Skip to main content

Declaration Of David Sibley

This document is available in two formats: this web page (for browsing content) and PDF (comparable to original document formatting). To view the PDF you will need Acrobat Reader, which may be downloaded from the Adobe site. For an official signed copy, please contact the Antitrust Documents Group.
 

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA



UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,    

                  Plaintiff,

                  v.

MICROSOFT CORPORATION,

                  Defendant.
 


|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|         
Civil Action No:

DECLARATION OF
DAVID S. SIBLEY

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Table of Contents

  1. Qualifications and Introduction
  2. Microsoft Has Monopoly Power In the Operating System Market
  3. Microsoft's Bundling and Contractual Restrictions on the Use of Competing Browsers are Anticompetitive
    1. A Summary of Anticompetitive Restrictions Enforced by Microsoft on the Use of Competing Browsers
    2. Are Microsoft's Restrictions on the Use of Competing Browsers Justified by Economic Efficiency Considerations?
      1. OEM Restrictions
      2. Browser Restrictions for ISPs, ICPs, and Online Services
    3. Would Microsoft's Contractual Restrictions be Profitable but for Their Effects in Impeding Competition in the OS Market?
    4. What are the Effects of Microsoft's Giving Away Its Browser?
  4. Microsoft Will Recoup the Opportunity Costs of its Contractual Restrictions byMaintaining its Operating System Monopoly
  5. Conclusions

Declaration of David S. Sibley

I. Qualifications and Introduction

1. My name is David S. Sibley. I am the John Michael Stuart Centennial Professor of Economics at the University of Texas at Austin. I received the degree of B A. in Economics from Stanford University in 1969 and a Ph.D. in Economics from Yale University in 1973. In addition to my current teaching responsibilities, I have taught graduate level courses in economics at the University of Pennsylvania and Princeton University. Prior to joining the University of Texas. I was Head of the Economics Research Group at Bell Communications Research. I have also served as a Member of the Technical Staff in economics at Bell Laboratories. During the last twenty-five years, I have carried out extensive research in the areas of industrial organization, microeconomic theory, and regulation. My publications have appeared in a number of leading economic journals, including the Journal of Economic Theory, Review of Economic Studies, Rand Journal of Economics, American Economic Review, Economeirica, and the International Economic Review, among others. I am also a co-author (with Steven J, Brown) of a leading textbook on monopoly pricing, THE THEORY OF PUBLIC UTILITY PRICING, which was first published by Cambridge University Press in 1986 and is now in its fourth printing. A copy of my curriculum vitae is attached to this declaration.1

2. I have been asked by the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice to examine the competitive effects of Microsoft Corporation's ("Microsoft's") contractual restrictions (including the bundling of its Internet browser with the Windows 98 operating system) in its agreements with personal computer original equipment manufacturers ("PC manufacturers" or "OEMs"), Internet access providers ("IAPs"), and Internet content providers ("ICPs"), In particular, I examined Microsoft's bundling and other contractual practices to determine whether these actions represent anticompetitive behavior undertaken by Microsoft to maintain a monopoly in the market for operating system software used to run Intel-compatible desktop PCs ("PC operating system market," or "OS market"), I also studied whether Microsoft's actions represent anticompetitive behavior undertaken to establish a monopoly in the market for browsers.

3. In conducting this analysis, I examined: (1) public documents and websites containing relevant information; (2) certain confidential Microsoft and third party documents supplied to me by the Department of Justice; (3) deposition transcripts of personnel from Microsoft and other companies, including OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs; and (4) relevant books and articles from the economic literature in antitrust and industrial organization.

4. In analyzing the competitive affects of Microsoft's conduct, I proceeded in three steps. Each of these steps, and the conclusions drawn from my analysis of relevant data, are summarized as follows. First, I examined whether Microsoft possesses a dominant share of the PC operating system market, and whether it has monopoly power in that market. I found that Microsoft has monopoly power because of entry barriers in a bottleneck input in computing -- the operating system. Second, I examined whether Microsoft's contractual practices affecting browser choice would be profitable on their own, regardless of its monopoly power; or, alternatively, if the profitability of its practices depended on impeding competition in the operating system and browser markets. In particular, Microsoft appears to be concerned about the potential of the browser to serve as a software applications platform that would run on operating systems other than those produced by Microsoft. I conclude that, if Microsoft were not attempting to impede this type of competition, it would encourage the sale of all browsers (including those of its rivals), since greater browser sales would increase the demand for its operating system and increase the profit which could be obtained from users wanting to access the Internet (e.g.,, by increasing the price of the OS). In fact, I found Microsoft's contractual practices constrained consumers' choice of browsers, thus resulting in a diminution of profits that could most plausibly be recouped only because of competitive restraints in the OS market. Importantly, these contractual restrictions have minimal or non-existent offsetting efficiency justifications. Third, I examined whether Microsoft likely can recoup the reduction in profits resulting from its restrictive practices. I found that Microsoft is likely to recover its lost profits by blunting direct and indirect competitive threats to its OS monopoly and by gaining market power in Internet-related markets, Microsoft's restrictive practices add to the natural entry barriers associated with the OS market by inhibiting the use of competing internet browsers as software applications platforms that are independent of any particular underlying operating system. This deters future entry into the OS market and protects Microsoft's current monopoly power.

5. An alternative line of reasoning leads to the same conclusion as that drawn from the three-step analysis described above. Because contractual agreements with OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs impose exclusionary restrictions on the use of a competing browser, Microsoft blunts the threat to its OS monopoly posed by the browser's potential as an alternative platform for software applications. Based on my review of internal Microsoft documents, these exclusionary restrictions were imposed with this threat very much in mind. Furthermore, the analysis presented below demonstrates that these restrictions have few apparent purposes aside from discouraging the use of competing browsers. These findings, as well as the three-step analysis outlined in paragraph four, lead me to conclude that Microsoft's contractual practices constitute anticompetitive behavior.

6. The development of the high-tech, computer industry has had a profound positive effect on the nation's economy and the economic welfare of all consumers. The growth of software and computer companies has accounted for almost thirty percent of the increase in gross domestic product since 1994, and it is estimated that commerce conducted over the rapidly expanding Internet will surpass $180 billion dollars annually in the beginning of the next millennium.2 The absence of effective competition in two important segments of the software industry (PC operating systems and browsers) will not only affect the price that consumers pay for these products but, perhaps more importantly, it will also change the pattern of innovation that has characterized this dynamic industry. Innovation is a driving force in economic progress because it affects the quality of existing products in the marketplace and the development of new and better products. Actions taken to increase competition in this industry may well be among the most critical economic policy decisions facing the nation today. The artificial entry barriers erected by Microsoft (through its restrictive practices, including bundling) will have the effect of slowing or halting the natural tendency of the marketplace to provide alternative technologies, reducing the welfare of many consumers. If current trends in market share continue, the browser market is likely to tip to a Microsoft monopoly soon, eliminating the competitive threat Microsoft faces from Internet browsers that have the ability to run software applications independent of any particular operating system. If this happens, the Microsoft browser may well become the bottleneck input for Internet-related markets.

II. Microsoft Has Monopoly Power
in the Operating System Market

7. For the purposes of antitrust analysis, the relevant operating system market is the market for personal computer operating systems that are compatible with Intel x86/Pentium (or Intel-compatible) microprocessors. This definition is motivated by the product market definition given in the U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines, and is, in my view, consistent with accepted economic theory.3 A proposed product market defined under the Merger Guidelines is accepted as corret if a price increase in the proposed market would not cause demand to shift to products outside the proposed market to such an extent as to dissuade a hypothetical profit maximizing monopolist from imposing a "small but significant and nontransitory" price increase.4 Because I am evaluating here an allegation of maintaining monopoly power as opposed to evaluating a merger, I adopt this definition with the clarification that the initial price level prior to the price increase be a competitive price level.

8. In order to implement this methodology, I begin by noting that the licensing fee for the vast majority of the operating systems currently licensed by Microsoft to OEMs is approximately $65.5 If a hypothetical monopolist were to increase price by ten percent above this level6, this would represent an increase of no more than four-tenths of one percent in the price of a $1,500 computer, (For a $1,000 computer, the additional $6.50 represents an increase in price of no more than seven-tenths of one percent.) It seems implausible that a price increase of less than one percent would cause a significant number of buyers of PCs with Intel (or Intel-compatible) microprocessors to switch to Apple or UNIX PCs not using an x86 or Pentium chip, let alone forego the purchase of a PC entirely. Industry experts corroborate this conclusion.7 Therefore, a hypothetical monopolist that was the only supplier of operating systems for Intel and Intel-compatible PCs would find it profitable to increase price by ten percent over a competitive level The reasoning is that for an end user to switch from the Intel-based PC to an Apple computer, for example, usually requires the end user to incur substantial switching costs, in both time and money, to learn to use the different system. Moreover, as discussed below, even if the product market were more broadly defined to Include desktop operating systems for all PCs, such as those offered by Apple and UNIX that do not use Intel (or Intel-compatible) microprocessors, Microsoft's market share would fall only slightly (see discussion below) and its monopoly power would remain.8

9. Internet browsers are in a separate relevant product market. An Internet browser is a specialized software program that allows computer users to locate, access, display and use applications located on the Internet's World Wide Web or on internal corporate computer networks known as intranets.9 Today, a browser is the predominant conduit to the Internet and allows computer users to access and view "pages" on the World Wide Web. Browsers constitute a separate product market because a distinct consumer demand exists for browsers, apart from operating systems, as evidenced, for example, by the many PC users who obtain the Internet browsers they use as a stand-alone product apart from the OS.10 In fact, many corporate users purchase only an operating system and do not want a browser at all.11 Moreover, OEMs have a separate demand for a particular browser apart from the Microsoft operating system, as evidenced by CEM's desire to remove the version of Internet Explorer ("IE") packaged with Windows 95 (with the option of replacing IE with another browser).12

10. The view that Internet browsers constitute a separate product market is further supported by the fact that browsers are marketed and distributed independently from PC operating systems. Significantly, Microsoft independently markets, distributes, and monitors the distribution of its Internet Explorer browser software even though it is also bundled with its Windows 95 operating system. In addition, Microsoft intends to offer a version of IE (referred to as IE 5.0} after Windows 98 is released.13 Microsoft's marketing and distribution channels for IE provided apart from its operating system are numerous: IE is available on the Microsoft website for consumers to "download" directly to their PCs; Microsoft has agreements with IAPs that allow them to distribute IE to their subscribers; and Microsoft sells IE as a stand-alone product at retail software outlets. Microsoft has even developed and distributed versions of the IE browser for Apple Computer's Macintosh and the Sun Solaris operating system, both non-Microsoft operating systems. Finally, Netscape, Microsoft's principal browser competitor, also distributes its browser product apart from an operating system.

