 |
which is now a single firm, have all sold authorized |
48
1 |
generic forms of drugs under licenses from the innovator
|
2 |
varieties. Barr, a company that actually derives most
|
3 |
of its revenues from sales of generic drugs, has a few
|
4 |
branded products as well, and it recently launched an
|
5 |
authorized generic version of its brand oral
|
6 |
contraceptive product Seasonale after Watson, a generic
|
7 |
company, launched a generic version of the product.
|
8 |
Bruce Downey, again, said, quote, "It is our obligation
|
9 |
to preserve our rightful interest in this product." So,
|
10 |
you see, even the generic companies see the benefit of
|
11 |
launching authorized generics when they do expand into
|
12 |
the brand or innovator segment of the industry.
|
13 |
Some firms have arisen to sell authorized
|
14 |
generics only. For example, Prasco is a firm that
|
15 |
currently sells authorized generic versions of seven
|
16 |
branded products. It is a privately held company. It
|
17 |
was created because of the opportunities presented to
|
18 |
the marketplace by this ability to sell authorized
|
19 |
generic products.
|
20 |
I have seen various estimates of the value of
|
21 |
the patented products coming off patent in the next two
|
22 |
or three years, and it could easily exceed $27 billion
|
23 |
in 2007 and $29 billion in 2008. So, the point is that
|
24 |
there are profit opportunities in the generic industry
|
25 |
with authorized generics in the marketplace as well. |
49
1 |
So, the new entrants have emerged, and future profit
|
2 |
opportunities exist.
|
3 |
The issue remains, however, what is the role for
|
4 |
antitrust policy versus competitive forces in this
|
5 |
industry? Where in the industry should antitrust policy
|
6 |
be focused? Should it be focused at the manufacturer
|
7 |
level? Should it be focused at the retail level?
|
8 |
Should it be focused at the distribution level? There
|
9 |
are fundamental questions with regard to using antitrust
|
10 |
policy to address issues in the pharmaceutical industry.
|
11 |
I think there have been several mistakes in the current
|
12 |
application of the antitrust laws to the pharmaceutical
|
13 |
industry, broadly defined as this vertical chain from
|
14 |
research through distribution of the products to
|
15 |
patients.
|
16 |
One is that market definitions are often too
|
17 |
narrow in this industry from an antitrust perspective.
|
18 |
Market definitions that use a single chemical as the
|
19 |
appropriate defining characteristic of a market,
|
20 |
overlook the therapeutic competition that exists in the
|
21 |
pharmaceutical industry, competition between chemical
|
22 |
entities, Avandia competes with Actos, Fosamax competes
|
23 |
with Actonel, ear tubes compete with antibiotics for
|
24 |
treating otitis media. There is a lot of competition
|
25 |
that's overlooked by taking the static view that it's |
50
1 |
only a single chemical constitues a relevant market.
|
2 |
Well, a fundamental flaw in current antitrust, taking a
|
3 |
too narrow view of the market, not realizing the
|
4 |
therapeutic competition, competition across therapies,
|
5 |
be they pharmaceutical or surgical procedures.
|
6 |
Taking that narrow view of market definition
|
7 |
causes decisions to be made that monopolies exist when,
|
8 |
in fact, they do not, you see.
|
9 |
Another flaw is taking a static, as opposed to a
|
10 |
dynamic, view of the market when you have a market
|
11 |
environment characterized by high expenditures in R&D
|
12 |
and new products emerging from research being done
|
13 |
within U.S. laboratories, UK laboratories, Japanese
|
14 |
laboratories, and even in other countries, such as India
|
15 |
and Argentina and Brazil, countries that are developing
|
16 |
and have recently improved their protection for
|
17 |
intellectual property.
|
18 |
Competitive forces are working in health care
|
19 |
markets, and I think a greater reliance on allowing
|
20 |
these competitive forces to work as opposed to
|
21 |
intervening too early with antitrust enforcement is a
|
22 |
better solution for everyone concerned. What we need to
|
23 |
do is to convince consumers that shopping for
|
24 |
pharmaceutical products, such as they do for other
|
25 |
consumer goods, is a good idea. We have to induce more |
51
1 |
of a shopping or a searching procedure for the lowest
|
2 |
pharmaceutical prices.
|
3 |
I recently conducted with one of my colleagues a
|
4 |
survey of pharmacies in Crystal City, Virginia to
|
5 |
purchase the product albuterol, which is an asthma
|
6 |
treatment. We found that in a narrow geographic region
|
7 |
within Crystal City, Virginia, the price of a canister
|
8 |
of albuterol ranged from $8.19 to $26.49. We found out
|
9 |
this information just by calling the pharmacy and asking
|
10 |
them how much a canister of albuterol would cost. There
|
11 |
is often a significant difference in price, which you
|
12 |
can find out by just calling before you even go to the
|
13 |
pharmacy with your prescription.
|
14 |
WalMart recently announced a pilot program to
|
15 |
sell generic pharmaceutical products for $4 a
|
16 |
prescription. K-Mart is offering a 90-day supply of a
|
17 |
prescription for $15. The market is responding to the
|
18 |
need to control health care costs.
|
19 |
So, in conclusion, I want to say that innovators
|
20 |
in the pharmaceutical industry obtain patents and
|
21 |
regulatory approval in the U.S. They are subject to the
|
22 |
general U.S. antitrust laws, as are all companies, and
|
23 |
additional specialized rules, such as the Hatch-Waxman
|
24 |
Act, that strikes a balance between innovation and
|
25 |
imitation. This structure creates the incentives for |
52
1 |
both innovators and imitators to develop, manufacture
|
2 |
and sell their products. To preserve the gains from
|
3 |
both types of activities, public policy, including
|
4 |
antitrust, should focus on maintaining a business
|
5 |
environment that allows innovators and imitators the
|
6 |
most effective means to manage their product life cycles
|
7 |
under the existing system.
|
8 |
In the case of innovators introducing authorized
|
9 |
generics and the other activities I described earlier,
|
10 |
competition has increased and new entrants have emerged.
|
11 |
Patients have had access to established therapies and to
|
12 |
new therapies, and they have the mechanism in place to
|
13 |
assure that research will be done on therapies to meet
|
14 |
unmet medical needs in the future.
|
15 |
With regard to the pharmaceutical industry, a
|
16 |
reliance on competitive forces rather than a stepped-up
|
17 |
antitrust policy that has focused on static analysis
|
18 |
under narrow market definitions holds greater promise
|
19 |
for controlling health care costs in the future.
|
20 |
Thank you.
|
21 |
(Applause.)
|
22 |
MR. DAGEN: Before we proceed to our last two
|
23 |
speakers, we will take about a ten-minute break. When
|
24 |
we come back, we will hear from Gil Ohana and George
|
25 |
Cary and then go directly from their presentations into |
53
1 |
our round table discussion. Thank you.
|
2 |
(A brief recess was taken.)
|
3 |
MR. DAGEN: Okay, welcome back, everybody. We
|
4 |
have two speakers remaining, and after their
|
5 |
presentations we will follow with the round table
|
6 |
discussion.
|
7 |
Gil Ohana is Director of Antitrust and
|
8 |
Competition for Cisco Systems, a leading manufacturer of
|
9 |
networking equipment for the internet. He writes and
|
10 |
speaks regularly on licensing, standard-setting, patent
|
11 |
pools and other subjects at the intersection of
|
12 |
antitrust and intellectual property law. Before joining
|
13 |
Cisco, Gil was a trial attorney at the Antitrust
|
14 |
Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, specializing
|
15 |
in antitrust issues in high technology industries.
|
16 |
Gil?
|
17 |
MR. OHANA: Thank you, Richard, and thanks to
|
18 |
the Justice Department and the FTC for the opportunity
|
19 |
to speak today.
|
20 |
Susan Creighton earlier used the term "network
|
21 |
industries." I am in the networking industry, and in
|
22 |
the networking industry, something the customers care
|
23 |
about a lot is that networking products work together
|
24 |
well and the way that we make sure they work together
|
25 |
well is largely by participation in standard-setting. |
54
1 |
So, we're very proud of the leading role that we've
|
2 |
played in developing standards that many of you use
|
3 |
every day, whether or not you realize it. To give some
|
4 |
examples, 802.3, which is the ethernet standard; 802.11,
|
5 |
which is the WIFI standard; TCPIP, which is the basic
|
6 |
transmission control protocol on which the internet
|
7 |
runs.
|
8 |
We also sell every year billions of dollars of
|
9 |
products that implement a wide variety of industry
|
10 |
standards, so both from the standpoint of participation
|
11 |
in standards development, from the standpoint of
|
12 |
implementation of standards in commercial products, we
|
13 |
are passionately interested in a transparent standards
|
14 |
development process. What do I mean by that? I mean a
|
15 |
process that values intellectual property rights but
|
16 |
that also recognizes, as the Justice Department did in
|
17 |
the Vita letter, that the incorporation of a patent into
|
18 |
a standard may confer on that patent significant market
|
19 |
power and that, therefore, the decision to incorporate
|
20 |
the patent into a standard should be made knowingly with
|
21 |
access to the best information that is available at the
|
22 |
time.
|
23 |
The deceptive practices in standards
|
24 |
development, therefore, run contrary to our interests.
|
25 |
They reduce our incentives to participate in standards |
55
1 |
development, and they reduce our confidence that the
|
2 |
products we ship will not infringe or that if they do
|
3 |
infringe that we will be able to address the
|
4 |
infringement with a payment of reasonable licensing
|
5 |
fees.
|
6 |
I'd like to preface my remarks with a quote from
|
7 |
Justice Brennan in the Allied Tube case that I am sure
|
8 |
many of you have seen before. Historically, the
|
9 |
antitrust scrutiny that Justice Brennan referred to was
|
10 |
really around Section 1. More recently, the FTC in
|
11 |
particular has brought a number of cases involving
|
12 |
Section 2 issues in standards development, as we all
|
13 |
know. What I'd like to talk about today is those cases
|
14 |
without getting deeply into the facts of any of them and
|
15 |
make a few points about them.
|
16 |
First of all, to suggest that despite the title
|
17 |
of today's discussion, when we talk about deception, we
|
18 |
really ought to be talking about exploitation and not
|
19 |
deception. Second, that if you situate deception in the
|
20 |
broader panoply of Section 2, you come up with some
|
21 |
interesting conclusions, and I think Susan touched on
|
22 |
these earlier, regarding whether the risk of
|
23 |
over-enforcement operates as strongly in the context of
|
24 |
deception in standards development cases as it does in
|
25 |
Section 2 cases more generally. And last, I'd like to |
56
1 |
comment on, since I am here in an event hosted by the
|
2 |
Justice Department and the FTC, I'll abuse a privilege
|
3 |
of being here by talking about how I feel the agencies
|
4 |
can best address issues of deceptions in standards
|
5 |
development, and I'll give you a hint, it's not just
|
6 |
about bringing cases.
|
7 |
I won't spend long on this slide. Here are some
|
8 |
examples all drawn from recent FTC decisions or
|
9 |
investigations involving deception in standards
|
10 |
development, and as the cases suggest, there are a fair
|
11 |
number of fact patterns -- I didn't, for example, deal
|
12 |
with government standard-setting here, the Orange Book
|
13 |
cases, et cetera, but there are a fair number of fact
|
14 |
patterns just in classic tech industry standards
|
15 |
development.
|
16 |
So, to unite the theory, I thought about a kind
|
17 |
of way of defining the issue, which is that it is a
|
18 |
patentee's exploitation of monopoly power that results
|
19 |
from the success of a standard for which their patent is
|
20 |
essential, where that power is created by actions that
|
21 |
run contrary to the rules or shared expectations of the
|
22 |
participants in standards development.
|
23 |
I'd like to focus on two parts of that
|
24 |
definition. The first is exploitation of monopoly
|
25 |
power, and the second is resulting from the success of |
57
1 |
the standard.
|
2 |
First of all, on exploitation of monopoly power,
|
3 |
it seems to me that the analytical weakness of just
|
4 |
focusing on deception is that you are really missing
|
5 |
what matters, which is not the deceptive act itself, but
|
6 |
the exploitation of the market power that that creates.
|
7 |
Let me offer an example, as they say, ripped from the
|
8 |
headlines, though it is a situation that people in the
|
9 |
networking industry are aware of, as I think are some
|
10 |
people in this building.
|
11 |
The hypothetical is, a patent holder discloses a
|
12 |
patent in patent standards development, it offers to
|
13 |
license the patent for fully paid up $1 royalty, give me
|
14 |
a buck, use all you want. The patent holder then sells
|
15 |
the patent to someone else. The buyer buys the patent
|
16 |
without knowledge of the prior licensing commitment,
|
17 |
let's assume. The buyer begins to assert the patent
|
18 |
against companies implementing the standard, which by
|
19 |
now has enjoyed a great deal of success, and you won't
|
20 |
be surprised to learn that the successor is asking for
|
21 |
more than a dollar. The rules of the standards
|
22 |
development organization at the time did not
|
23 |
specifically require that licensing commitments made in
|
24 |
the context of the standards development effort, in
|
25 |
fact, bound successors, but if you ask people who |
58
1 |
participate in the standards development effort, that
|
2 |
would certainly be their expectation.
|
3 |
What was the deception here? Well, there really
|
4 |
wasn't any. The successor was quite up front about what
|
5 |
they were doing. The initial patent holder did not
|
6 |
deceive anyone, the successor did not deceive anyone, so
|
7 |
where is the deception? It seems to me that what you
|
8 |
are really focusing on here is the exploitation, and the
|
9 |
exploitation begins at the moment that the successor
|
10 |
becomes aware of the past licensing commitment and the
|
11 |
consensus within the standards development effort that,
|
12 |
in fact, it would bind the successor as well. At that
|
13 |
point, failure to withdraw the claim and seek only the
|
14 |
one dollar royalty is I guess deceptive conduct, though
|
15 |
it seems to me more to be exploitative conduct.
|
16 |
Now, note in this case, the deception and the
|
17 |
exploitation essentially merged into one in the matter
|
18 |
of the standpoint of timing. In cases like Rambus and
|
19 |
BroadCom, obviously there is a much longer time period
|
20 |
between when deception occurs and when the exercise of
|
21 |
monopoly power will occur, thereby exemplifying the
|
22 |
point that the two may be different, they may be the
|
23 |
same, but in any case, what you want to worry about is
|
24 |
the second, not the first.
|
25 |
Listening to some of the discussion this morning |
59
1 |
made me think of another reason why you want to focus on
|
2 |
exploitation rather than deception. It is the question
|
3 |
of inadvertent deception. Deception may very well be
|
4 |
inadvertent, and it is particularly true in the
|
5 |
standard-setting context. Where the rules of standards
|
6 |
development organizations are not clear, people can make
|
7 |
innocent mistakes. Exploitation is never inadvertent.
|
8 |
Let's move on to the second phrase I'd like to
|
9 |
talk about, the phrase resulting from the success of the
|
10 |
standard. Here we come to a significant difference
|
11 |
between the FTC's series of standards cases and what
|
12 |
I'll call kind of classic Justice Department monopoly
|
13 |
maintenance cases, AT&T, IBM, Microsoft, all of which
|
14 |
involve durable monopoly power and raise the question
|
15 |
and the understandable concern that what you should
|
16 |
really be worried about is the risk of false positives,
|
17 |
because in those cases, you are dealing with a
|
18 |
successful company, and you have got to tease out, a
|
19 |
pretty difficult analytical task, tease out specific
|
20 |
exclusionary conduct from what made that company
|
21 |
successful as a general matter. That's not easy to do,
|
22 |
a risk that I am sure many of you have seen the Learned
|
23 |
Hand quote that captured this.
|
24 |
Now, the question I would like to pose is under
|
25 |
what circumstances can you be sure that the deceiver in |
60
1 |
a standards deception case is or is not what Learned
|
2 |
Hand would call the successful competitor? It seems to
|
3 |
me that in deception cases, the conduct and market power
|
4 |
elements of monopolization may focus on different
|
5 |
subjects. In other words, you may be worried about or
|
6 |
you may be focusing on different actors. Certainly you
|
7 |
would be focusing on whether the act of deception was
|
8 |
anticompetitive and then whether it lacked business
|
9 |
justification, but you would also be focusing not on
|
10 |
whether the deceiver gained monopoly power through its
|
11 |
actions, but whether the standard gained monopoly power,
|
12 |
and the standard may have gained monopoly power for
|
13 |
reasons that have very little to do with the underlying
|
14 |
deception.
|
15 |
In that sense, the risk of over-enforcement is
|
16 |
lowest when, first of all, the undisclosed intellectual
|
17 |
property right was not core to the success of the
|
18 |
standard. It was, in other words, nice to have. Now,
|
19 |
this isn't an argument for counting patents. The fact
|
20 |
that the undisclosed patent was one patent out of fifty
|
21 |
or a hundred or a thousand should not be dispositive,
|
22 |
because all patents are not created equal, but the other
|
23 |
thing you should think about is, what were the rejected
|
24 |
substitutes? First of all, did they exist? Second,
|
25 |
were they close? And third, can you say with some |
61
1 |
degree of assurance that they would have been selected
|
2 |
absent the deception?
|
3 |
Now, that may not be the easy inquiry, but it is
|
4 |
a whole lot easier than figuring out whether per
|
5 |
processor licensing was the source of Microsoft's
|
6 |
vertical monopoly in operating systems in 1984. It is a
|
7 |
whole lot easier than figuring out whether lease
|
8 |
practices were the reason that IBM enjoyed a leading
|
9 |
position in mainframes for quite so long.
|
10 |
First of all, the time period is very
|
11 |
compressed. In the facts of the Rambus case, the period
|
12 |
in which Rambus gained monopoly power through the
|
13 |
insertion of its patents in JEDEC and competitive
|
14 |
alternatives were distorted was a matter of months. You
|
15 |
knew what the alternatives were. You typically, because
|
16 |
standards development activities are ostensibly
|
17 |
documented, have a good set of evidence to look to to
|
18 |
figure out what the alternatives were, why they were
|
19 |
rejected. It seems like an easier exercise, and because
|
20 |
it is an easier exercise, the risk that you are going to
|
21 |
get it wrong it seems to me goes down.
|
22 |
Let's talk about moving on to the culture of
|
23 |
standards development. First of all, standards
|
24 |
development is not a lawyer-intensive process, which
|
25 |
goes back to the point I made earlier about the risk of |
62
1 |
inadvertent nondisclosure or the risk of inadvertent
|
2 |
deception. In thinking about that, I go back to the
|
3 |
Rambus case and the FTC's description of standards
|
4 |
development as a cooperative effort in which the risk of
|
5 |
deception is therefore present. I would like to think
|
6 |
that that is right, but it raises an interesting
|
7 |
question and one that antitrust plays a role in.
|
8 |
The question is, how do we get there? And it is
|
9 |
not just an academic question for this audience. It is
|
10 |
a question in which antitrust does not necessarily come
|
11 |
with clean hands, not the Government, mind you, but the
|
12 |
private enforcement. Specifically, because of the
|
13 |
pervasive antitrust scrutiny of standards development
|
14 |
that Justice Brennan spoke about in Allied Tube and
|
15 |
particularly the imposition of vicarious liability on
|
16 |
standards development organizations in Hydrolevel,
|
17 |
standards organizations got very, very, very concerned
|
18 |
about antitrust liability.
|
19 |
They do not know much about it, but they know
|
20 |
enough to be frightened, which is kind of like what we
|
21 |
would feel if suddenly a brilliant men appeared at these
|
22 |
doors and told us we would be locked in this room until
|
23 |
we came up with the next standard for high speed
|
24 |
wireless data communications, and the way they responded
|
25 |
to that concern was by developing rules that |
63
1 |
systematically discouraged the discussion of what seemed
|
2 |
like efficient things to talk about, cost, patent
|
3 |
validity, pricing, particularly in the context of input
|
4 |
pricing.
|
5 |
The standards development organizations, for
|
6 |
whom the cost of defending that antitrust case to a
|
7 |
motion of dismiss, let alone summary judgment, would
|
8 |
consume multiples of their annual budget, decided we are
|
9 |
not going there, and we are going to enforce these
|
10 |
rules. That led to the development of what I will call
|
11 |
a culture of standard-setting in which people can be
|
12 |
forgiven for not having asked what seem in retrospect to
|
13 |
be obvious questions, like, hey, I really like your
|
14 |
technology contribution, how much is it going to cost me
|
15 |
to practice that, and instead being satisfied with the
|
16 |
answer, well, it will be reasonable, and also questions
|
17 |
like, well, can you prove to me that that patent is
|
18 |
valid? How much do -- do you have patents?
|
19 |
These are questions that seem, again, pretty
|
20 |
basic from the standpoint of lawyers with the benefit of
|
21 |
reading cases in this area but that the rules of the
|
22 |
standards development organizations often prohibited
|
23 |
discussion of, which suggests a role for the agencies,
|
24 |
but not necessarily a litigation role. I don't want to
|
25 |
dismiss the litigation role, having been at Cisco during |
64
1 |
the Rambus case and having talked to many engineers who
|
2 |
were following the coverage of the case in EE Times,
|
3 |
which is a leading semiconductor trade journal, which
|
4 |
had a full-time reporter, believe it or not, covering
|
5 |
the Rambus case.
|
6 |
It did provoke a lot of interest, and cases are
|
7 |
very useful from that standpoint, but beyond that, since
|
8 |
antitrust in some sense played a role in creating this
|
9 |
problem, it can also play a role, particularly the
|
10 |
agencies, in helping address the culture of standards
|
11 |
development by helping the agencies understand or the
|
12 |
participants in standards development understand what
|
13 |
they can and cannot do, and I would like to say that we
|
14 |
are off to a good start in that, particularly with
|
15 |
statements like Chairman Majoras' speech at Stanford
|
16 |
last year, the recent Vita letter, and also some
|
17 |
statements out of the European Union regarding this, but
|
18 |
more dialogue is needed and more help from the
|
19 |
enforcement organizations to figure out how far they can
|
20 |
go to defend themselves from these risks, to in some
|
21 |
sense change the culture, will nevertheless be
|
22 |
necessary.
|
23 |
Thank you.
|
24 |
(Applause.)
|
25 |
MR. DAGEN: Our final speaker during the |
65
1 |
prepared presentations is George Cary. George is a
|
2 |
partner at the D.C. office of Cleary Gottlieb. Before
|
3 |
joining Cleary, George served as Deputy Director of the
|
4 |
FTC's Bureau of Competition. George also was a
|
5 |
principal contributor to the 1997 modification of the
|
6 |
1992 Federal Horizontal Merger Guidelines, which
|
7 |
incorporated consideration of efficiencies in merger
|
8 |
assessment. He is a frequent speaker and writer on
|
9 |
antitrust issues.
|
10 |
George?
|
11 |
MR. CARY: Thanks, Rick.
|
12 |
We seem to have started with some very broad
|
13 |
principles at the beginning, through Susan's comments,
|
14 |
and have now narrowed down through Gil's comments to a
|
15 |
specific analysis of the standard-setting process. I am
|
16 |
going to take it one level more narrowly, and I am going
|
17 |
to talk about implementation of specific rules within
|
18 |
the standard-setting context and whether violations of
|
19 |
those specific rules ought to be treated as an antitrust
|
20 |
issue, an issue of antitrust concern.
|
21 |
The particular provision that I am going to talk
|
22 |
about is so-called FRAND licensing commitments,
|
23 |
commitments by participants in the standard-setting
|
24 |
process to license their technology on fair, reasonable
|
25 |
and nondiscriminatory terms, and I am going to start by |
66
1 |
laying out several premises that you have already heard
|
2 |
referenced this morning but which I believe apply in
|
3 |
this case as well.
|
4 |
First, standard-setting eliminates competition
|
5 |
among alternative technologies. Companies that
|
6 |
otherwise would be competing to promulgate proprietary
|
7 |
standards have now gotten together and eliminated that
|
8 |
competition by agreement. Antitrust, therefore, has a
|
9 |
stake in policing that standard-setting activity.
|
10 |
Second, when proprietary technology is made an
|
11 |
essential element of an industry standard, the owner of
|
12 |
that technology gains market power, exclusionary power,
|
13 |
beyond what is inherent in the patent itself. Prior to
|
14 |
the adoption of the standard, the company can exclude
|
15 |
others from practicing the particular innovation
|
16 |
incorporated in the patent. After inclusion in the
|
17 |
standard, if it is an essential patent, the patent
|
18 |
holder can exclude firms from practicing the standard
|
19 |
generally. That is a much broader grant of monopoly
|
20 |
power and one, again, where antitrust has a stake in how
|
21 |
it is exercised.
|
22 |
Third, the proposition that nondisclosure of
|
23 |
patents after lock-in as part of a standard has occurred
|
24 |
has been recognized as an antitrust concern. I think we
|
25 |
have had a couple of references to that recognition this |
67
1 |
morning, the Rambus case, the UNOCAL case, the Dell
|
2 |
case, and other cases where the Commission and the
|
3 |
courts have recognized that if you fail to disclose a
|
4 |
patent, if you have a duty to disclose because you are
|
5 |
part of the standard-setting body, and if, as a result,
|
6 |
you have gained market power because the standard has
|
7 |
now incorporated that patent, that raises antitrust
|
8 |
concerns.
|
9 |
My premise here today is that if you accept
|
10 |
those three propositions, then it naturally follows that
|
11 |
you have to accept the proposition that violation of
|
12 |
commitments to particular terms that the standard body
|
13 |
sets in order to ensure that there is no hold-up after
|
14 |
lock-in and that there is no extension of a patent
|
15 |
monopoly to a monoply of the standard as a whole, also
|
16 |
must raise antitrust concerns. So, violations of other
|
17 |
rules designed to constrain exploitation of lock-in
|
18 |
raise similar competitive problems to failure to
|
19 |
disclose, and therefore, ought to be treated similarly
|
20 |
under the antitrust laws.
|
21 |
What is a FRAND commitment? A FRAND commitment
|
22 |
is an agreement to license on fair, reasonable and
|
23 |
nondiscriminatory terms as a condition for including the
|
24 |
intellectual property within the standard. The purpose
|
25 |
of this is to avoid hold-up, the same purpose as a |
68
1 |
requirement that patents be disclosed, and an obligation
|
2 |
to disclose is ineffective if there is no recourse for
|
3 |
violation of the FRAND commitment. If one can simply
|
4 |
disclose, agree to license, and then fail to fulfill
|
5 |
that agreement, it raises the same competitive concern
|
6 |
as failure to disclose in the first instance.
|
7 |
What are the problems that FRAND is designed to
|
8 |
address? Before the standard is adopted, companies have
|
9 |
options. They can invent around patents. They can use
|
10 |
alternative patented technology. After the standard is
|
11 |
adopted, those wishing to practice the standard no
|
12 |
longer have options. They are locked into the use of
|
13 |
the standard, and having sunk significant investment in
|
14 |
standard-specific resources, it creates the potential
|
15 |
for monopoly rents, because their elasticity of demand
|
16 |
is now much more inelastic. They need to recover the
|
17 |
investments that they have made in that standard, and
|
18 |
they are going to be willing to pay a higher price for
|
19 |
the patented technology than they would have prior to
|
20 |
the adoption of the standard.
|
21 |
Second, FRAND is a commitment to a common
|
22 |
enterprise. Participating in the standard-setting body
|
23 |
is a commitment to the efficiency and the success of
|
24 |
that standard. That promise is that all participants in
|
25 |
the standard, many of whom contribute intellectual |
69
1 |
property of one form or another, have committed to each
|
2 |
other as a matter of good faith and fair dealing to
|
3 |
impose a mutual restraint on their exploitation of the
|
4 |
market power created by that standard and a commitment
|
5 |
that they will not price their intellectual property at
|
6 |
such a level so as to make the standard itself
|
7 |
uncompetitive or inefficient.
|
8 |
FRAND is designed also to ensure competitive
|
9 |
markets downstream for products that are compliant with
|
10 |
the standard. To accomplish this, there is a
|
11 |
nondiscriminatory element to a FRAND commitment where a
|
12 |
holder of intellectual property promises not to use that
|
13 |
control to disadvantage its competitors in producing
|
14 |
parts, equipment, networks that are compliant with that
|
15 |
standard. These are the goals of the standard-setting
|
16 |
process in imposing FRAND, and these goals, I would
|
17 |
submit, inform us as to how to properly interpret FRAND
|
18 |
in the context of an antitrust enforcement.
|
19 |
My next premise is that FRAND is enforceable
|
20 |
under the antitrust laws under standard, conventional
|
21 |
Section 2 theory. The holder of a patent included in a
|
22 |
standard gains monopoly power. What is the definition
|
23 |
of monopoly power under the cases? It is the power to
|
24 |
exclude others from the marketplace and the power to
|
25 |
control prices. If you hold a patent, if the patent is |
70
1 |
essential to practicing the standard, and if you refuse
|
2 |
to license that patent, you have effectively excluded
|
3 |
competition from within the standard. If you hold a
|
4 |
patent that is essential to practicing a standard and
|
5 |
you charge an exorbitant royalty to competitors who are
|
6 |
producing products compliant with the standard, you have
|
7 |
imposed costs on your rivals, and those costs have to be
|
8 |
passed onto consumers, and you have gained the power to
|
9 |
control prices in that downstream market. Both of those
|
10 |
things are the hallmarks of monopoly.
|
11 |
When does monopoly violate the antitrust laws?
|
12 |
It violates the antitrust laws where it is willfully
|
13 |
acquired; in other words, where it is not competition on
|
14 |
the merits, when the monopoly is not based on superior
|
15 |
products, business acumen or historical accident. A
|
16 |
willful violation of a FRAND commitment to license on
|
17 |
fair, reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms is,
|
18 |
therefore, monopolization. You have a monopoly by
|
19 |
virtue of the power to exclude and control prices.
|
20 |
Making a commitment to FRAND that you then renege upon
|
21 |
or do not follow through on is willful acquisition of
|
22 |
that market power, and therefore, the two would
|
23 |
constitute a violation of the Sherman Act with a
|
24 |
requisite showing of competitive effects.
|
25 |
Antitrust courts are competent to enforce FRAND |
71
1 |
commitments. Now, there has been some discussion about
|
2 |
this, but again, the idea that you can have an antitrust
|
3 |
violation by virtue of violating the essential elements
|
4 |
of Section 2 with no antitrust recourse is one I think
|
5 |
we would generally reject, and I think Susan articulated
|
6 |
the principles of that very well. Some have argued that
|
7 |
FRAND should be enforceable only under contract law or
|
8 |
under tort law, but if it is a violation of the
|
9 |
antitrust laws by virtue of its effect on competition,
|
10 |
by virtue of its effect on consumers, then the public
|
11 |
should have standing under the antitrust law and
|
12 |
recourse to vindicate a violation of the Sherman Act.