11. In many software markets, including the OS market, there are fundamental forces which may lead to one firm being dominant at a given time and which tend to create barriers to entry. These forces have been widely discussed in the economics and computing literature. Very briefly, they are as follows:

Economies of Scale. For complex software such as an OS. the initial, or first-copy, costs to writing software are often very large, whereas the incremental cost of producing additional copies is small. Hence, average cost declines as the scale of output rises.

Increasing Returns In Consumption. The larger the market share of a particular OS, the more will independent software vendors ("ISVs") tend to write applications for that OS. The more this happens, the more attractive will customers find that OS, further increasing its market share, leading to more new software applications, and so forth. Thus, increasing returns in consumption induces a series of feedback effects, which tend to make a dominant OS more dominant over time.14

Both economies of scale and increasing returns in consumption, when combined with the lock-in effect created by consumer switching costs discussed below, create natural barriers to entry,

12. Increasing returns to consumption and economies of scale give rise to a phenomenon which lies at the heart of antitrust analysis of network industries: monopoly tipping.15 If a large set of users adopts a new network technology, then that technology becomes more attractive to everyone else due to increasing returns in consumption. As more users join, the technology becomes still more attractive until it becomes dominant; in economic terminology, the market has "tipped" to the new technology. Once tipping has taken place, there are forces that tend to keep the victorious technology dominant until a new, much improved product is developed; incremental improvements are unlikely to be successful. Users invest time and money in learning to use a given technology proficiently. If at some future date a still "newer" technology were to become available, potential users of the newer technology would have already incurred those learning costs on the older one. Therefore, in considering whether or not to adopt the newer technology, potential users would weigh the possible benefits of the newer technology against the switching costs of learning that technology, given that they already know the old technology. Thus, for the newer technology to succeed, it would have to offer a substantial improvement in performance, i.e., enough of an improvement at least to overcome the switching costs associated with the change. In the normal course of markets and competition, such improvements do, in fact, occur. An example is the displacement of slide rules with pocket calculators.

13. The economic theory of network effects describes well the performance of the OS market. As Microsoft itself has stated: "The availability of a rich variety of quality applications software that will ran on a particular operating system is fundamental to its success. This fact has been recognized by publishers of operating systems for years."16 In the computer industry, the theory of network effects is known as "positive feedback." The concept of positive feedback recognizes that as an operating system gains popularity, the incentive to develop software for that operating system grows since the number of potential customers for the application developer is larger. This, in turn, increases the value of the operating system (and likely its market share) which is determined by the quality and variety of software applications written for it. As the OS gains market share, software developers find it even more advantageous to produce additional applications for that system, and so on. As noted by Dr. Nathan Myhrvold, a Senior Vice President of Microsoft, the positive feedback effect has been responsible for the phenomenal strength of leading software products in both applications and operating systems,"17 Dr, Myhrvold also notes that the exchange of data between computer users is facilitated by computer and computer software compatibility. He observes "the laws of positive feedback govern any system where compatibility with other users is either directly or indirectly a key factor in the utility of a product or service."18 Positive feedback explains the importance of the number of complementary software applications and the installed base of these applications as a natural barrier to entry, and also why alternative operating systems already in the market at a small scale (such as Unix) are not effective competitors,

14. A predictable consequence of the installed base of applications is evidenced by Table One, which presents market share information for operating systems that rely on Intel x86/Penttum (or Intel-compatible) microprocessors, Microsoft's market share in each period from 1991 to 1997 holds consistently at about ninety percent.19 Microsoft's OS dominance is stable; has hardly fluctuated in the face of determined attempts at entry by rival operating systems; and is forecast to remain stable in the future.20

Table One
Market Share (%) for Intel-Based
Operating Systems SoldWorldwide

  Year/4
Operating
System/1
1991 1992 1993 1994

1995

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Microsoft/2 93 89 89 91 90 92 92 93 93 93 93
IBM OS/2 0 7 7 6 7 6 6 5 5 5 5
UNIX/3 0.2 0.2 0,2 0.1 0,1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1
Other Intel 7 4 4 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2

Notes:

/1 Operating systems used in single-user client and PC operating environment.

/2 Includes Microsoft 16-bit and 32-bit Windows and MS-DOS.

/3 Intel-based UNIX operating systems.

/4 Market shares may not total 100% due to rounding.

/5 The market shares for the years 1997-2001 are forecasts. ;

Sources:

International Data Corporation (I997), Operating Environments, Review and Forecast 1996-2001
International Data Corporation (I997), Client Operating Environments, Review and Forecast 1996-2001

15. To illustrate the importance of the installed base as an entry barrier, it is instructive to review the experience of IBM's OS/2 operating system. This operating system, first released in 1987, was designed to compete with Microsoft Windows. In 1994 and I995} IBM installed OS/2 on its own Aptiva line of computers, but retailers and consumers routinely demanded software applications that were not available on OS/221 In response, IBM abandoned its practice of installing OS/2 on the Aptiva computer, choosing instead to license Windows from Microsoft.22 Similarly* Packard Bell negotiated with IBM in 1994 to license OS/2 for preinstallation on the Packard Bell PC because Packard Bell was interested in the possible price advantage that OS/2 might offer. But, when IBM stated "in addition to our operating system you need Windows"23 to ensure software compatibility, Packard Bell decided to license Windows from Microsoft directly and not install OS/2,

16. The importance of an installed base of applications software as an entry barrier is further demonstrated in the analysis of Mr. Joachim Kempin, Senior Vice President of OEM Sales for Microsoft. In discussing what could "derail" Microsoft's OS pricing strategy, Mr. Kempin stated:

Our high prices could get a single OEM (Compaq might pay us 750M$ next year) or a coalition to fond a competing effort (say in India). While this possibility exists I consider it doubtful even if they could get a product out that they can market it successfully, leapfrog us and would not deviate from their own standard to differentiate. Could they convince customer [sic] to change their computing platform is the real questions [sic]. The existing investments in training, infrastructure and applications in windows computing are huge and will create a lot of inertia. No kindling of OS on low end systems would be the easiest way to hurt us - but who would want to start with this and loose [sic] business.24

17. Based on the above discussion, it should be clear that in markets such as OS software, certain economic forces can lead naturally to dominance by a single firm, even apart from exclusionary restrictions. (There are, of course, other countervailing factors that tend to perpetuate competition, such as product differentiation,) ff a single firm does achieve dominance, these forces lead to entry barriers which protect that dominance. In themselves these facts do not warrant competitive concern. Preeminence in a market is the market's own way of rewarding excellence. Indeed, there is no reason to think that the market, left to itself, will not generate alternatives to Microsoft's operating system that will be sufficiently superior to overcome the entry barrier advantage that Microsoft enjoys. For example, in an insightful article, Evans and Schmalensee25 point out how tipping was reversed in the case of stereo long playing record players, a technology with a huge installed base of recordings, by the CD technology, which started with no recordings at all.

18. The bundling and other contractual browser restrictions that Microsoft insists upon in its agreements with OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs add artificial entry barriers to those that occur naturally, and are therefore a source of competitive concern. These artificial entry barriers have the effect of slowing or halting the natural tendency of the marketplace to provide alternative technologies that compete with Microsoft. Specifically, these restrictions are currently threatening the potential of competing Internet browsers that can run software applications independently of the Windows operating system and that therefore challenge the dominance of the Windows OS. Bill Gates recognized this threat when he stated: "They (Netscape] are pursuing a multi-platform strategy where they move the key API into the client [browser] to commoditize the underlying operating system." 26 This is the subject of the next section.

III. Microsoft's Bundling and Contractual Restrictions
on the Use of Competing Browsers
are Anticompetitive

19. In this section, I carry out the second step of the three-stage analysis outlined in paragraph four above. After describing the browser restrictions contained in the Microsoft agreements with OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs, I analyze their competitive effects and conclude that they are likely to enable Microsoft to monopolize the browser market, thereby removing the Internet browser as a software platform that can exert competitive pressure on the OS market where Microsoft has monopoly power. I also examine possible legitimate business justifications for the browser restrictions and conclude they are likely to be minimal or non-existent,, so that the main effects of the restrictions are to reduce profit to Microsoft from browsers and the Internet. Such practices therefore appear to make sense only in their entry-deterring effects in the OS market. Finally, I address the issue of Microsoft's distributing its browser without charge,

  1. A Summary of Anticompetitive Restrictions Enforced by Microsoft on
    the Use of Competing Browsers

 

20. Table Two presents a summary of the restrictions in Microsoft agreements with OEMs, IAPs (including online service providers and Internet service providers ("ISPs")), and ICPs which have anticompetitive effects. Taken together, these constitute a powerful force against the use of non-Microsoft browsers in four main distribution channels. (Whether or not these restrictions have countervailing benefits will be discussed in Section IZI.B.)