|
13 |
Participants in the standard-setting process may not
|
14 |
have the requisite incentives, and in any event, there
|
15 |
is a separate injury to consumers and to the public by
|
16 |
virtue of the exploitation of market power that results
|
17 |
from this kind of conduct.
|
18 |
Finally, if a court is capable of determining
|
19 |
whether conduct violates FRAND in a contract or tort
|
20 |
case, there is no reason why, as a matter of judicial
|
21 |
administerability, it cannot do the same in an antitrust
|
22 |
case, and there is no reason under antitrust policy why
|
23 |
it should not do so.
|
24 |
I am now going to illustrate a couple of
|
25 |
examples of FRAND violations and talk about how one |
72
1 |
might go about proving such a violation in an antitrust
|
2 |
case. The first is the most obvious, the extreme case
|
3 |
of a refusal to license. If you have agreed to license,
|
4 |
the standard has now incorporated your patent and you
|
5 |
refuse to license, you now have the capability of
|
6 |
monopolizing the market for standard-compliant parts and
|
7 |
equipment and networks. That, it seems to me, is a
|
8 |
clear violation of the FRAND commitment. It is also a
|
9 |
violation of antitrust law, because now you have created
|
10 |
a downstream monopoly.
|
11 |
Second, if you discriminate against competitors,
|
12 |
the "ND" part of the FRAND commitment, in
|
13 |
standard-compliant markets, again, you are taking your
|
14 |
monopoly on essential technology and you are extending
|
15 |
it to product markets for standards-compliant parts and
|
16 |
equipment. The hold-up potential is very real, and
|
17 |
antitrust law has recognized this kind of vertical
|
18 |
integration and abuse of monopoly in one market to gain
|
19 |
a monopoly in another in a variety of settings.
|
20 |
One example might be the case of a
|
21 |
rate-regulated utility vertically integrating into a
|
22 |
market where there is no such rate regulation and then
|
23 |
using its market power to expel other competitors from
|
24 |
that market, and once achieving a monopoly, charging
|
25 |
higher prices in the unregulated market to evade |
73
1 |
regulation in the regulated market. This is a similar
|
2 |
kind of phenomenon where a company might agree to
|
3 |
license on fair and reasonable terms but through
|
4 |
discrimination that excludes competitors in compliant
|
5 |
markets gains the ability then to charge the monopoly
|
6 |
price in the compliant parts and equipment market.
|
7 |
Such discrimination also has an effect on future
|
8 |
innovation and competition, because often in these kinds
|
9 |
of markets, you find that the companies that are making
|
10 |
the compliant parts are learning about how the standard
|
11 |
works in ways that allow them to make improvements on
|
12 |
the technology in the standard, and in the next
|
13 |
generation of standardization, provide a competitive
|
14 |
alternative to the firm that provided the essential
|
15 |
technology in the first instance. Eliminating those
|
16 |
kinds of innovators and competitors cements the position
|
17 |
of the firm providing the technology in the first
|
18 |
generation and potentially permits them to succeed to a
|
19 |
monopoly in the second generation without making the
|
20 |
kinds of commitments that a standard-setting body might
|
21 |
otherwise require or by raising what they might be able
|
22 |
to charge as a fair and reasonable royalty in the second
|
23 |
round.
|
24 |
Again, discrimination is well known to antitrust
|
25 |
courts. Antitrust courts look at that in the context of |
74
1 |
the Robinson-Patman Act, of the Sherman Act, of
|
2 |
discriminatory pricing, of predatory pricing. This is
|
3 |
not a foreign concept, and antitrust courts have
|
4 |
demonstrated an ability to administer these kinds of
|
5 |
rules.
|
6 |
What does fair and reasonable mean? Again, we
|
7 |
have to look at the underlying purposes of the
|
8 |
commitment that is being made in the light of the
|
9 |
antitrust principles that are being addressed here.
|
10 |
Fair and reasonable means a royalty that reflects the
|
11 |
competitive environment before lock-in. I think Gil
|
12 |
described it very well. It is the value of the
|
13 |
innovation separate and apart from the additional value
|
14 |
that that innovation takes on by virtue of its
|
15 |
incorporation in the standard and by virtue of the
|
16 |
lock-in created by the standard.
|
17 |
Second, fair and reasonable means a royalty that
|
18 |
is sufficient to allow the standard itself to be a
|
19 |
commercial success, so that you do not have a situation
|
20 |
where the royalties are so high that the standard is
|
21 |
debilitated, weakened, and is not able to provide the
|
22 |
efficiencies that the standard is designed to provide.
|
23 |
So, how would one determine a fair and
|
24 |
reasonable value? One would look at the alternatives
|
25 |
that were available to the standard-setting body before |
75
1 |
the standard was adopted. One would compare how close
|
2 |
those alternatives are, and one would ascribe a value
|
3 |
based on the benefits that the chosen technology
|
4 |
provides over and above the other alternatives. You
|
5 |
then might adjust that royalty if you find yourself in a
|
6 |
situation where the cumulative royalty stack is so high
|
7 |
that it impedes the efficient adoption of the standard.
|
8 |
Again, antitrust courts routinely compare the
|
9 |
but-for competitive world with the observed market when
|
10 |
assessing constraints, and this is no different. In a
|
11 |
price-fixing case, you would look at the price set
|
12 |
through the illegal restraint. You would then, through
|
13 |
economic evidence, look at what the price would have
|
14 |
been in the but-for competitive world. You would look
|
15 |
at the comparison, and you would say the difference is
|
16 |
damages. Again, here, one might look at what options
|
17 |
were available to the standard-setting body, how close
|
18 |
those options were, what did the standard-setting body
|
19 |
at the time think about their alternatives, and how much
|
20 |
incremental value, separate and apart from the lock-in
|
21 |
value, did the accepted technology provide?
|
22 |
Determining the fair and reasonable royalty is
|
23 |
within the competence of courts and enforcement
|
24 |
agencies. Courts routinely determine in the context of
|
25 |
a patent infringement suit what would a reasonable |
76
1 |
royalty have been. The courts have developed a
|
2 |
standard. The Georgia Pacific case lays out a whole
|
3 |
series of standards that might be used to do that.
|
4 |
There are industry benchmarks that could be looked at.
|
5 |
There are examples of the licensing of the same
|
6 |
technology in a context outside of the standard, what
|
7 |
kind of royalty did that patent attract where it did not
|
8 |
have the benefit of the standard?
|
9 |
A comparison of royalties charged in other
|
10 |
standards might also provide a benchmark, and a
|
11 |
comparison of the royalty charged in a competitive
|
12 |
market with no FRAND obligation might also be looked at.
|
13 |
So, courts have experience in assessing those kinds of
|
14 |
things. There is a body of case law that informs us,
|
15 |
there is an antitrust principle that gives us a
|
16 |
benchmark, and the courts are certainly capable of
|
17 |
analyzing those factors.
|
18 |
So, in conclusion, I would cite to you Justice
|
19 |
Ginburg's decision in the Cable and Wireless case that
|
20 |
was cited previously, and I would just quote from
|
21 |
Justice Ginsburg when he says, "Anticompetitive conduct
|
22 |
can come in too many different forms and is too
|
23 |
dependent upon context for any court or commentator ever
|
24 |
to have enumerated all of the varieties." It does no
|
25 |
good to shut one barn door and leave others open. It |
77
1 |
does no good to say failure to disclose is an antitrust
|
2 |
violation, but disclosure with commitments that you then
|
3 |
refuse to implement cannot violate the antitrust laws.
|
4 |
The courts are capable of looking at the factual context
|
5 |
and coming to reasoned decisions about whether the
|
6 |
antitrust laws have been violated because of the
|
7 |
creation of market power and whether a particular
|
8 |
actor's conduct should be adjusted as a result of the
|
9 |
commitments they made.
|
10 |
Thank you.
|
11 |
(Applause.)
|
12 |
MR. DAGEN: And I think it is now time for a
|
13 |
little inter-panel discussion. Each panelist -- I think
|
14 |
we will probably go in the same order that we did the
|
15 |
presentations, if you have any comments that you want to
|
16 |
share addressing other panelists' presentations or
|
17 |
questions that you want to pose to other panelists, we
|
18 |
can try to keep track of them and either have them
|
19 |
addressed as part of this discussion or further on down
|
20 |
the line. We are thinking three to five minutes per
|
21 |
person, if you have got that amount to go through, and
|
22 |
we will see how it proceeds from there.
|
23 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I am not sure I have three to
|
24 |
five minutes of things, but I had just a few points, I
|
25 |
think one comment on what Preston had to say a couple on |
78
1 |
what Gil had to say.
|
2 |
First, on Preston's observations, I found
|
3 |
intriguing his remark by the one lawyer who quoted that
|
4 |
he does his level best whenever he can to turn a
|
5 |
contract dispute into an antitrust claim. I would think
|
6 |
that typically, if people are in a contractual
|
7 |
relationship, that means that they are probably
|
8 |
somewhere in the vertical chain of supply, and so my
|
9 |
guess is that those antitrust claims that he is turning
|
10 |
his contract disputes into are a whole variety of what
|
11 |
we would view as sort of typical arguments about
|
12 |
vertical restrictions, and yet somehow we do not think
|
13 |
that that problem with turning contracts into antitrust
|
14 |
disputes means that we should invalidate all those types
|
15 |
of Section 2 claims sort of ex ante as somehow
|
16 |
invalidating them.
|
17 |
So, sort of returning to the point I had made
|
18 |
about we need to separate the question about problems we
|
19 |
have with private actions from the substantive antitrust
|
20 |
analysis, I guess I would pose as a broad experiment,
|
21 |
suppose we did away with private antitrust enforcement
|
22 |
just for the time being. In that circumstance, I would
|
23 |
be curious for those who have voiced concerns about
|
24 |
bringing -- for the Government to bring an antitrust
|
25 |
enforcement action in the context of -- I guess what I |
79
1 |
would call opportunism. If the Government is satisfied
|
2 |
that that conduct has, in fact, caused durable market
|
3 |
power, why would we nonetheless still eschew government
|
4 |
enforcement to remedy it?
|
5 |
With respect to Gil's point about intent, I
|
6 |
had -- that was actually -- I think I share the concern
|
7 |
that he does and had mentioned that one of the things
|
8 |
that can be misleading, so to speak, about using
|
9 |
business torts as our sort of initial predicate act for
|
10 |
an antitrust claim is that we really are not about
|
11 |
intent and that what you are trying to get at with a
|
12 |
business tort is different from what we are driving at
|
13 |
with antitrust, and so some folks had mentioned about
|
14 |
inadvertent deception.
|
15 |
I guess what I have tended to think of as
|
16 |
deception, I have been tending to think of -- I will
|
17 |
misuse Mr. Williamson again -- I think he defined
|
18 |
opportunism as self-interest with guile, and so I think
|
19 |
understanding it in that context, if we have -- what we
|
20 |
are really concerned about in antitrust is self-interest
|
21 |
with guile that causes durable market power, and that is
|
22 |
really what we are talking about here, not some narrow
|
23 |
business tort that may or may not fit the particular
|
24 |
facts of what we are concerned with, which is consumer
|
25 |
harm created by such market power. |
80
1 |
And then my final point, I wanted to amplify and
|
2 |
underscore a point that I thought Gil made quite well,
|
3 |
which was sort of going back to the causation question
|
4 |
that people have raised with Section 2 claims in this
|
5 |
area. I would agree with his point that it would seem
|
6 |
that many of our more traditional antitrust cases
|
7 |
actually do pose that causation problem more forcefully
|
8 |
than the kind of opportunism cases that we have been
|
9 |
focused on here. So, for example, in the cases that Gil
|
10 |
had identified, the Microsoft case, the AT&T case, the
|
11 |
IBM case, obviously untangling the effect of the
|
12 |
particular exclusionary acts is a challenge, but that
|
13 |
does not mean it is a challenge that we should forgo.
|
14 |
I would say, by contrast, in an Orange Book
|
15 |
case, if you conclude that there actually was a listing
|
16 |
that was made self-interestedly with guile and there was
|
17 |
a patent on it that automatically excluded competitors
|
18 |
from the market for 30 months where competition should
|
19 |
not have been excluded, the causation issue is pretty
|
20 |
straightforward. So, I would agree with Gil on that,
|
21 |
that sometimes the standard-setting cases, misuse of
|
22 |
government processes, the causation issue actually can
|
23 |
be quite straightforward.
|
24 |
That was it for my comments.
|
25 |
MR. DAGEN: Thank you. |
81
1 |
DR. McAFEE: Thank you.
|
2 |
Let me actually echo something that Gil said,
|
3 |
which is that it would be useful for the agencies to
|
4 |
provide guidance to the standard-setting organizations.
|
5 |
In particular, the prohibition of talking about costs or
|
6 |
for that matter the prohibition of negotiating prices
|
7 |
for the use of patented technology in advance are
|
8 |
actually quite harmful in making good decisions. It is
|
9 |
as if you had to buy a car without knowing what the
|
10 |
prices are, and so the inability or the fear of
|
11 |
discussing what technologies will cost when implemented
|
12 |
in the standard is itself something that is designed to
|
13 |
procure standards inefficiently.
|
14 |
The second thing I want to say is that -- and
|
15 |
also in response to Gil -- is when you buy a bath robe,
|
16 |
it comes with a somewhat optimistic statement that one
|
17 |
size fits all. One of the things that you learn in
|
18 |
studying standard-setting organizations is that they
|
19 |
solve very different problems from each other, and they
|
20 |
make their decisions in a very different environment,
|
21 |
and I think one of the things that will be a challenge
|
22 |
for providing guidance to standard-setting organizations
|
23 |
is that they actually -- one size will not fit all very
|
24 |
well.
|
25 |
In particular, the amount of information that |
82
1 |
they have available to them at the time that they make
|
2 |
decisions is often very different. I know JEDEC, in
|
3 |
particular, would discuss proposed standards, and then
|
4 |
the individuals would go back and work in their labs and
|
5 |
see whether or not the proposed standard was something
|
6 |
they could actually build themselves and what problems
|
7 |
needed to be solved in order to practice the tentative
|
8 |
standard. They very much were not necessarily on the
|
9 |
same page, nor did they want to get on the same page in
|
10 |
the sense that they did not want to reveal things that
|
11 |
they knew about the technology, because that would give
|
12 |
them a competitive edge. Giving advice about just what
|
13 |
they are allowed to do in such a circumstance where
|
14 |
standards are chosen, where how the standard is going to
|
15 |
be implemented is not yet even known, is going to be a
|
16 |
challenge.
|
17 |
And then finally, I have to agree with George
|
18 |
that it certainly is not a solution to say we can
|
19 |
practice a RAND -- if I make a promise that I will
|
20 |
satisfy a RAND, which there is another definition of
|
21 |
RAND, which is research and no development, which seems
|
22 |
appropriate in standard-setting organizations, but --
|
23 |
and then charge an exorbitant fee after the fact, after
|
24 |
the standard has been adopted, that is no solution at
|
25 |
all, and certainly the antitrust laws -- that is, I am |
83
1 |
going to completely agree -- that certainly the
|
2 |
antitrust laws, if they cover the deceptive conduct,
|
3 |
must also cover the failure to provide a RAND or failure
|
4 |
to live up to the RAND assurance. I am less confident,
|
5 |
however, that the courts can actually effectively
|
6 |
interpret what is reasonable.