21. Consider first the OEM agreements. To obtain licenses to preinstall Windows on the PC, OEMs have agreed to restrictions designed to deter them from preinstalling and promoting a competing browser. The requirement that the OEM not modify the OS software has been used to prevent OEMs from offering the OS without the IE browser. It also prevents OEMs from removing the IE icon or replacing it with the

Table Two
Summary of Anticompetitive
Contractual Restrictions Affecting
Browser Promotion and Distribution

Original Equipment Manufacturer Agreements:

Online Service Folder Agreements:

ISP Internet Referral Server Agreements:

icon of a competing browser.27 This requirement is exclusionary even though the OEM has the option of installing a competing browser. While it is true that OEMs may place two browser icons on the desktop, OEMs are generally reluctant to do so for two reasons. First, OEMs believe that the two icons would cause customer confusion, thereby increasing their own "customer support" costs.28 Second, the desktop constitutes scarce real estate to OEMs. As such, OEMs are generally reluctant to preinstall more than one product in each functional category.29

22. Microsoft's Windows license agreements also require that the folders or icons added to the desktop must be substantially the same size and shape as those delivered by Microsoft. This requirement appears innocuous by itself, but biases browser choice since OEMs cannot remove the IE icon. An OEM that wanted to feature a competing browser, but still had to keep the IE icon on die desktop, might wish to have a larger icon for its preferred browser so as to minimize customer confusion and the resulting support calls; however, limitations on size and shape of icons prevent this and bias the OEM away from promoting or preinstalling a competing browser.

23. Three additional OEM browser restrictions affect the initial boot and startup screen, and should be viewed as a group, OEMs cannot alter the content or sequence of screens viewed by the end user on the initial boot of the PC; OEMs cannot insert a screen or image of their own during startup; and OEMs cannot cause a non-Microsoft program to execute on the initial boot, as they could IE, for example. One effect of this set of restrictions is to make the initial boot confusing for unsophisticated users who have a PC with a rival browser preinstalled. In Windows 95, the startup screens all refer to Windows and! IE so that even with another browser preinstalled, the end user cannot see any reference to it until startup is complete and the desktop appears, showing the icon of the preinstalled competing browser. More generally, these restrictions prevent OEMs from featuring another browser or an IAP that promotes a competing browser during the startup sequence prior to the Welcome to Windows screen where Microsoft promotes its own IAP business partners (see paragraph 25 below). Perhaps more importantly, the startup screen restrictions help to strengthen Microsoft's bargaining power with IAPs and ICPs. If OEMs could make their own deals directly with lAPs or ICPs and feature them on screens during the startup sequence, this would tend to devalue Microsoft's provision of access to the Windows desktop. (As I will describe below, the value of space on Microsoft's channel bar, the Online Service Folder, or the Internet Connection Wizard is what induces IAPs and ICPs to agree to Microsoft's restrictions on their use and promotion of competing browsers.)

24. Microsoft's Online Service Folder Agreements provide the three major online services and AT&T Worldnet with a highly desirable position on the Windows desktop - their Internet access software in the Online Service Folder - in exchange for agreeing to restrictions which deter them from distributing or promoting competing browsers.30 The agreements typically specify that an online service provider must distribute IE and not any third party browser with physical distributions of its software and promotional material unless a customer requests that third party browser. The online service provider is not permitted to ship a non-Microsoft browser with more than fifteen percent of its physical distributions of software even if more than fifteen percent of its customers were to request another browser. The online service folder agreements require that the online service provider place download links to the IE download site on its website and place limitations on a provider's ability to provide links to use and to download third party browsers. Again Microsoft's requirements make it more difficult for the end user to download a competing browser than to download IE. While the quantitative importance of this may not be large, it does require the online service provider to bias website visitors' selection of browsers.

25. Microsoft's Internet Referral Server Agreements include the ISP in a list of providers that are shown to an end user who selects his Internet access provider using a process called the Internet Connection Wizard, which is bundled with the Windows operating system. The Internet Connection Wizard can be invoked by the end user not only from the desktop but also from the Welcome to Windows screen -- that is the first screen end users see after initiating their PCs for the first time. In return for this preferential access to potential subscribers, the ISP must not express or imply to any potential subscriber (whether or not the subscriber was obtained from the Internet Connection Wizard) that an alternative browser is available unless specifically requested by the subscriber. The ISP must also accept limitations on links to its home page that allow users to download non-Microsoft browsers. The ISP must display the IE logo on its home page, along with a "hot link" to the Microsoft IE web page, and must use the IE logo in its promotional and packaging material. These requirements make it easier for an end user to download IE from an ISP's home page than to download another browser, thus requiring the ISP to bias its website visitors' browser choice. The Internet Referral Server Agreements typically also specify that the ISP must include IE as the only browser shipped seventy-five percent of the time. Thus, when more than twenty-five percent of its customers prefer another browser, an ISP is restricted from providing a third party browser to its customers even if they requested it to do so.

26. Microsoft's Internet Referral Server Agreements also provide discounts on referral fees for use of IE-specific technologies, thereby providing ISPs a financial incentive to configure their own web pages in such a way so as to reduce cross-platform threats to Microsoft's OS monopoly. For example, one of the IE-specific technologies is ActiveX controls31 My understanding is that ActiveX controls are generally operating system specific. That is, only Windows users can run an ActiveX control developed for Windows embedded in an ISP website. For a competing browser to support ActiveX controls would thus encourage the development of applications on the Internet that are Windows specific, thereby blunting one of the advantages of Internet browsers - the ability to run applications on any operating system.

27. The Internet Content Provider Agreements grant ICPs placement on the Channel Bar that appears on the Windows desktop.32 In return, the ICPs must implement certain IE-specific technologies on their websites. This requirement is similar to that imposed on ISPs and has the same anticompetitive effect of reducing the cross platform threat to Microsoft's OS, The ICP agreements also specify that the ICP must promote IE and the Active Desktop, and display the IE logo and links to IE on its home page. These requirements make it easier to download IE from an ICP's home page than it is to download another browser, thus requiring the ICP to bias its customers' browser choice. The ICPs are required to distribute IE exclusively, eliminating these ICPs as a distribution channel for a competing browser. The ICP cannot provide non-paid promotions or endorsements of non-Microsoft browsers on its Web and Content pages. Nor can the ICP pay or receive payment for any Content agreement with a non-Microsoft browser company. These requirements taken together limit the possible financial gains that an ISP and a competing browser supplier could achieve by an agreement with each other.

28. As of August 2, 1996, Microsoft had signed approximately 2,500 "IE preferred" licenses with providers of access to the Internet.33 An internal Microsoft document lists the top severity-five Internet access providers of North America by dial-up users, and the status of their Internet Explorer agreements with Microsoft.34 According to this document, Microsoft entered into agreements that require a minimum distribution of IE as a percentage of browsers distributed with fifteen of the top seventy-five providers, These fifteen providers offered access to eighty-nine percent of the dial-up users served by the top seventy-five firms.35 Of the top seventy-five providers, fifty-three had signed agreements Microsoft termed "IE preferred" in which IE is the "preferred and default browser" ISPs distribute to their customers.36 These data demonstrate that Microsoft's restrictive agreements are with those ISPs that are the first point of Internet access to the majority of PC users.

29. Table Three contains market share data for the IE and Netscape Navigator browsers for the period February 1996 through February 1998. Initial versions of Internet Explorer (versions 1.0 and 2.0) were not comparable to the Netscape browser and did not capture significant share. With the release of Internet Explorer 3.0 in May 1996, Microsoft first offered browser features and quality comparable to those of Netscape, and its market share grew rapidly during the period May 1996 through August 1996. During this period, Microsoft went from the "alpha release" to the commercial release of Internet Explorer version 3.0. It was also during this period that Microsoft began to sign the agreements with ISPs that contained the restrictions listed in Table Two. The ICP restrictions listed in Table Two were contained in agreements that became effective between June and September of 1997. With the release of Microsoft's Internet Explorer 4.0, its browser market share has continued to climb, to the point where its share and that of Netscape are roughly equal. As shown in Table Three, Microsoft's share of the browser market increased from three percent to four percent in early 1996, to twenty percent in early 1997, to more than fifty percent in early 1998.

TABLE THREE
Internet Browser Market Share
(%)

    1996 1997 1998
Source Browser/2 FEB APR MAY JUN JUL AUG OCT NOV DEC JAN FEB MAR SEP OCT NOV DEC JAN FEB
Zona Navigator 74 87       83     "«-'. ' 70     62          
Research/a Internet Explorer 3 4       8       28     36

 

       
                                       
Positive Support Navigator                         53 46 43 43 42 40
Review/b Internet Explorer                         42 48 52 53 55 58

Notes:

/1 Only months for which data are available arc listed.
/2 All release versions.

Sources:

/a Zona Research, Inc. Figures from the latest 'Browser Census.'
/b Positive Support Review, Inc, Figures from the 'Browser Market Study.'


30. Without doubt, Microsoft's improvements to its browser would have increased its market share even absent the restrictions described above (the restrictions were first imposed at the same time IE 3.0 was introduced). However, interviews and depositions of the representatives of OEMs, ISPs, and ICPs indicate that these restrictions had an important independent effect on Microsoft's browser market share.37 That this would occur was explicitly recognized by James Allchin, Senior Vice President of Microsoft, In an email to Paul Maritz, Microsoft's Group Vice President, Platforms and Applications, entitled "IE and Windows." Mr. Allchin described his primary concern as follows:

You see browser share as job 1. The real issue deals with not losing control of the APIs on the client and not losing control of the end-user experience. For Netscape this is synonymous with winning the browser battle. That is because they don't have Windows. We have an asset which has APIs and controls the end-user experience: Windows.

I do not feel we are going to win on our current path. We are not leveraging Windows from a marketing perspective and we are trying to copy Netscape and make IE into a platform. We do not use our strength -which is that we have an installed base of Windows and we have a strong OEM shipment channel for Windows. Pitting browser against browser is hard since Netscape has 80% marketshare [sic] and we have < 20 %.I am especially worried that we don't have a long term winning strategy, I fee! we are street fighting. Even if we get IE to be totally competitive with Nav/Communicator, why would [we] be chosen? They have 80% marketshare [sic]. I am convinced we have to use Windows - this is the one thing they don't have. For some reason we are in heavy copy mode against Netscape, I saw a trip report on how our booth should be changed and how we should name the components of "our client", etc. to be competitive with Netscape. This reminds me of the Novell battles. It is not a long term winning strategy. We have to be competitive with features, but we need something more - Windows integration.38

This passage unifies the exclusionary practices presented in Table Two. The bundling of the IE browser is precisely the "integration" that Mr. Allchin describes and, as he states, its purpose was for IE to win a competitive battle with Netscape that (apparently) could not be woo based on price and quality. The other restrictions perform the same role: by linking the exclusion of competing browsers to space on the desktop and in the Internet Referral Server, Microsoft's agreements with OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs perform the essential function of leveraging" Windows.

31. Microsoft would be correct in pointing out that the anticompetitive practices in question do not remove completely the ability of final consumers to obtain rival browsers. For example, notwithstanding Microsoft's practices, it remains theoretically possible for Netscape to continue distributing its browser via download from its website. A number of consumers do obtain it in this way, though for many the greater time and expense of downloading (not to mention the nervousness of less computer-literate users who may be wary of trying to obtain their browser in this way), make obtaining the browser directly from an IAP or an OEM the preferred choice. Moreover, in those cases where an OEM has been willing to bear the added customer confusion and support costs, competing browsers can be obtained preinstalled on a PC as well. And, of course, Microsoft would be correct in pointing out that there are at least some iAPs and ICPs with which it does not have exclusionary licenses. Finally, the screen and boot-up restrictions do not present an impenetrable barrier to a consumer's ability to access competing browser technologies. Nevertheless, Microsoft's practices, although they undeniably stop short of choking off all possible means by which competing browsers can be obtained, collectively amount to a strong "thumb on the scale" that significantly advantages Microsoft, disadvantages competitors, and restrains effective competition. Furthermore, in markets subject to network effects, such as those at issue here, even modest artificial advantages are capable of skewing the browser market Microsoft's way and making it significantly less likely that a competing browser will be able to weaken Microsoft's current dominant position in the OS market.

 

  1. Are Microsoft's Restrictions on the Use of Competing Browsers Justified by Economic Efficiency Considerations?

 

32. At this point, I will consider possible efficiency justifications for Microsoft's browser restrictions. I will analyze these restrictions by asking two questions. First, are there any efficiency justifications that apply in this case? Second, if one does apply, could the legitimate business purpose of that restriction be served without restricting other parties' distribution and promotion of a competing browser?

 

    1. OEM Restrictions

 

33. The most important OEM restriction is that the OEM not modify the operating system software as provided by Microsoft, This restriction appears justifiable to the extent that it performs a quality assurance function by prohibiting OEMs from modifying the OS in ways that undermine Microsoft's ability to provide ISVs with a consistent platform to which they can write applications. If each OEM were to modify the OS software it receives from Microsoft in different ways so as to create different versions of Windows, ISVs might have to rewrite their applications for each version. Microsoft refers to this scenario as "balkanization" of its operating system.39

34. However, the desire of Microsoft to provide ISVs with a consistent applications development platform does not provide economic justification for biasing the OEMs' choice of which browser to feature. In the case of Windows 95, Microsoft itself provided the ability to remove Internet Explorer 3,0 and Internet Explorer 4.0 using an uninstall utility called "Add/Remove" supplied in Windows, presumably with the intent that such a removal feature would be used.40 If removal would have undermined the consistency of the platform for ISVs in any meaningful way, it seems doubtful that Microsoft would have provided such a removal ability. In the case of Windows 98, it is my understanding that the ability to browse the web using IE can be removed and replaced with a competing browser in such a way that the consistency of the Windows platform for ISVs would not be frustrated in any appreciable manner.

35. Nor can the restriction be justified in the case of Windows 98 by Microsoft's claim that IE and Windows 98 are integrated in a manner designed to give users a superior integrated browsing experience from the Windows desktop to the Web. It is my understanding that a comparable browsing experience can be achieved by the combination of Windows 98 and a competing browser. Furthermore, even if this were not true, restrictions on the use of competing browsers would be unnecessary because end users would select the integrated Microsoft product of their own volition, if it were superior.

36. The anticompetitive effects of the screen restrictions were discussed above in paragraphs 22 and 23. One possible reason for these restrictions is that they prevent OEMs from obtaining referral fees from IAPs through an OEM-sponsored ISP referral server (similar to Microsoft's ISP referral server) presented to the end user during the initial boot. My impression, based on Microsoft documents, is that this motive is a minor one.41 In any case, given its OS monopoly, Microsoft could probably recapture such referral fees by charging an OEM for the right to insert its own screens or alter those provided by Microsoft during startup. Restrictions that tilt the scales against competing browsers are not essential to Microsoft's retention of TAP referral fees that might otherwise go to OEMs.

37. A second possible justification for the screen restrictions is that there may be marketing or quality benefits to be obtained from keeping the Window's startup sequence and desktop uniform across all users, regardless of whose PC the end user is buying. For example, Microsoft devotes resources to ensuring that there are no failures during the initial boot. If OEMs were allowed to put in their own screens and change the icons on the desktop, it is conceivable that this could, for example, result in a longer initial boot-up process or increased confusion lo consumers which could reflect poorly on Microsoft. This is a variation on the ISP balkanization argument discussed above but applied to end users.

38. As an initial matter, replacement of the IE icon with the icon of a competing browser would not appear to interfere with any marketing or quality benefits associated with uniformity of the startup sequence and the desktop screen. In fact, the screen restrictions as applied to Windows 98 support this view since Microsoft does permit the OEM to add items of any shape and size to the desktop screen if the OEM turns on the Active Desktop as the default configuration on its PCs. I therefore see no legitimate business interest in Microsoft requiring OEMs to limit the size and shape of additional folders and icons on the desktop.

39. Potentially, the balkanization argument is more significant in the case of OEMs inserting their own screens highlighting a competing browser or an ISP service that promotes a competing browser prior to the desktop screen because more significant changes in the appearance and startup sequence of Windows could result. Therefore, although these startup sequence restrictions probably have some anticompetitive effects, legitimate business justifications may be important. On balance, I consider the anticompetitive effects of these restrictions to outweigh concerns about balkanization of the startup sequence. I base this judgment on the fact that Microsoft has negotiated exceptions to these startup sequence restrictions with OEMs. 42

 

    1. Browser Restrictions for ISPs, ICPs and Online Services

 

40. Collectively, these browser restrictions are remarkably uniform in their focus on promoting IE and discouraging the use of competing browsers. One possible justification for these restrictions could be that Microsoft and its Internet partners are engaged in joint marketing of their respective products. Microsoft offers promotional facilities on the desktop, and the IAPs and ICPs promote Microsoft on their web pages and Microsoft technologies with their services. The anticompetitive browser restrictions, it might be argued, perform the necessary function of limiting ex-post opportunism43 without which the joint marketing might not take place. For example, an Internet partner, such as an ICP, could get top billing on the Microsoft desktop but would then look for a similar deal on the channel bar of a competing browser in return for allowing that competitor to advertise on the ICP's web pages, too. From the standpoint of economic efficiency, though, anticompetitive restrictions such as these are justifiable only if there is no obvious alternative that is less anticompetitive. In this case, the restrictions are not reasonably necessary for the joint marketing to occur. The reason is that it is in Microsoft's interest to continue this joint marketing whether or not the Internet partner also deals with a competing browser vendor in the same way.

41. To see this, suppose that the Internet partner does joint marketing with a competitor in the browser market. What is Microsoft's best response? If it does not allow the Internet partner access to the Windows desktop, Microsoft leaves the competing browser as the only means by which an end user can be a customer of that IAP or ICP, If the IAP or ICP is of any importance, Microsoft would still want it on the Windows desktop in order to boost the use of IE. Similarly, because Microsoft has an OS monopoly, it is to the advantage of the IAP or ICP to allow Microsoft to advertise on its Web pages and install links to Microsoft's own Web pages, etc. Thus, I would expect that the joint marketing activities between Microsoft and its Internet partners would continue in the absence of the browser restrictions. Indeed, Microsoft has voluntarily dropped some of these restrictions, which appears inconsistent with a claim that they are necessary for joint marketing. This being so, the restrictions cannot be justified as a means of deterring ex-post opportunism by Microsoft's Internet partners.