|
7 |
Thank you.
|
8 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: I would like to comment a
|
9 |
little bit on some of the remarks of Preston and
|
10 |
Richard.
|
11 |
First of all, with respect to the issue of
|
12 |
private enforcement, I do not believe that we should
|
13 |
eliminate private enforcement, and indeed, I think the
|
14 |
decisions of the court over the last 20 years or so have
|
15 |
made it much more difficult for the plaintiff to
|
16 |
proceed, and indeed, the argument of I guess last Monday
|
17 |
or so in the Twombley case could also have an effect on
|
18 |
private enforcement, albeit that case is a Section 1
|
19 |
case.
|
20 |
But I do want to touch on private enforcement in
|
21 |
that I believe private enforcement is one way to explain
|
22 |
the result in Conwood. While not knowing what U.S.
|
23 |
Tobacco's presentation was before the jury with respect
|
24 |
to the existence of monopoly power and accepting the
|
25 |
concession that it did have monopoly power that was in |
84
1 |
the Sixth Circuit, when we think about the evidence that
|
2 |
was put forth and the reasonable juror sitting there,
|
3 |
hearing about a monopolist whose salespeople are running
|
4 |
around ripping out racks and throwing them in dumpsters
|
5 |
and various other types of conduct with respect to I
|
6 |
guess misleading information being provided or whatever,
|
7 |
in my view, the result in Conwood is not particularly
|
8 |
surprising given that it was in a private enforcement
|
9 |
setting.
|
10 |
Now the question becomes, well, do we want to
|
11 |
deter that? Well, I think one way to look at it, and
|
12 |
maybe this is Susan's point, is does the result in
|
13 |
Conwood somehow deter efficient conduct? Are we going
|
14 |
to deter throwing out racks or whatever or are we going
|
15 |
to -- whatever, and I think the end result is I do not
|
16 |
find Conwood to be a particularly surprising case, and I
|
17 |
think it can be explained in the context of private
|
18 |
antitrust enforcement and a reaction of juries to
|
19 |
evidence.
|
20 |
With respect to the pharmaceutical arena and
|
21 |
Hatch-Waxman and the regulatory scheme, Richard is
|
22 |
absolutely right. As I've mentioned in one of my
|
23 |
principles, I think we need to take into account the
|
24 |
structure of the industry and the regulation involved.
|
25 |
On the other hand, when there is deception, when there |
85
1 |
is anticompetitive conduct that disrupts the balance
|
2 |
that is struck in Hatch-Waxman, then I think antitrust
|
3 |
has an appropriate role to play. Indeed, I would say
|
4 |
that the Commission's case against Bristol-Myers and the
|
5 |
deception that was involved with Bristol-Myers is a very
|
6 |
good example of where antitrust properly intervened in
|
7 |
this particular setting.
|
8 |
MR. DAGEN: Richard?
|
9 |
DR. ROZEK: Well, as an economist, I was struck
|
10 |
by the discussion this morning that raised questions of
|
11 |
measurement. Economists like to practice their craft
|
12 |
and measure things. It comes up a lot in the areas of
|
13 |
misleading and deceptive conduct. One area where it
|
14 |
comes up frequently is in the issue of false
|
15 |
advertising. How do you measure whether an ad is really
|
16 |
false? It could have on its face a false statement or
|
17 |
it could be perceived as conveying a certain message
|
18 |
that is inaccurate, and so economists can do surveys and
|
19 |
interpret that survey result.
|
20 |
But in some cases, it is much harder to measure
|
21 |
whether something is misleading or deceptive, and I
|
22 |
think back to some of the cases I have worked on where
|
23 |
in one situation, for example, an organization had
|
24 |
funded some scientific research; it was concerned about
|
25 |
the scientific and statistical merit of the research; |
86
1 |
that is, the scientific protocol followed and the
|
2 |
statistical tools that were used to analyze the results
|
3 |
of that data.
|
4 |
So, the company raised legitimate questions, I
|
5 |
thought, as a reviewer of an academic article would
|
6 |
raise in commenting on the methodologies used to conduct
|
7 |
the research, but it was criticized for doing that and
|
8 |
for suggesting that the article not be published. To
|
9 |
avoid bad publicity, the company just paid a large
|
10 |
settlement. How to measure whether that was -- whether
|
11 |
their withholding publication -- or their request to
|
12 |
withhold publication of the article was really
|
13 |
misleading or whether there were legitimate scientific
|
14 |
questions that needed to be resolved before publication,
|
15 |
was a much more difficult issue.
|
16 |
That brings me to the question that was raised
|
17 |
earlier about private actions following on government
|
18 |
settlements. When someone settles a particular case
|
19 |
with the FTC or the Department of Justice, and they may
|
20 |
have done a calculation at that point that settling the
|
21 |
case was -- even if they could win, settling the case
|
22 |
was within that company's interest, was in their
|
23 |
interests to settle the case, but then they do not
|
24 |
always adequately factor in the private antitrust
|
25 |
actions that are going to follow and the damages that |
87
1 |
are at issue in those private cases. So, they do not
|
2 |
take a complete picture of the damage calculation and
|
3 |
factor it in when they settle.
|
4 |
So, sometimes -- I have had cases like this,
|
5 |
too, where people come to us after two or three of the
|
6 |
private cases have gone forward and say, "we are just
|
7 |
tired of paying all this money. We are going to fight
|
8 |
this now." And I say, well, you know, you should have
|
9 |
fought it at the FTC or the Department of Justice,
|
10 |
because you could have a better case there on market
|
11 |
definition and on entry conditions and so on. In some
|
12 |
settlement discussions, the full impact of the private
|
13 |
cases are not factored into those calculations.
|
14 |
And then I was struck by George's comments on
|
15 |
the FRAND standards and what evidence is actually used
|
16 |
to determine whether a royalty rate is fair and
|
17 |
reasonable. I think the discussion of Georgia Pacific
|
18 |
factors borrowing from the patent literature, and the
|
19 |
wealth of information in the tax literature on applying
|
20 |
the arm's length standard to valuing intangible property
|
21 |
on transfers between affiliated companies such as a UK
|
22 |
research lab and an Irish manufacturing plant, that
|
23 |
would be very helpful to apply in the FRAND context.
|
24 |
Now, I was also struck by the discussions of
|
25 |
private cases and whether or not there should be a ban |
88
1 |
on private antitrust actions. It seems to me that not
|
2 |
an outright ban, but maybe some reform in the process.
|
3 |
Again, speaking to some of the cases I have been
|
4 |
involved in from my own experience, there was no reason
|
5 |
that the brand name antitrust litigation should have
|
6 |
gone on as long as it did until Judge Kocoras made the
|
7 |
decision that it was meritless. All but four
|
8 |
pharmaceutical firms who were initially sued in that
|
9 |
case settled. That case went on too long, and there
|
10 |
should have been a process in place to make a decision
|
11 |
much faster. So, there are areas where there could be
|
12 |
reform in the private antitrust cases to at least render
|
13 |
decisions on frivolous cases much faster.
|
14 |
I was struck also by Preston's comments on
|
15 |
Canada because of the absence of private actions. I did
|
16 |
a study of health care reform in Canada and compared it
|
17 |
to health care reform initiatives in the United States.
|
18 |
One of the key differences between Canadians and
|
19 |
Americans -- residents of the United States that you see
|
20 |
is that in Canada, they have a much greater confidence
|
21 |
in the Government as a solver of problems, and so they
|
22 |
trust the Government to provide their health care and to
|
23 |
provide high-quality health care. Whereas in the United
|
24 |
States, I think we saw it with the Clinton Health Care
|
25 |
Reform Initiatives, there was a great deal of distrust |
89
1 |
in the Government as a solver of problems and more the
|
2 |
Government as a creator of problems. So, there is a
|
3 |
fundamental difference in Canada and the U.S. just in
|
4 |
terms of how the residents in those countries interpret
|
5 |
the Government and government action.
|
6 |
I think part of the reason you do not see
|
7 |
private antitrust cases in Canada is that, "Well, the
|
8 |
Government will take care of it" is the solution. Those
|
9 |
are my comments.
|
10 |
MR. OHANA: I'll segue on the point that the
|
11 |
Government will take care of it. I wanted to pick up on
|
12 |
Preston's comment regarding one size fits all and the
|
13 |
role that I posited for antitrust agencies relative to
|
14 |
helping standards development organizations and their
|
15 |
participants understand what I will call the limits to
|
16 |
self-help to avoid deception.
|
17 |
I agree with Preston that one size does not fit
|
18 |
all. The point I was making maybe was a little bit
|
19 |
different. I am not positing a role for the agencies in
|
20 |
creating the uniform code of standards disclosure rules
|
21 |
or standards patent licensing rules. Far from it.
|
22 |
Standards organizations need, because of the variety
|
23 |
that Preston mentioned, a lot of freedom in that area.
|
24 |
I think, nevertheless, it is useful for the
|
25 |
agencies to do as the Antitrust Division did in the Vita |
90
1 |
letter and as the European Commission did in the letter
|
2 |
they wrote ETSI in June of this year, to set out what
|
3 |
are the points that you cannot go past? For example, in
|
4 |
ETSI, the European Telecom Standards Institute, one of
|
5 |
the proposals was to essentially create a cap that at
|
6 |
the start of a standards development exercise, all
|
7 |
participants would agree that any IP disclosed would
|
8 |
essentially be under a cap of X percent, and even if you
|
9 |
had a very fundamental, very broad, very valuable
|
10 |
patent, you were in there with the rest of the patents
|
11 |
fighting for your share of X percent, and the European
|
12 |
Commission quite rightly said that that was problematic,
|
13 |
and it is that role that I see the agencies playing in
|
14 |
terms of limiting what is now the considerable desire of
|
15 |
standards development organizations to enact rules that
|
16 |
address this problem proactively ex ante rather than ex
|
17 |
post.
|
18 |
MR. CARY: Just a couple of observations.
|
19 |
First, I think that Preston's observations about the
|
20 |
costs of antitrust enforcement, the difficulties of
|
21 |
administerability and perverse incentives are all points
|
22 |
that we constantly have to keep in mind and keep guard
|
23 |
of in terms of how one interprets and applies the
|
24 |
antitrust laws. But having said that, I think those
|
25 |
comments also paint with too broad a brush, and maybe |
91
1 |
one size fits all does not apply in that context either.
|
2 |
I would say that for those of you who have not
|
3 |
read it, and I am assuming that is not very many, the
|
4 |
"Cheap Exclusion" article that Susan authored with her
|
5 |
co-authors is a brilliant piece. The idea that one can
|
6 |
rationally set about determining where to apply
|
7 |
prosecutorial discretion in a systematic way in coming
|
8 |
up with arrays of combinations of anticompetitive
|
9 |
conduct where antitrust enforcement is likely to do as
|
10 |
little harm as possible, is a prototype for how to make
|
11 |
prosecutorial decisions going forward.
|
12 |
And using that framework and integrating the
|
13 |
points that Michael made, I would set up an array, and I
|
14 |
would say, for example, at one end of the deceptive
|
15 |
conduct that we have been talking about might be false
|
16 |
advertising or sham litigation. In sham litigation, you
|
17 |
have a built-in control: You have a judge. And if the
|
18 |
case is frivolous and has no reasonable basis,
|
19 |
presumably a judge would be easily in a position to get
|
20 |
rid of the case quickly and efficiently; and if the case
|
21 |
is more complicated so that he cannot get rid of it
|
22 |
quickly and efficiently; then perhaps that is correlated
|
23 |
with the idea that there is a reasonable basis to
|
24 |
litigate the claim, and it ought to go forward.
|
25 |
So, sham litigation as anticompetitive conduct |
92
1 |
would seem to be one which has a built-in mechanism to
|
2 |
police it, and in addition, one where the
|
3 |
anticompetitive injury is likely to be small. Attorneys
|
4 |
are expensive, but relative to the sizes of most
|
5 |
business, paying an attorney is not likely to debilitate
|
6 |
you from competing.
|
7 |
At the other extreme would be the
|
8 |
standard-setting discussion that we have had where SSO's
|
9 |
create networks, durable market power is created through
|
10 |
lock-in, it is very, very difficult to change those
|
11 |
networks once they are established, and the
|
12 |
opportunities for exploitation of market power are
|
13 |
therefore significant.
|
14 |
In addition, you have got antitrust concerns in
|
15 |
participants establishing royalty rates pre-adoption of
|
16 |
the standard which, again, puts a premium on antitrust
|
17 |
enforcement after the fact if there is a pattern of
|
18 |
exploitation that a participant then engages in. Maybe
|
19 |
somewhere in between might be the Orange Book context
|
20 |
where there is an immediate anticompetitive effect from
|
21 |
bringing the litigation, separate and apart from the
|
22 |
standard sham litigation (where the anticompetitive
|
23 |
effect might flaw only as a result of paying attorneys'
|
24 |
fees). So that is a middle ground, in light of the fact
|
25 |
that you still have a judge who could dispense with the |
93
1 |
case very quickly if it is truly a sham.
|
2 |
So, I do not think it is necessarily appropriate
|
3 |
to say that antitrust has no role in any of these areas
|
4 |
because of the possibility of an unintended consequence.
|
5 |
Instead, I think you can array these things and you can
|
6 |
apply antitrust where it is going to have the highest
|
7 |
likelihood of procompetitive impact and the lowest
|
8 |
possibility of making a mistake.
|
9 |
MR. DAGEN: Thank you.
|
10 |
Does anybody else have any comments they want to
|
11 |
share before we move into our rapid-fire questioning
|
12 |
period?
|
13 |
(No response.)
|
14 |
MR. DAGEN: Okay, we have some slides that I
|
15 |
think we will get to in a second with some propositions
|
16 |
and questions, but I think just since George went last,
|
17 |
I just had a question about one of the propositions he
|
18 |
just made.
|
19 |
So, in terms of your sham litigation, which you
|
20 |
put at one end, it sounds like it would be a very strong
|
21 |
presumption that there would be no sham litigation
|
22 |
monopolization claims, because it either gets disposed
|
23 |
of quickly, in which case there is no harm, or it lasts,
|
24 |
in which case it is not sham. So, is that --
|
25 |
MR. CARY: Oh, I do not know that I would use |
94
1 |
the term "presumption," because that implies a legal
|
2 |
rule. I would say that as a matter of logic and maybe
|
3 |
some casual empiricism, that will tend to be the case,
|
4 |
and therefore, as a matter of prosecutorial discretion
|
5 |
or as a matter of the kind of scrutiny that a judge
|
6 |
might impose on such a case, it should be at the end
|
7 |
where the plaintiff might have to demonstrate a little
|
8 |
bit more in terms of context and effect than they might
|
9 |
in other contexts.
|
10 |
MR. DAGEN: Any views from the rest of the
|
11 |
panel?
|
12 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: I would like to make a quick
|
13 |
comment about Richard and what George just said about
|
14 |
mechanisms for quick disposal of cases. I am going to
|
15 |
point two cases out to you and Judge Schwarzer. Judge
|
16 |
Schwarzer attempted in the Northern District of
|
17 |
California to impose a screen -- and I will use the word
|
18 |
screening mechanism to shed cases quickly, limited
|
19 |
discovery, and in an effort to determine whether there
|
20 |
was merit to the claim. If there was not, dismissal,
|
21 |
and you move on, okay?