42. A second justification sometimes given in the economics literature for certain types of exclusionary restrictions is that they can facilitate usage metering and thereby make possible efficient price discrimination. In this case, there seems to be no such metering function that is related to pricing and is facilitated by excluding competing browsers. A third type of justification in the literature is that exclusionary restrictions may be needed to maintain quality control. For this justification to apply, the use of a rival browser with Windows would somehow degrade the operation of Windows. To my knowledge, Microsoft often points out how well rival browsers such as Netscape Navigator works with Windows 95.44 (As pointed out above, if the technical integration of the browser with the OS in Windows 98 is required in order to provide seamless and efficient operation, then exclusionary restrictions would be unnecessary.)

43. The discussion in this section and in the preceding section demonstrates three main points. First, the exclusionary restrictions heavily bias end users' choices towards IE and away from competing browsers. Second, absent these restrictions, many end users would have been offered a competing browser by their OEM, TAP, or ICP. Third, these restrictions have little apparent business purpose besides being anticompetitive regarding a competing browser's cross platform role. These points by themselves would lead me to conclude that Microsoft's browser restrictions are intended to reduce competition to its OS monopoly. There is, however, an additional line of reasoning which leads to the same conclusion. This is the subject of the next section.

 

  1. Would Microsoft's Contractual Restrictions be Profitable but for Their Effects in Impeding Competition in the OS Market?

 

44. At this point, I turn to the question of whether the restrictions just described are aimed solely at expanding Microsoft's profit in Internet-related markets by increasing IE browser usage, or whether they are undertaken to impede competition in the OS market. To analyze the foil economic effects of these restrictions, I rely on the main finding of Section IT, that Microsoft has monopoly power over a bottleneck input in computing - the operating system. In this setting, browsers are complementary to the bottleneck input, and the restrictions described above tend to exclude competing browsers from being used with Microsoft's dominant OS. This paradigm, a monopoly with alleged exclusionary practices in a complementary market that it also services, has been analyzed by a number of economists and antitrust scholars.45 The general conclusion from this body of work is that if the price level in the complement's market is limited by competitive forces, then in the absence of efficiency justifications such as those discussed above, the monopolist's control over the bottleneck input does not give it any profit incentive to restrict or exclude a competitor's product in the complements market. The reason is that control over the bottleneck input allows the monopolist to extract value from consumers no matter whose version of the complementary good the consumer buys.

45. Applied to the case at hand, the bottleneck input is Microsoft's OS and the complementary product is the browser. Profits earned from browsers come not from the browser software itself, which is generally offered free to end users at the current time, but from Internet-related businesses engaged in by Microsoft, such as referral fees from IAPs and advertising revenue from the Microsoft website. Potentially, revenue could also come from the sale of desktop space to IAPs.

46. The analysis of Microsoft's restrictions involves several steps. Assume, for the sake of argument, that Microsoft markets a "better" browser than any of its rivals. For example, suppose hypothetically (and contrary to my previous analysis) that the integration of IE with the OS could provide a more "seamless" experience than would the use of another browser In that case, the bundle of Windows and Internet Explorer would create more value for the end user than would Windows with a competing browser. Given its dominant position in the OS market, Microsoft could extract higher value in the form of profits, whether through a higher royalty for the OS software, through raising customer referral fees paid by ISPs to Microsoft, or by charging IAPs and ICPs for space on the Windows desktop (other methods are doubtless possible, as well). Under these assumptions, absent anticompetitive motives, if IE is superior to competing browsers, Microsoft would have no need to impose contractual restrictions to encourage the use of IE.

47. Now suppose that a competing browser is superior to IE, In this case, it might well seem that Microsoft would gain by imposing exclusionary restrictions against the users of competing browsers. However, the economic logic described above applies in this case, as well. If the combination of Windows with a competing browser did provide more value to the user than bundling Windows with IE, Microsoft's bottleneck OS monopoly would allow it again to extract this value through a higher OS royalty (or by one of the other means described above), even though the increase in consumer value came from another company's browser and not its own.

48. The evidence establishes, however, that Microsoft has put in place contracting restrictions that indeed had force and constrained licensees of various versions of Windows from offering Netscape Navigator in circumstances where they wished to do so.46 Making the reasonable assumption that OEMs, IAPs and ICPs who wanted to offer Navigator wanted to do so because it would provide value to their customers, Microsoft's restrictions prevented end users from obtaining this additional value. Microsoft could have extracted this additional value from consumers {or OEMs, IAPs and ICPs), but chose not to in order to obtain the restrictions, In economic terms, Microsoft has incurred an opportunity cost by foregoing the additional value it could have extracted from consumers (or OEMs, IAPs, and ICPs). An example of the foregone value it could have obtained is the provision of tree space on its Channel Bar to ICPs who were willing to pay a positive price for placement on the Channel Bar as evidenced by deals Netscape struck with a number of ICPs for placement on the Netcaster Channel Bar.47

49. Why would Microsoft incur the opportunity cost of these restrictions? In my view the economic rationale is that it is attempting to preserve its OS monopoly. This behavior is easy to understand once we take account of the competitive threat to Microsoft's operating system monopoly by the competitive browser platform. The threat of Netscape's browser to Microsoft's OS dominance has been known for some time and has been described by Microsoft's Steve Ballmer:

If I wanted to compete with Microsoft, I wouldn't say 'Oh yeah, let's try to write a better memory manager, and we'll have lighter-weight threads than they do.' In this day and age it's not sexy enough, and there's no user interface. The OS/2 experience proves full well the value of that. I would do what Netscape is doing. I'd say I'll build on top of [Windows] and I'll take their future away from them.48

More recently, Microsoft's James Allchin stated: "The goal, the stated goal of Netscape was to replace the user interface of Windows where you couldn't see it and to create a new set of APIs that developers would write to."49 When asked how Netscape could threaten Windows and the sales of Windows, Mr. Allchin stated: "You get developers to write the APIs, you cover op Windows, you've just got this layer running on top, and if the size, performance was acceptable, it becomes irrelevant, Windows becomes irrelevant. 50

50. Because the browser can serve as a software applications platform independent of the underlying OS, a new entrant in the OS market would not have to create an installed base of software applications complementary to its OS and comparable to Microsoft's in its size and use in order to succeed. Developers would no longer have to incur the extra cost of rewriting software to be "ported" to the new OS. Instead, these applications written to the browser platform (perhaps using Sun Microsystems' Java programming technology51) would be accessible to a user using any OS that supported that browser. This would reduce both the installed base entry barrier and the switching costs entry barrier in the OS market. Therefore, I conclude that Microsoft's browser restrictions are likely to have the effect of weakening a potential competitive threat to its dominant position in the OS market

51. Moreover, Microsoft could obtain an additional benefit if these restrictions force major browser vendors to leave the market. The browser market could tip to monopoly, and entry barriers are likely to arise naturally, much as they do in the OS market. Thus, the browser market and associated Internet markets will become Jess competitive. With IE dominating the browser market, websites will tend to be written to the IE technology. This will induce more end users to switch to IE, increasing software developers' incentives to build websites around IE. As this occurs and as end users incur the sunken adjustment costs to IE, the natural entry barrier of installed base (of websites and other technology) and switching costs will act to give Microsoft market power for Internet services. Thus, in the long term, Microsoft will have the opportunity to benefit from a less competitive market structure in the Internet just as it has in the OS market.

52. An important part of the exposition in this section is the conclusion reached in paragraphs 45 through 47, that if these restrictions were aimed solely at expanding Microsoft's profits in Internet-related markets by increasing IE browser usage, it could do better by capturing such profits through the price of its OS, or through selling Internet products tied to the OS (such as desktop space and ISP referral fees). The implication is that these restrictions serve an anticompetitive purpose. However, as stated in paragraph 42, my conclusion that these restrictions are anticompetitive does not depend solely on the framework presented in those paragraphs. There are three additional reasons why I regard Microsoft's browser restrictions to be anticompetitive. First, by restricting the use of competing browsers, Microsoft automatically blunts the threat to its OS monopoly that is posed by the browser's potential as an alternative platform for software applications. Second, the internal Microsoft sources cited above make it clear that OEM, IAP, and ISP restrictions described earlier were imposed with this threat very much in mind. Third, the discussion in Section B above demonstrates that the restrictions listed in Table Two have little apparent purpose aside from their anticompetitive effects,

 

  1. What are the Effects of Microsoft's Giving Away Its Browser?

 

53. The discussion above demonstrates that the intent and effect of the contractual restriction is predominately anticompetitive. An additional Microsoft practice of considerable importance in light of these anticompetitive effects is that of distributing its browser without charge. This practice has forced Netscape to reduce its browser price to zero and has apparently cut into Netscape's revenue stream considerably. I will now analyze the effects of Microsoft's distributing its browser without charge, taken in the context of the anticompetitive non-price restrictions described above.

54. The starting point for discussing pricing is cost. For a software product like a browser, the vast majority of costs are first-copy costs, i.e., the cost of developing the product. Given that the product has been developed, additional costs related to volume of output are low, consisting mainly of packaging, marketing, and distribution costs. Therefore, a zero browser price certainly does not recover any of the first-copy costs, although the extra, or "marginal," cost of an additional browser may well be close to zero. Hence, Microsoft has priced the browser in such a way that it cannot recover the cost of the browser from the browser market itself

55. Furthermore, there are significant interactions between zero pricing of the browser and the non-price restrictions analyzed above. For example, by bundling IE with Windows 98, Microsoft ensures that many end users will decide just to go with IE due to convenience, since there is a nontrivial amount of effort involved to download and install another browser after the end user's initial boot of the PC, Because Microsoft does not offer a cheaper version of the OS without IE installed, the zero price of IE simply reinforces the convenience of buying a PC with IE preinstalled. Therefore, zero pricing reinforces the anticompetitive effects of the OEM license requirement that IE cannot be uninstalled. The agreements with certain on-line service providers, ISPs, and ICPs all have elements which make it onerous to use a non-Microsoft browser when attempting to access websites based on IE technology or which do not support non-Microsoft browsers. Zero pricing adds a strong additional inducement for such distributors to go with IE.