|
22 |
There are two cases of Judge Schwarzer's in that
|
23 |
period that went to the Supreme Court, and both were
|
24 |
reversed, Kodak and Hartford. Those both came from
|
25 |
Judge Schwarzer. So, while I recognize that, I do not |
95
1 |
know how receptive the courts will be to that type of
|
2 |
procedure.
|
3 |
And so as a result, you are right, George, yes,
|
4 |
one way to say you can get rid of the sham litigation
|
5 |
quickly. Possibly not. It may depend on the judge.
|
6 |
MS. CREIGHTON: Maybe if I could just pick up on
|
7 |
George's idea, sort of to continue -- and I also thank
|
8 |
you for the kind remarks, George -- because I agree, I
|
9 |
think, that it is definitely not one size fits all when
|
10 |
we are looking at this kind of conduct. Some is much
|
11 |
more likely to arise in circumstances where there is a
|
12 |
likelihood of causing durable market power, and I
|
13 |
think -- and I would agree with George that at the other
|
14 |
end, deceptive marketing claims where you are talking
|
15 |
about -- particularly when it is sort of dueling claims
|
16 |
about products, I think Judge Easterbrook in Sanderson
|
17 |
versus Culligan cases correctly points out on the do no
|
18 |
harm end of things or sort of not trying to chill
|
19 |
procompetitive conduct.
|
20 |
I think the FTC for the last 20 or 30 years has
|
21 |
been a pretty aggressive proponent of the notion that
|
22 |
advertising is a good, and so this is one area where if
|
23 |
you allowed claims of any -- sort of I disagree with
|
24 |
that advertising, he said bad things about my product,
|
25 |
that is an antitrust claim, that kind of claim can chill |
96
1 |
procompetitive conduct and that advertising is as much a
|
2 |
good for consumers as price competition. So, I
|
3 |
appreciate George's refinement of my analysis, and I
|
4 |
would agree with it.
|
5 |
MR. DAGEN: So, Hill, did you have anything you
|
6 |
wanted to talk about before we move on?
|
7 |
MR. WELLFORD: I have one question that several
|
8 |
people glanced over, and I think George maybe most
|
9 |
directly, so I will start there.
|
10 |
What does your point about incentives say about
|
11 |
the kind of remedies that we should look for to be
|
12 |
procompetitive or perhaps even prohibit as the FTC tried
|
13 |
to do in the Schering case, if you want to characterize
|
14 |
it that way? You said, you know, certain participants
|
15 |
in standard-setting organizations, for example, may not
|
16 |
have the incentive to correct the -- to challenge or
|
17 |
challenge the correct way. Perhaps some people who
|
18 |
claim to represent the public, which was your point,
|
19 |
some would have better incentives than others. Is there
|
20 |
anything to that that you would like to share?
|
21 |
MR. CARY: Well, yeah, let me back up a bit and
|
22 |
start from the beginning on it. You start with the
|
23 |
question, why shouldn't a violation of these kinds of
|
24 |
commitments be enforceable only in contract or tort? I
|
25 |
guess a wrinkle on that would be if it is remediable in |
97
1 |
contract or tort, why bother with antitrust,
|
2 |
particularly when, overlaying Preston's presentation,
|
3 |
antitrust litigation can do harm?
|
4 |
I was attempting to answer that question by
|
5 |
saying that there is a harm that might extend beyond
|
6 |
those individuals that might have standing to bring a
|
7 |
contract claim or a fraud claim, that that harm is also
|
8 |
a harm to consumers, and that that harm ought to be
|
9 |
vindicated. So, for example, let's say you have someone
|
10 |
who is not part of the original standard-setting
|
11 |
proceeding; let's say that a particular state law of
|
12 |
contract limits the rights of third-party beneficiaries
|
13 |
to only those who are directly anticipated to be
|
14 |
beneficiaries; and therefore, a nonparticipant in
|
15 |
standard-setting would not qualify, they would not have
|
16 |
a contract claim directly. Nonetheless, there might be
|
17 |
a situation where a violation of the standard-setting
|
18 |
rules would cause competitive harm, and that individual,
|
19 |
without standing under contract, might be an appropriate
|
20 |
party to vindicate it.
|
21 |
A second example might be a state fraud statute
|
22 |
or a state common law rule of fraud which says if the
|
23 |
representation was not made to you, you have no standing
|
24 |
to vindicate the fraud. Again, if a misrepresentation
|
25 |
is made about patents, for example; if the |
98
1 |
standard-setting body for one reason or another decides
|
2 |
not to pursue that, say, for example, the perpetrator of
|
3 |
that misrepresentation has now stacked the
|
4 |
standard-setting body with its own agents,
|
5 |
representatives, network of suppliers, allies; but there
|
6 |
is a hold-up in the sense that the failure to disclose
|
7 |
the patent was real, and now the patent is being
|
8 |
asserted, why wouldn't a member of the public who is
|
9 |
paying the bill for that violation of the
|
10 |
standard-setting body's rules have an opportunity to
|
11 |
bring an antitrust case, claiming the antitrust damage?
|
12 |
It is that kind of thing that I was referring
|
13 |
to, in saying that people with standing may not have the
|
14 |
incentives, and people without standing may have
|
15 |
suffered the consumer injury or the anticompetitive
|
16 |
harm.
|
17 |
MR. WELLFORD: Does it follow from your analysis
|
18 |
there that a member of the public should be limited to
|
19 |
remedies that benefit the public or the competitive
|
20 |
process as a whole as opposed to that particular person
|
21 |
who has brought the lawsuit, and is that done today or
|
22 |
can it be effectively done?
|
23 |
MR. CARY: I do not think that there is a
|
24 |
necessity, just because of the standard-setting context,
|
25 |
to revisit all of the rules of antitrust injury and |
99
1 |
antitrust damages. So, for example, the courts have
|
2 |
established rules as to what consumers can recover. The
|
3 |
courts have established rules as to what competitors who
|
4 |
are the target of the anticompetitive activity might
|
5 |
recover.
|
6 |
Those rules do not need be any different in the
|
7 |
context of standard-setting than they would be in any
|
8 |
other monopolization case or price-fixing case or other
|
9 |
antitrust violation. I do believe that an antitrust
|
10 |
injury requirement is appropriate.
|
11 |
MR. OHANA: Just to comment, to pick up on
|
12 |
something George said, it is by no means universal in
|
13 |
standards development organizations' IPR policies that
|
14 |
any implementer of the standard is given explicitly the
|
15 |
right to sue to vindicate a disclosure or a
|
16 |
nondisclosure made to the standards development
|
17 |
organizations. In fact, it is extremely rare in my
|
18 |
experience that they actually explicitly say that. So,
|
19 |
you are going to be proceeding at that point under a
|
20 |
third-party beneficiary theory, and a third-party
|
21 |
beneficiary theory will vary a lot with state law. So,
|
22 |
in that sense I agree with George that it is entirely
|
23 |
possible that the contractual remedy will not exist.
|
24 |
MR. DAGEN: A couple of panelists I think
|
25 |
mentioned the notion that the regular false advertising |
100
1 |
sort of claim would be on the lesser end of the
|
2 |
perspective. I wanted to try to juxtapose that with the
|
3 |
standard-setting discussion that you were having, which
|
4 |
was let's say you have a misrepresentation not about IP
|
5 |
but something else within the standard-setting
|
6 |
organization. There was a case involving Heary brothers
|
7 |
a long time ago where there was an allegation, I
|
8 |
believe, similar to an Allied Tube sort of thing with
|
9 |
packing except involving misrepresentations about an
|
10 |
alternative technology that was to be accepted or
|
11 |
proposed for an alternative within the SSO.
|
12 |
Where do you think that sort of
|
13 |
misrepresentation more or less similar to the false
|
14 |
advertising I think that you were talking about, where
|
15 |
would that fall, if you have any thoughts on that?
|
16 |
Anybody?
|
17 |
DR. McAFEE: Theoretically, it should not
|
18 |
actually make any difference. If I establish my
|
19 |
technology as the standard by claiming that the
|
20 |
alternative technology sets the atmosphere on fire and
|
21 |
burns up the earth, it is not -- and that is fraud --
|
22 |
that is not true, then it has had exactly the same
|
23 |
effect. On the other hand, it seems much less likely
|
24 |
that in reality you are going to be able to pull that
|
25 |
off, because by and large, the standard-setting |
101
1 |
organizations are composed of people who know technology
|
2 |
pretty well, and so your ability to impugn alternative
|
3 |
technologies seems much more limited than your ability
|
4 |
to keep secret, for example, that you have patents.
|
5 |
MR. OHANA: There are cases, and I am thinking
|
6 |
of the Schachar case in the Seventh Circuit, where, if I
|
7 |
remember the case right, there was an allegation that
|
8 |
there was a misrepresentation made to a standards body,
|
9 |
and I think the response of the Seventh Circuit was that
|
10 |
the answer to bad speech is more correct speech, and I
|
11 |
would tend to agree with that. Those cases are not
|
12 |
going to impose a high risk of durable competitive harm
|
13 |
and therefore are unlikely to require the intervention
|
14 |
of antitrust agencies or courts.
|
15 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I thought the Commission was
|
16 |
right in Rambus in focusing on the ability of the
|
17 |
representation to be adequately -- both that its -- both
|
18 |
public and rebuttable, I guess, in the sense of I think
|
19 |
they were focused in particular on collaborative
|
20 |
ventures where there's less ability to ferret out people
|
21 |
where it might be making misrepresentations, but they
|
22 |
were trying, I think, to be getting at this point about
|
23 |
is it something that can be responded to with the
|
24 |
contrasting speech.
|
25 |
So, if I could change your hypothetical, for |
102
1 |
example, suppose the misrepresentation was that each and
|
2 |
every member of the standard-setting organization was
|
3 |
voting based on sort of independent assessment of the
|
4 |
technology, but, in fact, I have gone around and paid
|
5 |
off everybody to vote my way, so there is a
|
6 |
representation that everyone is voting unilaterally,
|
7 |
and, in fact, that is not true. It has been stacked.
|
8 |
It seems to me like that misrepresentation poses
|
9 |
the same kind of difficult-to-get-at or ferret-out
|
10 |
problem that misrepresentations about IP do, but they
|
11 |
would be quite different from saying you should not use
|
12 |
that guy's technology because it is bad and that guy is
|
13 |
right there and he can counter.
|
14 |
MR. CARY: Having set up the continuum and
|
15 |
putting that kind of conduct at one end, now let me
|
16 |
retract just a little bit, because I do think that there
|
17 |
are environments where sowing confusion through false
|
18 |
representations can, in fact, be an antitrust violation.
|
19 |
I would not say that it does not exist, and I am
|
20 |
reminded of the good old days of pop-up windows where
|
21 |
people who were trying to create applications software
|
22 |
that ran on particular operating system platforms would
|
23 |
find that when somebody went to activate that
|
24 |
application program, a little screen would pop up
|
25 |
saying, "you are about to go into unchartered territory, |
103
1 |
and we cannot guarantee that your computer will not blow
|
2 |
up if you press the button."
|
3 |
There are examples where that kind of activity
|
4 |
causes consumers, who are not expert technicians, to
|
5 |
worry about using alternative software which might, if
|
6 |
it were allowed to grow and expand, reduce an
|
7 |
application barrier to entry and result in more
|
8 |
competition to the operating system. I would not say
|
9 |
that as a matter of law one should not be allowed to
|
10 |
pursue those claims in a well-pled complaint and beyond
|
11 |
summary judgment if there are facts to be litigated
|
12 |
about whether that kind of activity does, in fact,
|
13 |
retard the growth of competing technologies.
|
14 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, yeah, I want to agree
|
15 |
with what George just said, and we need to be a little
|
16 |
careful, because while I agree also with what Gil said,
|
17 |
that often false advertising or false statements may
|
18 |
well be -- again, continuing to use the scale here -- at
|
19 |
very much the low end of the scale, I do not believe we
|
20 |
should fall victim to even possibly absolutist language,
|
21 |
which one of the cases that we looked at was a Judge
|
22 |
Easterbrook decision involving Culligan, where he has a
|
23 |
fairly direct sentence that says commercial speech can
|
24 |
never be the basis of a Section 2 claim.
|
25 |
I believe that is wrong, and indeed, to go back |
104
1 |
to the quotation from Judge Ginsburg that George read at
|
2 |
the end of his presentation I think has it right, which
|
3 |
is, yeah, we need to look at the context of the
|
4 |
circumstances where the commercial speech or the
|
5 |
misleading statements are made and then measure the
|
6 |
effect of that in the context of the market in which it
|
7 |
is made.
|
8 |
MR. OHANA: I would agree with that. I would
|
9 |
just point out that in the context of ETSI section
|
10 |
consensus-based broad participation standard-setting, it
|
11 |
seems to me that the likelihood that a disparaging
|
12 |
statement by the proponent of one technology about
|
13 |
another technology is very unlikely to have competitive
|
14 |
harm, because there are going to be a lot of other
|
15 |
participants who are going to be eagerly awaiting the
|
16 |
response from the proponent of the criticized
|
17 |
technology, and there is going to be a discussion of it,
|
18 |
and in that sense, I think the likelihood of competitive
|
19 |
harm is very low.
|
20 |
What I would point to in the example that George
|
21 |
gave, which actually I had to look at when I was at the
|
22 |
Antitrust Division, because I think it involved a
|
23 |
company in the Pacific Northwest and the Windows
|
24 |
operating system, is that what was very interesting
|
25 |
about that is that it was actually used only in the beta |
105
1 |
of I think it was Windows 3 or Windows 3.1, and what was
|
2 |
sort of interesting is that Microsoft then pulled it
|
3 |
when they actually released the operating system.
|
4 |
The argument from the complainants was that the
|
5 |
damage had been done, because obviously the beta test
|
6 |
was distributed to a lot of kind of key influencers of
|
7 |
the technology industry who were then going to write
|
8 |
articles, create demand for the product, knowing that
|
9 |
DRDOS, at least according to Microsoft, cannot work.
|
10 |
That might be a context in which responsive speech may
|
11 |
not be effective, because it has to happen in a very
|
12 |
short time period in which a lot of demand is going to
|
13 |
be set in a product market that is very subject to
|
14 |
tipping, which I guess goes to Michael's point that the
|
15 |
underlying facts matter a lot.
|
16 |
MS. CREIGHTON: Another fact pattern that might
|
17 |
be worth throwing out there at some point would be in
|
18 |
the context of something that cannot be responded to
|
19 |
effectively potentially with responsive speech or at
|
20 |
least some party is vaporware, saying you have got your
|
21 |
product coming when, in fact, it is not. So, that is a
|
22 |
deceptive statement not readily correctable.
|
23 |
I think Preston and Richard probably know the
|
24 |
literature better than I do, but I think Farrell,
|
25 |
Sloaner and others have written some articles about at |
106
1 |
least in tipping industries the potential for such
|
2 |
statements to have anticompetitive long-term effects.
|
3 |
DR. ROZEK: I think part of the discussion has
|
4 |
to involve the sophistication of the buyer. If you are
|
5 |
making statements to a buyer about a competing
|
6 |
technology, the buyer has to be able to assess those
|
7 |
statements. It may not be in every case that they can
|
8 |
do that instantaneously. It may be a statement about
|
9 |
reliability of the product after it is being used for
|
10 |
two years. You would not know if that statement is true
|
11 |
or false up front. You may have to spend a lot of money
|
12 |
to buy the machine, let's say a medical device, a
|
13 |
lithotripter, for example, something you have to spend a
|
14 |
lot of money, you would not know about the reliability
|
15 |
until after you spent the money, put it in place,
|
16 |
trained your workers and used it for a period of time.
|
17 |
Not all people can make those kinds of assessments.
|
18 |
So, I think underlying all of this in the
|
19 |
standard-setting process, in the false advertising
|
20 |
cases, you really have to conduct a rule of reason
|
21 |
analysis. You have to think about the sophistication of
|
22 |
the buyers and their ability to interpret the
|
23 |
information in a cost-effective way, without having to
|
24 |
make a purchase and wait two years or so to determine if
|
25 |
the machine is going to break down or be reliable, for |
107
1 |
example.
|
2 |
DR. McAFEE: I agree with that completely. In
|
3 |
fact, standard-setting organizations are unlikely to be
|
4 |
a place where misleading statements of that kind are
|
5 |
going to last. They tend to have a smaller number of
|
6 |
very well-educated individuals, and it is more -- the
|
7 |
vaporware, in particular, which is usually a gimmick to
|
8 |
buy time while you try to develop a product so that
|
9 |
another product does not become a standard.
|
10 |
Microsoft made various promises about Windows CE
|
11 |
as a way of trying to prevent Palm from becoming a
|
12 |
standard, although in the end, Palm did become a
|
13 |
standard. It did not -- the vaporware promises were not
|
14 |
actually effective in that case. But there, that is a
|
15 |
much more likely thing. We will eventually support
|
16 |
this, just wait another few months, and that may be
|
17 |
enough to buy time to prevent a competitor from entering
|
18 |
the market.
|
19 |
MR. DAGEN: If we could maybe put up a few of
|
20 |
our propositions for discussion, first, slide number 2
|
21 |
states, "Merely because a particular practice might be
|
22 |
actionable under tort law does not preclude an action
|
23 |
under the antitrust laws as well."
|
24 |
I think this has been discussed a fair amount
|
25 |
today. Is there -- I heard a lot of consensus on this, |
108
1 |
but I wanted to know if anybody had any views contrary
|
2 |
to that view or proposition.
|
3 |
MR. OHANA: I do not know if it is contrary, but
|
4 |
let me just offer what I hope is an exacerbation. If
|
5 |
you look at Trinko, one of the facts in Trinko is that
|
6 |
the conduct that Bell Atlantic was accused of was in
|
7 |
parallel the subject of an FCC regulatory proceeding
|
8 |
that resulted in the payment by Bell Atlantic of fines
|
9 |
to the FCC, and there is language in the opinion, if I
|
10 |
recall, that says that essentially where you have got a
|
11 |
regulatory system and the regulatory system is intended
|
12 |
to vindicate competition, the existence of the
|
13 |
regulatory system matters relative to the antitrust
|
14 |
analysis.
|
15 |
Then you get this quote from Conwood, and I will
|
16 |
not try to reconcile the two except to note that I think
|
17 |
there is a tension there.
|
18 |
MR. DAGEN: Well, given -- go ahead, Susan.
|
19 |
MS. CREIGHTON: Though I think maybe the way to
|
20 |
reconcile the tension was -- as I recall, Trinko said
|
21 |
where there is another comprehensive regulatory scheme
|
22 |
whose purpose is to promote competition --
|
23 |
MR. OHANA: Exactly.
|
24 |
MS. CREIGHTON: -- and that is a pretty
|
25 |
important difference. |
109
1 |
MR. DAGEN: Go ahead.
|
2 |
MR. WELLFORD: We have already covered the law
|
3 |
of contract a little bit, but let me talk about the law
|
4 |
of fraud and maybe some other areas. These areas of --
|
5 |
is developed in the common law over a very long period
|
6 |
of time as the collective judgments of the courts, the
|
7 |
common law courts anyway, has been that there is some
|
8 |
necessity to apply heightened pleading standards or
|
9 |
specialized pleading standards to them.
|
10 |
For example, in the law of fraud, you have
|
11 |
Federal Rule 9 and 9(B), which is the rule of
|
12 |
specificity, the rule to require justifying reliance,
|
13 |
and the law of defamation or misleading statements about
|
14 |
individuals in that area. You have the Supreme Court's
|
15 |
New York Times recklessness standard for defamation.
|
16 |
Are we at all concerned that imposing Section 2
|
17 |
liability, which very clearly has regular pleading
|
18 |
standards, regular Rule 8, is at all going to be an
|
19 |
end-run around any of those established doctrines, and
|
20 |
does that indicate that either we may be off balance
|
21 |
with Section 2 liability or we should have Section 2
|
22 |
liability but apply some different pleading standards to
|
23 |
try to vindicate those same concerns?
|
24 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, let me respond first, and
|
25 |
somebody can probably tell me I am dead wrong, but I |
110
1 |
believe, for example, in Walker Process, if you plead a
|
2 |
Section 2 claim based on Walker Process, you are subject
|
3 |
to Rule 9, and so you are going to have to plead with
|
4 |
specificity, I think in the case of Walker Process and
|
5 |
maybe in the case also of inequitable conduct, such that
|
6 |
I really wonder whether Rule 9 is already coming into
|
7 |
play when you need the heightened pleading standard when
|
8 |
fraud is the predicate act for the Section 2 claim.
|
9 |
MR. CARY: I guess I would respond that the
|
10 |
typical kinds of requirements under Rule 9 are not
|
11 |
ordinarily the kind that will not be able to be met in
|
12 |
an antitrust case of this kind. I mean, it simply asks
|
13 |
you to identify the kinds of statements that were made
|
14 |
and to whom they were made, and so in the
|
15 |
standard-setting context, it would be a statement that
|
16 |
you would agree to license on FRAND terms, for example,
|
17 |
that you did not intend to comply with or that you
|
18 |
represented that there were not patents when, in fact,
|
19 |
after the fact, you revealed the patents. The so-called
|
20 |
heightened pleading requirement I do not think is all
|
21 |
that heightened in this context.
|
22 |
I think in terms of the recklessness element,
|
23 |
there might be some room for divergence for the reasons
|
24 |
that Gil described, that the thrust of the matter, the
|
25 |
crux of the matter in the antitrust case is the |
111
1 |
exploitation of market power, not the niceties of the
|
2 |
precise statements that were made, and I think in the
|
3 |
standard-setting context, especially one where you are a
|
4 |
member of the body that is establishing the standard, I
|
5 |
do not think there is scope for recklessness and then
|
6 |
exploitation of the benefits of that recklessness after
|
7 |
the fact.
|
8 |
So, maybe there is a divergence there, and maybe
|
9 |
there is also a divergence with respect to those states
|
10 |
that have imposed a clear and convincing standard on
|
11 |
fraud allegations, which is by no means the majority of
|
12 |
states, but there are some.
|
13 |
Again, I would say that since the crux of the
|
14 |
matter is the exploitation rather than the deception
|
15 |
that a clear and convincing standard would not have a
|
16 |
place in an antitrust case, whereas it might if what you
|
17 |
are talking about is fraud.
|
18 |
MR. DAGEN: Slide 4.
|
19 |
Given what we have just talked about in terms of
|
20 |
the use or the nonpreclusive effect of the actions under
|
21 |
contract or tort compared to an antitrust case, I was
|
22 |
wondering if anybody had any thoughts about the issue
|
23 |
raised in Trinko about the cost of false positives. I
|
24 |
know Susan talked about it a little, I guess several
|
25 |
panelists talked about it a little, about it not being |
112
1 |
as significant a concern with respect to
|
2 |
misrepresentations, but I was wondering if the panel had
|
3 |
any additional thoughts on that question.
|
4 |
DR. McAFEE: I think one issue that has been
|
5 |
brought up is that while it is true that we do not have
|
6 |
to worry about chilling misleading statements, that is,
|
7 |
we are pretty happy to chill as many misleading
|
8 |
statements as we can, it was also brought up that there
|
9 |
is a fair bit of confusion among engineers, in
|
10 |
particular, about just what the antitrust laws entail
|
11 |
and that the threat of antitrust actions actually scare
|
12 |
the engineers a lot, and I think maybe the middle ground
|
13 |
here is to provide fairly concrete guidance as to what
|
14 |
is allowed and what is not so that we reduce that,
|
15 |
because it would actually be somewhat of a disaster if
|
16 |
companies instead of joining standard-setting
|
17 |
organizations said, well, we are just going to have our
|
18 |
own standard, let them fight it out in the marketplace,
|
19 |
which guarantees that the standard that comes out is
|
20 |
proprietary.
|
21 |
We are actually quite happy, it is quite
|
22 |
procompetitive, to have standards that are practiced by
|
23 |
many companies; that is, common standards that are
|
24 |
practiced by many companies. If you thought about all
|
25 |
batteries -- think about your digital camera, which |
113
1 |
probably has a proprietary battery. That is a much more
|
2 |
expensive proposition than if you have double A
|
3 |
batteries because of the standard associated and
|
4 |
multiple firms practicing it. So, we do not want to
|
5 |
actually have that harm the open standards, and, in
|
6 |
fact, we want to make sure that what we do with Section
|
7 |
2 is encouraging open standards, not discouraging it.
|
8 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I am probably just repeating
|
9 |
what I have said before. I think maybe the one area
|
10 |
where you would be concerned about false positives here
|
11 |
particularly would be chilling advertising unduly,
|
12 |
because that obviously is a positive. I agree with --
|
13 |
who was it -- Michael who made the comment that we are
|
14 |
probably not concerned with chilling having racks pulled
|
15 |
out of the shelves, you know, and we would not be unduly
|
16 |
concerned about chilling blowing up a competitor's
|
17 |
factory, and there is all kinds of conduct we probably
|
18 |
would not be too concerned about chilling.
|
19 |
I guess more generally, on the question of this
|
20 |
specter that is haunting Europe of sort of -- specter
|
21 |
haunting the United States of unduly broadening Section
|
22 |
2 liability, you know, it is not like we have got a huge
|
23 |
number of cases here we are talking about where people
|
24 |
have taken a fraud claim and then tried to turn it into
|
25 |
an antitrust claim. We have got a handful, and I am not |
114
1 |
even sure that it is very likely that we would see very
|
2 |
many, because usually they have to have some kind of
|
3 |
fraudulent relationship, you have to have a relationship
|
4 |
of trust and confidence, and the circumstances in which
|
5 |
companies are going to be engaging in that kind of
|
6 |
relationship would seem to be relatively discrete.
|
7 |
So, I guess while I agree with the Trinko
|
8 |
statement in general, other than advertising, I am not
|
9 |
sure that I see a big issue with chilling.
|
10 |
MR. CARY: I guess that brings to mind one of
|
11 |
the points that Preston made previously about lawyers
|
12 |
wanting to convert contract cases into antitrust cases.
|
13 |
It seems to me that in this regard, when you are talking
|
14 |
about allegations that essentially sound in fraud,
|
15 |
taking that and converting it to an antitrust case is
|
16 |
not something you would do as a matter of course in any
|
17 |
event.
|
18 |
First, you would still have to prove the fraud,
|
19 |
maybe not to a clear and convincing element, but then
|
20 |
you would also have to prove the other elements of an
|
21 |
antitrust case, which just expands your burden, and a
|
22 |
fraud claim is suitable for punitive damages. So,
|
23 |
limiting yourself to treble damages when you could get
|
24 |
punitives in a fraud case, I am not so sure that that is
|
25 |
necessarily the inclination most plaintiffs' lawyers |
115
1 |
would take.
|
2 |
I think what that points out, again, is that
|
3 |
there is a different role for the antitrust law than
|
4 |
there is for the private law of tort or the private law
|
5 |
of contract in this setting.
|
6 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Yeah, I want to make a quick
|
7 |
comment about what Preston said about engineers not
|
8 |
understanding the antitrust laws, and over time it was
|
9 |
not engineers, it was someone else, some other
|
10 |
occupation who does not understand the antitrust laws,
|
11 |
and I am not particularly sympathetic with the engineers
|
12 |
in that setting in the sense that the antitrust laws are
|
13 |
obviously an important segment of our body of law, and
|
14 |
in the engineer's development of a product or technology
|
15 |
or whatever, the engineer has to come to an
|
16 |
understanding with the assistance of counsel or
|
17 |
otherwise, and we proceed. Antitrust obviously at times
|
18 |
maybe we think has gone off course, but hopefully we
|
19 |
bring it back on course. So, I must say, I am not
|
20 |
particularly sympathetic to engineers that are sitting
|
21 |
out there and worrying about the antitrust laws.
|
22 |
DR. McAFEE: All right, I am going to make the
|
23 |
counter case, because what we are asking engineers to do
|
24 |
in the standard-setting situation actually flirts with
|
25 |
directly violating the antitrust laws. So, that is to |
116
1 |
say, we are asking competitors to get together and set a
|
2 |
standard that they are all going to practice. So, there
|
3 |
is a sense in which they are already exposed to risk,
|
4 |
and as a society, we do not like the alternative,
|
5 |
because the alternative is the companies never get
|
6 |
together, they each promote different standards that are
|
7 |
not compatible, and the market chooses one, much like is
|
8 |
happening with DVDs right now.
|
9 |
We have multiple standards. The market chooses
|
10 |
one of them -- actually, does not matter whether you
|
11 |
think about old DVDs where you had plus or minus R or
|
12 |
new DVDs where you have HD and Blu-ray. The market will
|
13 |
choose one that will be proprietary. That is bad for
|
14 |
society. We would be better off as a society if we have
|
15 |
a single standard that everyone agreed on, a useful
|
16 |
standard that all of the companies get to practice.
|
17 |
And so unlike other cases of antitrust law where
|
18 |
we said these are the laws, you have to obey them, here
|
19 |
we are asking firms to get together and do something,
|
20 |
which certainly there is a phrase, "tickles the dragon's
|
21 |
tail," and it certainly tickles the dragon's tail of
|
22 |
antitrust law automatically just because the competitors
|
23 |
are standing in the same room.
|
24 |
So, I would argue, then, that it is incumbent on
|
25 |
us as a society to actually give them instruction so |
117
1 |
that they do not just say, well, we are just not going
|
2 |
to go down that road. We are going to stay in our own
|
3 |
labs and never meet, because those meetings do actually
|
4 |
result in standards that are good for society.
|
5 |
MR. OHANA: I agree with Preston. I would just
|
6 |
make the point that over-emphasis on antitrust risk and
|
7 |
the idea that in some sense standards development is so
|
8 |
fraught that engineers cannot ask probing questions
|
9 |
about whether technology is patented, how much it will
|
10 |
cost to practice, et cetera, creates the risk of
|
11 |
significant inefficiencies as well, and you have to find
|
12 |
a balance here between recognizing the potential for
|
13 |
Section 1 problems in standard-setting and facilitating
|
14 |
the risk of Section 2 problems.
|
15 |
DR. McAFEE: I want to make an unrelated remark
|
16 |
on something that Susan has said several times. She has
|
17 |
referred to advertising as a good. This is -- I would
|
18 |
say that it is actually an emerging consensus among
|
19 |
economists, but it is hardly something -- if you went
|
20 |
back 15 years and polled economists, you probably would
|
21 |
not find 50 percent agreeing with that, although that
|
22 |
number has grown dramatically, so it is actually -- and
|
23 |
sometimes it is very cutting edge for the FTC to be
|
24 |
promoting that as its view, is that advertising is
|
25 |
itself a good. Everyone understood that informative |
118
1 |
advertising is a good, but advertising which is not
|
2 |
directly informative, some sort of brand positioning
|
3 |
advertising and that kind of thing, to view that as a
|
4 |
good is actually very -- looks to the future.