56. Microsoft's decision to integrate the IE browser with the Windows 98 operating system suggests the browser is not just free now, but "forever" free, as long as Windows 98 is used. In effect, Microsoft has made a binding, credible commitment to a free browser. That being true, for a rival to enter or remain in the browser market, that rival must be able to support a free browser with revenue from other sources, Even if Microsoft chooses not to maintain a forever free policy by bundling IE and Windows 98, consumers may form the expectation that such a policy will continue, causing the market to "tip" in its favor more rapidly.

57. It is possible as a matter of theory that (possibly temporarily) free distribution of browsers could be justified without anticompetitive concern, as a penetration policy designed to expand Internet markets. However, given the forever free commitment on the browser price, if the browser market "tips" easily, then if Microsoft drives rivals from the browser market, entry barriers will arise, some as a result of network effects, and some due to Microsoft's contractual restrictions concerning the use of non-Microsoft browsers. At that point, Microsoft can raise the price of its OS, the bottleneck input, so as to exploit this extension of its monopoly power.52 Alternatively, it could increase referral fees from IAPs, or begin to charge for space on the desktop. In the end, as others have observed, "there is no free browser,"53

IV. Microsoft Will Recoup the Opportunity Costs of its
Contractual Restrictions by Maintaining
its Operating System Monopoly

58. In the preceding discussion, I have established two points. First, Microsoft has monopoly power in the market for OS that is protected to a considerable degree by natural entry barriers (such as switching costs and increasing returns to scale in consumption) and by the artificial entry barriers created through its contractual policies regarding competing browsers. Second, Microsoft has adopted contractual restrictions with OEMs, ISPs, and ICPs which have a positive opportunity cost, but seem likely to remove competing web browsers from their potential role as a platform for software applications which would run on computers independently of the underlying operating system. Such a platform would "commoditize" Microsoft's Windows operating system, as applications no longer would be specific to a given OS.

59. Because the likely effect of Microsoft's contractual restrictions will be to remove the competitive threat to its operating system, Microsoft will likely recoup whatever profits it has foregone from ICPs and IAPs due to its browser restrictions. These restrictions are profitable overall because they will help to ensure Microsoft's immensely profitable OS business is without any serious competition for some time to come. Therefore, I find it likely that Microsoft would recoup the lost profits associated with its restriction through higher profits earned on its OS than if those restrictions were not imposed.

60. In reaching this conclusion, I do not need to rely solely on my own analysis. Microsoft's senior executives have made It clear in documents cited above that they consider the browser platform threat to be serious and that their contractual restrictions regarding competing browsers are intended to tie any user benefits from these technologies back to the use of Windows. The company's actions have been entirely consistent with this concern. Clearly, in Microsoft's own calculations, the benefits from protecting its OS monopoly outweigh the opportunity costs of the restrictions that I have analyzed.

V. Conclusions

61. I have concluded that the Microsoft contractual restrictions that I have analyzed are anticompetitive for four main reasons:

62. What would be the consequence to consumers if Microsoft's bundling and restrictive practices enabled it to maintain its OS monopoly and create a monopoly in the market for browsers? Consumers would be harmed in two significant ways. First, virtually all consumer and business users would pay prices for personal computers higher than those that would exist in a competitive market. Given the increased reliance on personal computers both at home and in the work place, even a small increase in price would create substantial economic welfare losses. Second, and perhaps more importantly, innovation in areas that threaten Microsoft would be inhibited. This could potentially have significant adverse consequences for the pace and direction of innovative activity in the software industry.

63. How is it that Microsoft's anticompetitive behavior, aimed at maintaining its dominance, could adversely affect the type and extent of innovation in the computer software industry? As a general proposition, firms invest in research and development only if they expect to earn, at a minimum, a competitive rate of return, that is, a return equal! to that obtained on an investment of comparable risk. To the extent that Microsoft's anticompetitive practices make it that much more difficult for an innovator to prove successful in markets where Microsoft currently dominates, independent innovative activity that might otherwise have been profitable may not be. At the extreme, if Microsoft's practices were to erect an insurmountable barrier to successful entry in its core monopoly markets, independent third party innovation in these markets would be less likely, and the prospects for technical advance in these markets would rely solely on the efforts of Microsoft itself. While it does not seem likely that Microsoft's practices will have quite so extreme an effect, it remains the case that innovative activity is likely to be skewed inefficiently, as firms seek to "invent around'' the Microsoft bottleneck, rather than compete directly against it.

64. Beyond any adverse effect on innovative effort in the PC operating system market itself, Microsoft's practices threaten also to deter efficient innovative activity aimed at developing technologies complementary to its operating system (such as Internet browsers). As discussed earlier in this declaration, and as recognized in much of the economics literature, even firms with monopoly power generally have an incentive to encourage the development and success of products complementary to their own. All else equal, this tends to enhance the value of the dominant firm's product. However, where the development of such products and technologies has the potential eventually to threaten the dominant firm's market power, for example, by creating a computing environment in which application software would work regardless of which operating system was installed on the user's computer, the deterring of efficient innovation in this area could be in the self-interest of Microsoft.

65. In sum, Microsoft's actions are likely not only to affect the prices consumers pay for products over which Microsoft has monopoly power, but also to affect adversely the path of innovation in the computer software industry. The artificial entry barriers erected by Microsoft (through bundling and its other restrictive practices) will have the effect of impeding the natural tendency of the marketplace to provide improved and alternative technologies that compete with Microsoft's OS monopoly, reducing the welfare of society as a whole.

I declare under penalty of perjury that the foregoing is true and accurate. Executed on May 15 , 1998 in Austin, Texas.

  _______________/s/________________
David S. Sibley

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA



UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,    

                  Plaintiff,

                  v.

MICROSOFT CORPORATION,

                  Defendant.
 


|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|         
Civil Action No:

APPENDIX TO DECLARATION OF
DAVID
S, SIBLEY

David S. Sibley

Professor, Department of Economics
University of Texas at Austin
Austin, TX 78712
Phone:(512)475-8545
Fax:(512)471-8899

Education:

Teaching Fields:

Research Fields:

Professional Experience:

Teaching:

Publications:

A. Journal Articles:

"A Note on the Concavity of the Mean-Variance Problem," Review of Economic Studies, July 1975,

"Permanent and Transitory Income Effects in a Model of Optimal Consumption with Wage Income Uncertainty," Journal of Economic Theory, August 1975.

"Optimal Foreign Borrowing with Export Revenue Uncertainty," (with J- L. McCabe), International Economic Review, October 1976.

"Regulatory Commission Behavior: Myopic vs. Forward-Looking," (with E. E. Bailey), Economic Inquiry, June 1978.

"Optimal Decisions with Estimation Risk," (with L. C. Rafsky, R, W. Klein and R. D. Willig), Econometrica, November 1977.

"The Demand for Labor in a Dynamic Model of the Firm," Journal of Economic Theory, October 1977.

"Public Utility Pricing Under Risk: The Case of Self-Rationing," (with J. C. Panzar), American Economic Review, December 1978.

"A Dynamic Model of the Firm with Stochastic Regulatory Review," (with V. S. Bawa), International Economic Review, October 1980.

"Optimal Nonlinear Pricing for Multiproduct Monopolies," (with L. J, Mirman), Belt Journal of Economics, Autumn 1980.

"Efficiency and Competition in the Airline Industry," (with D. R- Graham and D- P. Kaplan), Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1983.

"Optimal Non-Uniform Pricing," (with M. B. Goldman and H. E. Leland), Review of Economic Studies, April 1984.

"Reply to Lipman and Further Results," International Economic Review, June 1985.

"Public Utility Pricing Under Risk: A Generalization," Economics Letters, June 1985.

"Optimal Consumption, the Interest Rate and Wage Uncertainty," (with D. Levhari), Economics Letters, 1986.

"Regulating Without Cost Information: The Incremental Surplus Subsidy Scheme," (with D. M. Sappington), International Economic Review, May 1989.

"Optimal Two Part Tariffs for Inputs," (with J. C. Panzar), Journal of Public Economics, November 1989.

"Asymmetric Information, Incentives and Price Cap Regulation," Rand Journal of Economics, Fall 1989.

"Regulating Without Cost Information: Some Further Thoughts," (with D. ML Sappington), International Economic Review, November 1990,

''Compensation and Transfer Pricing m a Principal-Agent Model," (with D. E. Besanko), International Economic Review, February 1991,

"Thoughts on Nonlinear Pricing Under Price Cap Regulation," (with D. M. Sappington), Rand Journal of Economics, Spring 1992.

"Ex Ante vs. Post Pricing: Optional Calling Plans vs. Tapered Tariffs," (with K. Clay and P. Srinagesh), Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1992.

"Optimal Non-linear Pricing With Regulatory Preference over Customer Types," (with W, W. Sharkery), Journal of Public Economics,February 1993.

"A Bertrand Model of Pricing and Entry," (with W. W. Sharkey), Economics Letters, 1993.

"Regulatory Incentive Policies and Abuse," (with D. M. Sappington), Journal of Regulatory Economics, June 1993.