|
5 |
An example of this, I think perhaps the most
|
6 |
extreme example, is playground equipment. There are
|
7 |
playground equipment companies that actually advertise
|
8 |
that their rivals' products -- and they name them --
|
9 |
kill children. Now, this is advertising we would not
|
10 |
want to chill, whether it is -- well, if it is false
|
11 |
obviously we would like to chill it, but on the other
|
12 |
hand, you have got to have -- you have to view that as
|
13 |
sort of a risky ad, especially because there is a sense
|
14 |
in which all playground equipment kills children in the
|
15 |
sense that there is stuff that you can do that will kill
|
16 |
you if you fall off it, for example, not used as
|
17 |
directed. This is -- the advertising here -- so,
|
18 |
advertising in the playground equipment area is
|
19 |
particularly extreme, and it is actually worth going and
|
20 |
getting the brochures. It is a pretty entertaining
|
21 |
example.
|
22 |
MR. DAGEN: That actually reminds me of an FTC
|
23 |
consent that we had a few years ago which involved
|
24 |
bullet-proof vest manufacturers having an agreement not
|
25 |
to engage in any sort of comparative advertising, so |
119
1 |
they -- don't tell them -- we won't tell them yours
|
2 |
fails if you don't tell them ours fails. Similar to the
|
3 |
playground equipment in terms of mortality rates, I
|
4 |
think.
|
5 |
MR. WELLFORD: Let me ask one question, which is
|
6 |
taking it outside the standard-setting context, which is
|
7 |
probably special, if misleading conduct is such an
|
8 |
anticompetitive problem, why is it so absolutely common
|
9 |
between rivals in industries? And two examples I'll
|
10 |
make, and then you can react -- anyone, I will throw
|
11 |
this to Susan first perhaps -- as to whether there would
|
12 |
be necessarily an anticompetitive problem raised.
|
13 |
One is competitors are attempting to discover
|
14 |
your trade secrets by aggressive but legal means, and
|
15 |
your response is to start putting out misinformation so
|
16 |
that they will not. That is an extremely common fact
|
17 |
pattern. Does that raise concerns if they are a
|
18 |
dominant competitor? Is that part of the rough and
|
19 |
tumble of competition?
|
20 |
The other is if you are a dominant maker of a
|
21 |
particular product, are you permitted to do what lots of
|
22 |
product makers do, Sony with the PS3 or any variety of
|
23 |
car makers have done this, put out fake test products in
|
24 |
the market and do fake tests with consumer groups in the
|
25 |
hopes that your rivals will find out about the fake |
120
1 |
tests and then try to design towards that fake thing
|
2 |
when you have got something real?
|
3 |
If you are a dominant competitor, do either of
|
4 |
those raise concerns in the fact that they are common
|
5 |
does not necessarily make them okay, as we have seen in
|
6 |
the cartel area?
|
7 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I guess I am having a hard time
|
8 |
seeing how either would be likely to create and maintain
|
9 |
durable market power, which I hope I was clear about,
|
10 |
but I think that that really is the crux of -- the
|
11 |
question is, if we have inefficient conduct that we
|
12 |
believe causes durable market power, that is what we are
|
13 |
trying to get at, and so we are not -- and, in fact,
|
14 |
part of my point had been we are not trying to make
|
15 |
torts a predicate act for antitrust. In fact, that is
|
16 |
exactly the wrong way to think about it.
|
17 |
So, the fact that this is conduct that you may
|
18 |
or may not like or might or might not be good, unless I
|
19 |
could see some way in which it was likely to be creating
|
20 |
durable market power, I would not care from an antitrust
|
21 |
perspective.
|
22 |
MR. DAGEN: Just following up on Hill's question
|
23 |
then, the mere fact that it raises your rivals' costs in
|
24 |
this context would not be sufficient in your mind? They
|
25 |
are either going down the wrong path I think was -- Hill |
121
1 |
was suggesting or they have to counter, take some
|
2 |
counter -- so it raises their costs in the short run
|
3 |
potentially.
|
4 |
DR. McAFEE: I would actually object to that as
|
5 |
being characterized as raising rivals' costs.
|
6 |
MR. DAGEN: Okay.
|
7 |
DR. McAFEE: The rivals who have actually chosen
|
8 |
to investigate whatever they investigate, putting out,
|
9 |
you know, memos that say we are investigating this, the
|
10 |
rivals are free not to follow that, and, in fact, that
|
11 |
is -- I would say generally, the rivals are the best
|
12 |
informed. The general public is much more likely to be
|
13 |
misled, which is usually damaging to the originator.
|
14 |
So, if Sony says, well, we are going to deliver this,
|
15 |
and then they do not, that is harmful to Sony, not so
|
16 |
much to Microsoft.
|
17 |
MR. DAGEN: Why don't we head to slide 3. I
|
18 |
think we have had a lot of discussion about a lot of
|
19 |
these topics, and that was the purpose of this panel.
|
20 |
So, slide 3, "The jury could have found that --" this is
|
21 |
from Conwood -- "that USTC maintained its monopoly power
|
22 |
by engaging in the challenged conduct," and I would like
|
23 |
to focus this on causation issues.
|
24 |
So, what kind of causal connection must be shown
|
25 |
between misleading conduct and the creation of or |
122
1 |
preservation of monopoly power? I think it was -- well,
|
2 |
Michael or Gil, one of them talked about what you would
|
3 |
have to show, and we would like to consider that issue a
|
4 |
little more.
|
5 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, let me go first. Yeah,
|
6 |
basically what I had said was that you would need to
|
7 |
show -- I used the word institutional, that is, getting
|
8 |
away from the mistakes or the rogue district manager or
|
9 |
whatever, that is, that it was a conscious decision that
|
10 |
was corporate policy.
|
11 |
Secondly, that it was pervasive, and I thought a
|
12 |
little bit about how I would measure pervasive, and I
|
13 |
think I would -- what I suggested on the slide is
|
14 |
relative to the relevant geographic market. So, the
|
15 |
question is how much was there.
|
16 |
And then finally, ultimately, that it harmed the
|
17 |
competitive process, that somehow, in the case of
|
18 |
Conwood, that the throwing away of the racks and so on
|
19 |
and so forth harmed the competitive process among
|
20 |
Conwood and U.S. Tobacco.
|
21 |
As I mentioned earlier, I think it is a classic
|
22 |
case of what happens when you have private litigation in
|
23 |
front of a jury in that I just think about it as myself,
|
24 |
as I am sitting here, I am a juror and not an antitrust
|
25 |
lawyer, and I sit there, and here I have got a |
123
1 |
monopolist who is undertaking these acts.
|
2 |
Now, one key, of course, is I think you have to
|
3 |
distinguish -- and the judge has to instruct the jury in
|
4 |
a way to distinguish between what was deceptive or
|
5 |
misleading and what was procompetitive. For example,
|
6 |
responding to WalMart or whoever it was, the
|
7 |
competition, to have a rack, or even being the category
|
8 |
captain or whatever, you know, in and of itself, those
|
9 |
are not necessarily deceptive at all, and it is
|
10 |
important that the court, in instructing the jury,
|
11 |
allowed the jury to sort that out, and, in fact, would
|
12 |
have to.
|
13 |
So, to me, again, as I said earlier, I think
|
14 |
Conwood is just a classic case of a jury's reaction to
|
15 |
the evidence presented.
|
16 |
DR. McAFEE: This is also probably a good time
|
17 |
to remember that the antitrust laws are designed to
|
18 |
protect competition and not competitors and that that is
|
19 |
an easy mistake for a jury to make, because it is a
|
20 |
somewhat subtle distinction, but that deceptive act
|
21 |
should be viewed in that light, is does this actually
|
22 |
affect competition in the industry or does this affect
|
23 |
just one competitor in the industry.
|
24 |
MR. DAGEN: I think one of the allegations in
|
25 |
Conwood was that as category manager, they were |
124
1 |
supplying false information about their sales and their
|
2 |
competitors' sales, and there was some talk about
|
3 |
whether the information maybe was in public information,
|
4 |
easily rebuttable.
|
5 |
Does anybody have any sense of where that sort
|
6 |
of conversation would occur, where on the line that
|
7 |
would be?
|
8 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, one -- I hate to use this
|
9 |
word, but when I thought about that -- and I teach
|
10 |
Conwood in my antitrust class, okay, I like Conwood for
|
11 |
teaching students, and the word that comes to my mind --
|
12 |
I hate to use it -- is whether, in fact, U.S. Tobacco
|
13 |
took on I am going to say fiduciary responsibility when
|
14 |
it became the category captain to provide that
|
15 |
information. Yeah, the person from Kroeger or whatever
|
16 |
said, I made my own decision, and U.S. Tobacco was not
|
17 |
going to sway me, but the point being is that once U.S.
|
18 |
Tobacco took on those responsibilities, I think it had a
|
19 |
bit of a higher standard of conduct than it would
|
20 |
otherwise have as a competitor going in and pitching
|
21 |
information, because it had committed to Kroeger or
|
22 |
WalMart or whomever to provide information not only
|
23 |
about itself, but about the competition as well, in a
|
24 |
role different than being just a competitor in the
|
25 |
market. |
125
1 |
MR. OHANA: Let me maybe disagree with that a
|
2 |
little bit having advised on category management issues
|
3 |
over time. You always tell your clients when they have
|
4 |
been appointed, annointed, category captain that they
|
5 |
should provide truthful information to the retailer, but
|
6 |
it seems to me that the retailer knows the biases of the
|
7 |
category captain, that it is going to design a planogram
|
8 |
that promotes its products, and if you think that the
|
9 |
incentives of the retailer in any way parallel the
|
10 |
consumer welfare, then the idea that the dominant
|
11 |
company that is appointed category captain has some kind
|
12 |
of special obligation to be truthful seems odd to me.
|
13 |
This is not the context like the ones the FTC
|
14 |
identified in the Rambus case where you are talking
|
15 |
about a cooperative enterprise. There is a fierce
|
16 |
competition for shelf space. Everybody knows what the
|
17 |
biases of category captain are, and if the competitors
|
18 |
ever feel that they are being discriminated against by
|
19 |
the behavior of the category captain filtered through
|
20 |
the retailer, they know Kroeger's phone number.
|
21 |
MR. DAGEN: In terms of causation, Judge
|
22 |
Easterbrook in Sanderson distinguishes cases from
|
23 |
Hydrolevel and says Hydrolevel had an enforcement
|
24 |
mechanism by virtue of codes being adopted based on the
|
25 |
conduct in the standard-setting organization, and he |
126
1 |
says in Sanderson there is just basically speech. Does
|
2 |
there have to be an enforcement mechanism of some sort
|
3 |
in either government or standards or some other means
|
4 |
before the requisite causation can be shown in one of
|
5 |
these misrepresentation cases?
|
6 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I guess I'd say no and cite U.S.
|
7 |
v. Microsoft. In the diluted Java, for example, there
|
8 |
was no enforcement mechanism. It was cooperative in the
|
9 |
sense that the standard-setting process is cooperative,
|
10 |
but the representation was come build to Microsoft Java
|
11 |
because all the applications that you build will be
|
12 |
interoperable with Sun's Java, and people had no reason
|
13 |
to suspect that those representations were not true, so
|
14 |
they went ahead and built applications using Microsoft's
|
15 |
version of Java and then discovered that, lo and behold,
|
16 |
they had just collectively created a library of programs
|
17 |
that would only run on Microsoft. So, there was no
|
18 |
enforcement mechanism there that I can identify other
|
19 |
than the fact that it was a network market, but
|
20 |
nonetheless, I think that that decision -- that the
|
21 |
Justice Department was correct in pursuing that claim
|
22 |
and the D.C. Circuit in upholding it.
|
23 |
MR. CARY: It seems to me that the issue is
|
24 |
durability, not enforcement, and the question is from
|
25 |
what does that durability derive? Does it derive from |
127
1 |
network effects, from existing monopoly and interfaces,
|
2 |
does it derive from enforceability, does it derive from
|
3 |
the incorporation of a standard? It could be any of
|
4 |
those.
|
5 |
MR. DAGEN: If we could go to slide 7, this
|
6 |
states, "The Federal Trade Commission may consider
|
7 |
public values beyond simply those enshrined in the
|
8 |
letter or encompassed in the spirit of the antitrust
|
9 |
laws." That is from Sperry and Hutchinson, 1972.
|
10 |
So, one of the questions that arises in
|
11 |
connection with this agency, the FTC, is whether Section
|
12 |
5 gives the Commission a different role to play in
|
13 |
policing deceptive conduct than Section 2 of the Sherman
|
14 |
Act.
|
15 |
DR. ROZEK: One of the most difficult things to
|
16 |
deal with is arbitrariness on the part of the antitrust
|
17 |
agencies or any regulatory agency. If it is going to be
|
18 |
difficult for both buyers and sellers to understand what
|
19 |
the policies are going to be or the enforcement
|
20 |
policies, just introducing some arbitrariness into the
|
21 |
process, then I think there is a social cost to that.
|
22 |
For example, one of the things that is very
|
23 |
helpful in terms of enforcement of the antitrust laws
|
24 |
are the Merger Guidelines. You have Guidelines that
|
25 |
tell you how the antitrust agencies are going to look at |
128
1 |
these things, and they follow those Guidelines. They
|
2 |
have essentially become de facto the standard for doing
|
3 |
competition analyses even in private cases.
|
4 |
To the extent that there is a hidden agenda or
|
5 |
there is a hidden policy trying to be achieved, laws are
|
6 |
going to be applied in an arbitrary manner. I do not
|
7 |
think that does a service to buyers or sellers or to
|
8 |
firms or consumers.
|
9 |
MR. DAGEN: We talked a little bit about treble
|
10 |
damage actions. The other remedy often available is
|
11 |
injunctive relief. Would that influence the standard
|
12 |
that anyone would recommend as to what sort of conduct
|
13 |
might be actionable, whether there is simply injunctive
|
14 |
relief or whether there is treble damages also
|
15 |
available?
|
16 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Is your question in the context
|
17 |
of Section 5 or generally?
|
18 |
MR. DAGEN: More generally.
|
19 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Okay.
|
20 |
MR. OHANA: Bringing it back to the context of
|
21 |
Section 5, I have the blessing and curse, as does Susan,
|
22 |
of being a California admitted lawyer where we have the
|
23 |
experience of private actions for injunctive relief
|
24 |
under 17-200 recently, and I note this is a cautionary
|
25 |
tale, narrowed significantly by state ballot referendum, |
129
1 |
and the pattern in those cases is that the fact that you
|
2 |
can only get an injunction and not money damages did not
|
3 |
inhibit the creativity of people in using that law for
|
4 |
some truly bizarre ends.
|
5 |
MR. DAGEN: Anybody else?
|
6 |
DR. McAFEE: There has been a little boom in
|
7 |
sending out cease and desist letters for spurious
|
8 |
copyright violations, for example. So, if I mention a
|
9 |
company's name and mention their product, they may send
|
10 |
me a cease and desist letter saying you are not allowed
|
11 |
to mention our name because it is a copyright or it is
|
12 |
trademarked, and that seems to be a case where something
|
13 |
beyond -- and these are not necessarily antitrust
|
14 |
issues, but agency action beyond the promote the First
|
15 |
Amendment, for example, might be called for, and so
|
16 |
insofar as other laws have a bearing on this, you might
|
17 |
want to be selective about enforcement or go beyond.