"Multiproduct Nonlinear Prices with Multiple Taste Characteristics," (with P. Srinagesh), Rand Journal of Economics, Winter 1997.

"The Competitive Incentives of Vertically-Integrated Local Exchange Carriers: An Economic and Policy Analysis," (with D. L. Weisman), Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Winter 1998.

"Raising Rivals' Costs: The Entry of a Upstream Monopolist into Downstream Markets," (with D. L. Weisman), Information. Economics and Policy (forthcoming).

B. Reports and Articles In Conference Volumes, and Other Publications

"The Dynamics of Price Adjustment in Regulated Industries," (with E. E. Bailey), in Proceedings of IEEE Conference on Systems Control, 1974,

"Optimal Non-Uniform Pricing for Electricity: Some Illustrative Examples," (with R, W. Koenker), in Sichel (ed.) Public Utility Ratemaking in an Energy-Conscious Environment, Praeger, 1979,

"Antitrust Policy in the Airline Industry," (with S, B. Jollie), Civil Aeronautics Beard, October 19S2. Transmitted by the CAB to Congress as part of proposed sunset legislation,

"Deregulation and the Economic Theory of Regulation," (with W. W. Sharkey), in Proceedings of the Eleventh Annual Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, 1983.

"An Analysis of Tapered Access Charges for End Users," (with W. E. Taylor, D. P, Heyman and J. M. Lazorchak), published in the Proceedings of the Eighteenth Annual Williamsburg Conference on Regulation, H. Treeing (ed.), Michigan State, 1987.

Report to the Governor, The Task Force on Market-Based Pricing of Electricity, Co-authored with D. M. Sappington, Appendix III

"Optional Tariffs for Access in the FCC's Price Cap Proposal," (with D, P. Heyman and W. E. Taylor), in M, Einhorn (ed,), Price Caps and Incentive Regulation in the Telecommunications Industry, Kluwer, 1990.

"Optional Two-Part Tariffs: Toward More Effective Price Discounting," (with R, Rudkin) in Public Utilities Fortnightly, July It 1997.

C. Books:

The Theory of Public Utility Pricing, (with S. J, Brown), Cambridge University Press, 1986. Second printing 1986. Third printing 19&9. Revised, edition planned.

Co-editor of Telecommunications Demand Analysis: An Integrated View, North-Holland, 1989,

Completed Papers:

Current Research Areas:

Editorial Duties:

Other Professional Activities:

References:

May 1998


UNITED STATES CISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA



UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,    

                  PLAINTIFF,

                  v.

MICROSOFT CORPORATION,
ET AL.,

                  DEFENDANTS.
 


|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|         
C.A. NO. 94-1564
  WASHINGTON, D.C.
JANUARY 13, 1998
(P.M. SESSION)

TRANSCRIPT OF PROCEEDINGS
BEFORE THE HONORABLE THOMAS P. JACKSON

FOR THE PLAINTIFF:

PHILLIP MALONE, ESQ.    
PAULINE T. WAN, ESQ.    
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
ANTITRUST DIVISION
450 GOLDEN GATE AVENUE
P.O. BOX 36046
SAN FRANCISCO, CA 94102

MARK S. POPOFSKY, ESQ.    
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
ANTITRUST DIVISION
10TH & PENN. AVE., N.W.
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20530

FOR THE DEFENDANTS:

RICHARD J. UROWSKY, ESQ.    
STEVEN L. HOLLEY, ESQ.    
JOHN L. WARDEN, ESQ.    
SULLIVAN & CROMWELL
125 BROAD STREET
NEW YORK, NY 10004

COURT REPORTER:

DAVID A. KASDAN, RPR
MILLER REPORTING CO., INC.
507 C STREET, N.E,
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20003

1 Q.     NOW, WHAT HAPPENS TO THIS OSR 2 VERSION OF WINDOWS 95
2 IF THE USER DELETES ALL THE FILES THAT MAKE UP IE 3.0 AND
3 THE RETAIL CHANNEL?
4 A.     WHEN WINDOWS 95 BREAKS, IT WON'T WORK ANYMORE.
5 Q.     AND WHY DOES THIS HAPPEN?
6 A.     WELL, BECAUSE IF YOU WERE TO FOLLOW THAT PROCEDURE,
7 YOU WOULD HAVE TO DELETE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES; THAT
8 IS, FILES THAT ARE RELIED UPON BY WINDOWS 95 FOR ITS VERY
9 OPERATION.
10 Q.     COULD YOU TELL US MORE GENERALLY WHAT IS A
11 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY.
12 A.     YES. A SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY IS A COLLECTION OF
13 SOFTWARE CODE THAT IS RELIED UPON AND USED BY MULTIPLE
14 OTHER APPLICATIONS AND, IN SOME CASES, BY THE OPERATING
15 SYSTEM AS WELL,
16 Q.     AND DOES WINDOWS 95, THEN, RELY ON SHARED-PROGRAM
17 LIBRARIES?
18 A.     YES, IT DOES.
19 Q.     CAN YOU GIVE ME AN EXAMPLE OF A PARTICULAR
20 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY.
21 A.     YES, I CAN. COMCONTROL 32.DLL IS SUCH A
22 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY.
23 Q.     AND TELL US VERY GENERALLY WHAT DOES COMCONTROL
24 32.DLL DO?
25 A.     WELL, THE NAME IS SHORTHAND FOR COMMON CONTROLS. IT
 
1 CONTAINS SOFTWARE HAVING TO DO WITH THE DISPLAY OF MENUS
2 AND TOOLBARS, FOR EXAMPLE.
3 Q.     AND HOW WOULD AN APPLICATION, FOR EXAMPLE, USE
4 COMCOMTROL 32?
5 A.     WELL, AN APPLICATION MIGHT CALL UPON THE SOFTWARE
6 CODE CONTAINED IN THAT FILE IN ORDER TO DISPLAY
7 INFORMATION ON THE SCREEN.
8 Q.     AND HOW MIGHT WINDOWS USE COMCONTROL 32?
9 A.     FOR ESSENTIALLY THE SAME PURPOSE, FOR THE DISPLAY OF,
10 AGAIN, MENUS, TOOLBARS, OTHER ASPECTS OF THE GRAPHICAL
11 USER INTERFACE.
12 Q.     NOW, MORE GENERALLY, HOW ARE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES
13 DISTRIBUTED?
14 A.     WELL, SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES ARE DISTRIBUTED IN A
15 VARIETY OF WAYS. FOR EXAMPLE, WHEN AN OEM PRE-INSTALLS
16 WINDOWS 95 ON A PC, THE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES THAT
17 MICROSOFT SHIPS WITH WINDOWS 95 GET INSTALLED ON THAT
18 DISK. THAT'S AT THE VERY BEGINNING. THAT'S ASSUMING, FOR
19 EXAMPLE, A VERSION OF WINDOWS 95 THAT DOES NOT INCLUDE
20 INTERNET EXPLORER WOULD THAT SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES.
21 OTHER METHODS OF DISTRIBUTION INCLUDE, FOR
22 EXAMPLE, APPLICATION SOFTWARE VENDORS THAT PRODUCE
23 APPLICATIONS LIKE INTERNET EXPLORER OR OTHER PROGRAMS,
24 OFTEN INCLUDES CERTAIN SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES AND
25 REDISTRIBUTE THEM ON THE SAME MEDIA ON WHICH THEY
1 DISTRIBUTE THEIR PARTICULAR APPLICATION SOFTWARE,
2 Q.     ARE THERE ANY OTHER COMMON DISTRIBUTION METHODS FOR
3 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES?
4 A.     YES, THERE ARE. UPDATES TO THESE FILES APPEAR ON
5 MICROSOFT'S WORLDWIDE WEB SITE, FOR EXAMPLE, AND ON SOME
6 OF THE CD-ROM SUBSCRIPTION PRODUCTS THAT WE ALLUDED TO
7 BEFORE THE LUNCH BREAK, TECH-NET, THE DEVELOPER NETWORK
8 AND SO FORTH.
9 Q.     LET'S FOCUS AGAIN ON COMCONTROL 32. NOW, DOES THAT
10 SHIP WITH WINDOWS 95?
11 A.     YES, IT DOES.
12 Q.     AND IT'S PRESUMABLY WRITTEN BY MICROSOFT?
13 A.     I BELIEVE THAT TO BE THE CASE.
14 Q.     OKAY. NOW, DID IT SHIP IN THE FIRST COMMERCIAL
15 RELEASE OF WINDOWS 95 BACK IN AUGUST OF 1995?
16 A.     YES.
17 Q.     NOW, YOU MENTIONED THAT APPLICATIONS WILL
18 REDISTRIBUTE, ON OCCASIONS, SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES. WHY
19 WOULD THEY DO THIS?
20 A.     THEY DO THIS TO MAKE THEIR APPLICATIONS MORE
21 RELIABLE, IF AN APPLICATION RELIES UPON SOMETHING IN A
22 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY THAT MAY NEED TO BE UPDATED, THAT
23 PERHAPS THE USER HAS AN OLDER VERSION OF ON THE PC'S HARD
24 DISK, REDISTRIBUTING THE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES AWAY
25 FROM THE SOFTWARE APPLICATION VENDOR TO INSURE THAT IF THE
 