|
18 |
That is, I am going to agree, at least in principle,
|
19 |
that going beyond the letter of the antitrust laws might
|
20 |
be actually desirable in some circumstances, especially
|
21 |
as technologies move very rapidly.
|
22 |
MS. CREIGHTON: And just going back to your
|
23 |
Section 5 point, I guess I would say that I think
|
24 |
inefficient conduct that causes durable market power is
|
25 |
actionable under Section 2, is actionable under Section |
130
1 |
5, and I do not think we need to extend or should extend
|
2 |
Section 5 to go beyond that to reach other kinds of
|
3 |
conduct.
|
4 |
MR. CARY: I guess I would slightly disagree
|
5 |
with Gil also as a California admitted lawyer.
|
6 |
MR. OHANA: Oh, sorry.
|
7 |
MR. CARY: I think it does make a difference
|
8 |
that 17-200 is limited to injunctive relief in terms of
|
9 |
what kind of damage it can cause to pursue the more
|
10 |
frivolous claims. I think the ability to get a motion
|
11 |
to dismiss on the damage claims granted, leaving only a
|
12 |
17-200 claim, is significant and to some degree I think
|
13 |
addresses some of the anticompetitive motives of
|
14 |
bringing antitrust litigation that Preston has
|
15 |
mentioned, and it leaves you in a position of simply
|
16 |
litigating before a judge and not a jury a novel theory,
|
17 |
which I do not think is quite so bad as facing the
|
18 |
barrel of treble damages.
|
19 |
MR. OHANA: This may be an area where the
|
20 |
perspective of inside and outside counsel may differ to
|
21 |
some degree. We do not enjoy 17-200 cases even though
|
22 |
there is no ultimate risk of damages because litigating
|
23 |
them is expensive, time-consuming and difficult, and
|
24 |
yes, it is somewhat better that there is no risk of
|
25 |
damages, let alone treble damages, at the end, but that |
131
1 |
does not make the conversation with your general counsel
|
2 |
over how much you have spent on what is a completely
|
3 |
baseless action any easier.
|
4 |
MR. CARY: One man's cost is another man's
|
5 |
revenue.
|
6 |
MR. OHANA: I guess that's right.
|
7 |
MR. DAGEN: Turning to a variation on the
|
8 |
subject, are there any safe harbors in the area of
|
9 |
misleading or deceptive conduct that the panel would
|
10 |
suggest or panelists?
|
11 |
While you are pondering that, I will pose the
|
12 |
follow-up, which is what about in specific conduct
|
13 |
areas, the context of SSOs or false advertising or
|
14 |
patent abuse?
|
15 |
MR. CARY: I have got one example. I would go
|
16 |
back to the sham litigation example. It would seem to
|
17 |
me that if you are within Federal Rule of Civil
|
18 |
Procedure 11, which requires a reasonable basis for the
|
19 |
pleading, that being sued as an antitrust defendant for
|
20 |
sham litigation ought to be dismissed as a matter of
|
21 |
law. There ought to be a safe harbor if you have met
|
22 |
appropriate pleading standards. There should not be a
|
23 |
heightened standard for what might constitute sham
|
24 |
litigation.
|
25 |
DR. McAFEE: What if it is 200 sham litigations? |
132
1 |
That is, it is not one, but we have sued 200
|
2 |
different -- so, I am thinking about the Recording
|
3 |
Industry Association of America. We have sued hundreds
|
4 |
of different defendants. So, we are doing it over and
|
5 |
over and over again. It is not clear to me that,
|
6 |
especially when it is against small defendants, that
|
7 |
there should be a safe harbor. I agree about one, but I
|
8 |
am not so sure I agree with many.
|
9 |
MR. CARY: Well, I think you are back to the
|
10 |
question of whether the lawsuit is reasonably calculated
|
11 |
to yield the result that you are seeking in the case or
|
12 |
whether it is calculated to reach some other result, and
|
13 |
I am not sure the number should make a difference if
|
14 |
each one of them independently would be deemed a
|
15 |
reasonable assertion of a copyright or a patent.
|
16 |
MR. OHANA: This is the first time anyone from
|
17 |
Silicon Valley defends the RIAA, but it seems to me if
|
18 |
they bring 200 cases against 200 accused copyright
|
19 |
infringers, those are all fair cases.
|
20 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I think what Preston is talking
|
21 |
about is the kind of case that would meet what is
|
22 |
referred to as the pattern exception to Noerr, where it
|
23 |
is filed without regard to whether it is true or not,
|
24 |
and so, you know, you are going to have a coin toss
|
25 |
chance of it being true or not, but -- actually I am |
133
1 |
blanking on the name of the Second Circuit case where
|
2 |
they challenged each and every satellite certificate.
|
3 |
MR. CARY: Right.
|
4 |
MS. CREIGHTON: Primetime. So, it seems to me
|
5 |
that if you could satisfy the pattern exception in
|
6 |
Noerr, that would also stand up in antitrust law.
|
7 |
MR. CARY: Potentially it does under current law
|
8 |
in the Second Circuit and perhaps in the Ninth Circuit,
|
9 |
but I am questioning whether it should, especially in
|
10 |
the case of intellectual property where one of the
|
11 |
requirements for protecting the intellectual property is
|
12 |
that you have zealously protected that intellectual
|
13 |
property. The idea that then you could be charged with
|
14 |
an antitrust violation for having done what the patent
|
15 |
law requires you to do or the copyright law requires you
|
16 |
to do is problematic, and I think the key goes back to
|
17 |
your predicate, which is "without regard to the merits."
|
18 |
There is a distinction between bringing a case
|
19 |
which satisfies Rule 11, because you have a case that is
|
20 |
reasonably litigable on the one hand; and one that you
|
21 |
bring with no basis, which would violate Rule 11, in
|
22 |
which case if it has the requisite competitive effect,
|
23 |
there should be an antitrust remedy.
|
24 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: George, I need to give a small
|
25 |
refinement to your point, and I am not disagreeing with |
134
1 |
you, but I am aware of circumstances where the initial
|
2 |
bringing of the suit met Rule 11, but during discovery,
|
3 |
it then, at that point during discovery, the plaintiff
|
4 |
learned that there was no basis for the suit such that
|
5 |
at that point then obviously if it pursues the case
|
6 |
after that, then I think there is an issue for sham
|
7 |
litigation. Now, whether that piece of litigation is
|
8 |
exclusionary, that I do not know, but I would not agree
|
9 |
that the safe harbor is, well, if you are okay at the
|
10 |
initial filing of the suit, you are okay, because,
|
11 |
again, of the circumstances I have discussed with you.
|
12 |
MR. CARY: Yeah, I think I recognize that
|
13 |
distinction, and I do not totally disagree with that. I
|
14 |
think it gets very complicated, though, because in that
|
15 |
context, now you are talking about work product and
|
16 |
attorney-client privileged communications, and it gets
|
17 |
very complicated to assess at what point you are
|
18 |
obligated to drop that kind of lawsuit.
|
19 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, but the problem is in the
|
20 |
patent arena you may learn during discovery of the
|
21 |
fraud.
|
22 |
MR. CARY: Fair enough.
|
23 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Okay?
|
24 |
MR. CARY: Yeah.
|
25 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I think I would probably |
135
1 |
disagree with you, George, about the adequacy of Rule 11
|
2 |
sufficiently to guard against that anticompetitive
|
3 |
effect, because I think what you are proposing -- well,
|
4 |
usually my understanding of Rule 11 is an objective
|
5 |
standard, and so if you file every lawsuit and then it
|
6 |
turns out half of them are meritless, you get half of
|
7 |
them dismissed, but you have still raised rivals' costs,
|
8 |
and that is just sort of the willy-nilly filing, and to
|
9 |
your earlier point about a judge being able to serve as
|
10 |
an adequate gate-keeper, I do not think a judge
|
11 |
typically can serve as an adequate gate-keeper to that
|
12 |
kind of pattern of filing.
|
13 |
DR. McAFEE: Gemstar is alleged to be an example
|
14 |
of that.
|
15 |
MR. DAGEN: In terms of a kind of the safe
|
16 |
harbor, there is a Sixth Circuit case involving
|
17 |
podiatrists which looked at a multipart test and said to
|
18 |
survive summary judgment on a Section 2 case, you have
|
19 |
to show at least that there is a factual dispute, that
|
20 |
the statements were clearly false, and two, that they
|
21 |
were difficult or costly for plaintiff to counter. Is
|
22 |
that something that panelists would agree with?
|
23 |
DR. BROCKMEYER: Well, the problem with that
|
24 |
decision was that the Sixth Circuit adopted what I
|
25 |
indicated in my slides we should not have, which is |
136
1 |
there was a rebuttable presumption, and George or
|
2 |
someone said this earlier, we are now getting somewhat
|
3 |
into procedural law. I do not think it is appropriate
|
4 |
to have the rebuttable presumption. So, in the first
|
5 |
instance, I would disagree with that case, and I think
|
6 |
they filed a Ninth Circuit case as well.
|
7 |
MR. DAGEN: Another statement in that case was
|
8 |
that there is no liability if the statements are simply
|
9 |
misleading as opposed -- and that court talks about
|
10 |
Matsushita and what we have talked about earlier with
|
11 |
Verizon and the danger of chilling procompetitive
|
12 |
conduct, and the Sixth Circuit is saying if it is simply
|
13 |
misleading, and I think they mean by that not
|
14 |
intentionally, if you cannot show from the beginning
|
15 |
that it was an intentional misrepresentation, but if it
|
16 |
is just a statement that turns out to mislead people,
|
17 |
then they would dismiss the case on those grounds.
|
18 |
MR. CARY: In the Walker Process context, that
|
19 |
kind of distinction is an important one. In patent
|
20 |
litigation, there is always something in the file,
|
21 |
especially if it is a complicated product deserving of a
|
22 |
patent, something in the file that one can point to as
|
23 |
being slightly irregular or perhaps not as articulate as
|
24 |
it might have been or using a term of art in a
|
25 |
particular way that is distinct from how some future |
137
1 |
juror might interpret that.
|
2 |
Those kinds of technical issues that may or may
|
3 |
not give rise to inequitable conduct, it seems to me
|
4 |
that the judge does have an obligation to keep those
|
5 |
kind of, quote unquote, "simply misleading statements"
|
6 |
away from a jury and that some greater showing should be
|
7 |
required before a Walker Process fraud allegation could
|
8 |
be sustained.
|
9 |
MS. CREIGHTON: I guess I would repeat what I
|
10 |
have said before, which is I think the -- sort of the
|
11 |
intent element that seems implicit there maybe is a bit
|
12 |
misleading. I keep -- this analogy may be more
|
13 |
confusing than helpful, but I have tended to think of
|
14 |
like opportunism in contract. If a taxi driver picks me
|
15 |
up at the airport and says, you know, ten bucks, and
|
16 |
then pulls away and, you know, two miles later pulls
|
17 |
over to the side of the road and says, you know, I will
|
18 |
either let you out here or it will be a hundred bucks,
|
19 |
is probably not that relevant to me whether he thought
|
20 |
about that at the time he picked me up or only after we
|
21 |
left the airport, you know, it is still robbery.
|
22 |
And so in the same way, I do not know that it
|
23 |
would have mattered to my analysis if a Microsoft said,
|
24 |
go ahead and create, you know, applications using
|
25 |
Microsoft Java, it will interoperate, and at the time |
138
1 |
the person said that, he meant it and was sincere, went
|
2 |
back home, and somebody said, well, actually, that is
|
3 |
not true, all these people are only going to be able to
|
4 |
write applications that work on our product, and he
|
5 |
said, oh, yeah, that is a pretty nice fact, why don't we
|
6 |
just keep that ourselves?
|
7 |
I am not sure that the intent at the time of the
|
8 |
statement is really -- for antitrust purposes, that may
|
9 |
sometimes be more confusing.
|
10 |
MR. CARY: Yes, I completely agree with that,
|
11 |
and I think this goes back to Gil's distinction between
|
12 |
exploitation and deception in the first instance. One
|
13 |
can imagine, for example, a scenario where someone in
|
14 |
good faith enters into a FRAND obligation, and then a
|
15 |
year later, the CEO changes, and there is pressure on
|
16 |
the stock, and he comes up with a brilliant idea, why
|
17 |
don't we just increase the royalties on these patents?
|
18 |
It would seem to me that that kind of exploitation is
|
19 |
just as much an antitrust violation as one with the
|
20 |
deceptive intent in the first instance.
|
21 |
MR. OHANA: And since we are in the world of
|
22 |
patent trolls and nonproducing entities, the fact
|
23 |
pattern that George just described is not one that is
|
24 |
unfamiliar to many of us where incentives change after a
|
25 |
patent is disclosed subject to a RAND obligation, and |
139
1 |
what you thought was RAND based on what you perceived to
|
2 |
be the incentives of the party making the declaration
|
3 |
turns out to be quite wrong, often with significant
|
4 |
economic consequences.
|
5 |
At that point, I don't really care a whole lot
|
6 |
about whether the initial statement was made with guile
|
7 |
or opportunism. What I care about is the economic
|
8 |
consequence at the end.
|
9 |
DR. ROZEK: I think when you are talking about
|
10 |
safe harbor as being a more objective standard to apply,
|
11 |
like again, using the Merger Guidelines as an example,
|
12 |
with the Herfindahl Index standards in the Merger
|
13 |
Guideline. It is a more direct standard, easy to apply.
|
14 |
By contrast, whether something is misleading or not
|
15 |
misleading is difficult to determine with a bright line
|
16 |
rule. It would be harder in this context to have a safe
|
17 |
harbor as compared to the merger standard.
|
18 |
MR. DAGEN: Well, it is now approximately 1:00.
|
19 |
There are many other issues that we could have covered
|
20 |
today, but I think we have covered a lot of ground, and
|
21 |
I wanted to thank both the panelists and again the FTC
|
22 |
staff and DOJ staff who put pretty much all of this
|
23 |
together, and thank Hill. I would like to thank
|
24 |
everybody for being here, the panelists especially for
|
25 |
taking time out to educate us today, and I would like to |
140
1 |
ask the audience to give one final round of applause.
|
2 |
(Applause.)
|
3 |
(Whereupon, at 1:02 p.m., the hearing was
|
4 |
concluded.)
|
5 |
|
6 |
|
7 |
|
8 |
|
9 |
|
10 |
|
11 |
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
|
16 |
|
17 |
|
18 |
|
19 |
|
20 |
|
21 |
|
22 |
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
|
141
1 |
C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F R E P O R T E R.
|
2 |
DOCKET/FILE NUMBER: P062106
|
3 |
CASE TITLE: SECTION 2 HEARING
|
4 |
DATE: DECEMBER 6, 2006
|
5 |
|
6 |
I HEREBY CERTIFY that the transcript contained
|
7 |
herein is a full and accurate transcript of the notes
|
8 |
taken by me at the hearing on the above cause before the
|
9 |
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION to the best of my knowledge and
|
10 |
belief.
|
11 |
|
12 |
|
13 |
|
14 |
|
15 |
|
16 |
|
SUSANNE BERGLING, RMR-CLR |
|
17 |
|
18 |
C E R T I F I C A T I O N O F P R O O F R E A D E R
|
19 |
|
20 |
I HEREBY CERTIFY that I proofread the transcript
|
21 |
for accuracy in spelling, hyphenation, punctuation and
|
22 |
format.
|
23 |
|
24 |
|
25 |
|
|