1 USER DOES, IN FACT, HAVE AN OLDER VERSION OF THAT FILE,
2 THE NEWER VERSION NECESSARY TO SUPPORT THE APPLICATION
3 WILL BE COPIED OVER ONTO THE USER'S PC. IT'S A WAY OF
4 GUARANTEEING A MINIMUM LEVEL OF SHARED PROGRAM CODE
5 REQUIRED FOR THE APPLICATION.
6 Q.     AND WOULD THIS INCLUDE APPLICATIONS THAT ARE WRITTEN
7 BOTH BY MICROSOFT AND BY VENDORS OTHER THAN MICROSOFT?
8 A.     YES.
9 Q.     DO YOU KNOW OF ANY APPLICATIONS SPECIFICALLY THAT DO
10 DISTRIBUTE SUCH SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES?
11 A.     YES.
12 Q.     BESIDES IE, CAN YOU GIVE ME AN EXAMPLE OF SUCH AN
13 APPLICATION.
14 A.     YES. MICROSOFT'S WORD 97 IS AN EXAMPLE.
15 Q.     AND DO YOU HAVE ANY OTHER EXAMPLES THAT ARE BY A
16 VENDOR OTHER THAN MICROSOFT?
17 A.     YES. WE HAVE CHATTED ABOUT SYMANTEC'S NORTON
18 UTILITIES. THAT'S ANOTHER EXAMPLE OF SOFTWARE SHIPPED BY,
19 IN THIS CASE, A THIRD-PARTY VENDOR THAT CONTAINS
20 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES.
21 Q.     NOW, IN THE CASE OF THE NORTON UTILITIES PRODUCT,
22 WERE YOU ABLE TO IDENTIFY ANY PARTICULAR SHARED-PROGRAM
23 LIBRARIES THAT CAME WITH THE NORTON UTILITIES PRODUCT?
24 A.     YES. FOR EXAMPLE, THE COMCONTROL 32.DLL FILE THAT WE
25 MENTIONED EARLIER IS INCLUDED WITH THE NORTON UTILITIES
 
1 3.0 CD.
2 Q.     SO, WHEN YOU INSTALLED NORTON UTILITIES ONTO THAT PC,
3 LET'S FOCUS ON WHAT HAPPENED TO THAT COMCONTROL 32.DLL
4 FILE.
5 A.     CERTAINLY. NORTON UTILITIES COPIES ITS VERSION OF
6 THAT FILE ONTO THE USER'S COMPUTER OR HARD DRIVE.
7 Q.     WHAT HAPPENS TO THE VERSION THAT WAS THERE ON THE PC
8 ALREADY?
9 A.     NORTON UTILITIES ACTUALLY RENAMES THAT PARTICULAR
10 FILE WITH A DIFFERENT SUFFIX .NU3 FOR NORTON UTILITIES 3.
11 WINDOWS 95 WOULD NOT RECOGNIZE THAT FILE WITH THAT NAME,
12 BUT THIS IS SIMPLY TO PROVIDE A WAY FOR THE USER OR FOR A
13 TECHNICIAN TO GO BACK TO THAT EARLIER VERSION, IF IT
14 BECAME NECESSARY FOR SOME REASON.
15 Q.     BUT IT'S NOT USEFUL TO THE OPERATION?
16 A.     NO, WINDOWS 95 WOULD NOT SEE IT.
17 Q.     NOW, IN THE CASE OF WORD 97, THERE ARE SHARED-PROGRAM
18 LIBRARIES INCLUDED WITH THAT PRODUCT AS WELL?
19 A.     YES, THERE ARE.
20 Q.     AND WHAT HAPPENS, THEN, WHEN YOU INSTALL WORD 97 TO
21 THOSE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES?
22 A.     WELL, WHAT HAPPENS IS THAT THE SETUP PROGRAM LOOKS TO
23 SEE IF THE USER HAS AN OLDER VERSION OF ONE OF THOSE
24 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARY FILE. AND IF SO, THE SETUP PROGRAM
25 COPIES OVER THE NEWER VERSION CONTAINED ON THE WORD 97 CD.
 
1 Q.     NOW, IF YOU INSTALL WORD 97 AND NORTON UTILITIES AND
2 THEN REMOVED THEM USING THE ADD/REMOVE UTILITY THAT WE
3 WERE TALKING ABOUT EARLIER, WHAT HAPPENS?
4 A.     THE PROGRAMS ARE EFFECTIVELY REMOVED; THEY ARE NO
5 LONGER AVAILABLE.
6 Q.     SO CAN A USER--CAN A USER USE EITHER WORD 97 OR
7 NORTON UTILITIES AFTER THEY HAVE BEEN REMOVED IN THIS
8 FASHIOW?
9 A.     NO.
10 Q.     AND WHAT HAPPENS TO WINDOWS AFTER YOU HAVE REMOVED
11 THEM IN THIS FASHION?
12 A.     NOTHING UNTOWARD. EVERYTHING WORKS FINE.
13 Q.     AND WHY IS THIS THE CASE?
14 A.     BECAUSE THE DE-INSTALLATION OF THE REMOVAL SEQUENCE,
15 THE SCRIPTS THAT WB ALLUDED TO EARLIER THAT RUN WHEN YOU
16 ACTUALLY USE THE ADD/REMOVE PROGRAMS UTILITY, LEAVE THESE
17 SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES IN PLACE.
18 Q.     WOW, LET'S FOCUS ON IE 3. HOW DOES THE MICROSOFT
19 PROPOSAL TO REMOVE IE 3 FROM OSR 2 BY HAVING THE OEM
20 DELETE ALL THE FILES THAT MAKE UP IE 3 AND THE RETAIL
21 CHANNEL AFFECT THE SHARED-PROGRAM LIBRARIES THAT ARE
22 DISTRIBUTED WITH IE 3?
23 A.     ONE WOULD HAVE TO DELETE THOSE FILES.
24 Q.     AND IF YOU DELETE THOSE FILES, WHAT HAPPENS TO
25 WINDOWS?
 
 
1 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
2

FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

3

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,    
                  PLAINTIFF,
                  vs.
MICROSOFT CORPORATION, ET AL.,
                  DEFENDANTS.

|
|
|
|
|
|         
C.A. NO. 94-1564
4
5
6
7
8
9
10  
11 FOR THE PLAINTIFF: PHILLIP WALONE, ESQ.    
PAULINE T, WAN, ESQ.    
U. S. DEPT. OF JUSTICE
ANTITRUST DIVISION
450 GOLDEN GATE AVE
P. O. BOX 36046
SAN FRANCISCO, CA, 94102

MARK S, POPOFSKY, ESQ.    
U.S. DEPT. OF JUSTICE
ANTITRUST DIVISION
10TH & PENN.AVE., N.W,
WASH., D. C. 20530

12
13
14
15
16
17
18 FOR THE DEFENDANTS: RICHARD J. UROWSKY, ESQ.    
STEVEN L. HOLLEY, ESQ.    
JOHH L. WARDEN, ESQ.    
SULLIVAN & CROWWBLL
125 BROAD STREET
NEW YORK, N.Y. 10004
19
20
21
22 COURT REPORTER: PHYLLIS MERANA
6816 U.S. COURTHOUSE
3RD & CONSTITUTION AVE., N.W.
WASHINGTON, D. C. 2 0001
23
24
25
1 THE -- WHAT IS HAPPENING INTERNALLY BEHIND THE SCENES IN
2 THIS PROCESS OF REMOVING IE?
3 A.     YES. I HAVE LOOKED AT THIS AND WHAT HAPPENS -- WELL,
4 SEVERAL THINGS HAPPEN. A NUMBER OF FILES GET DELETED FROM
5 THE DISK. THE DESK-TOP ICON GOES AWAY. THE "START MENU"
6 ENTRY GOES AWAY, VARIOUS CHANGES ARE MADE TO WINDOWS 95
7 CONFIGURATION FILES, AND ALL OF THE ACCESS MECHANISMS FOR
8 INVOKING OR RUNNING INTERNET EXPLORER AT THAT POINT ARE
9 GONE.
10      THERE IS A SEQUENCE OF STEPS THAT ARE CONTAINED IN
11 A SCRIPT THAT DEFINES PRECISELY WHAT THE COMPUTER IS
12 SUPPOSED TO DO WHEN THE USER GOES THROUGH THIS PROCEDURE.
13 Q.     NOW, AT THIS POINT I WANT TO TURN TO THE HEARING THAT
14 WAS CONDUCTED BY THIS COURT ON DECEMBER 19TH OF 1997. DID
15 YOU REVIEW A TRANSCRIPT OF THAT HEARING?
16 A.     YES, I DID.
17 Q.     AND DID YOU READ THE DESCRIPTION THAT THE COURT GAVE OF
18 THE DEMONSTRATION HE SAW CALLED "UNINSTALLATION OF INTERNET
19 EXPLORER"?
20 A.     YES.
21 Q.     NOW, STARTING AT THE POINT AT WHICH YOU HAD ALREADY PUT
22 IE -- REINSTALLED IE AND MADE IT AN ENTRY IN ADD/REMOVE
23 PROGRAM MENU, HOW DID THE COURT'S DEMONSTRATION COMPARE TO
24 WHAT YOU DID?
25 A.     WHAT HAPPENED WAS THE SAME.
 
1 Q.     OVERALL, TAKING THE WHOLE PROCESS INTO ACCOUNT, WERE
2 THERE ANY DIFFERENCES BETWEEN WHAT YOU DID AND WHAT THE
3 COURT SAW THAT DAY?
4 A.     YES. THE ONLY DIFFERENCE WAS THAT I HAD TO GO THROUGH
5 THE PROCESS OF BASICALLY REINSTALLING INTERNET EXPLORER ONTO
6 THE PC IN ORDER TO GET THAT LINE TO SHOW UP IN THE LIST OF
7 INSTALLED PROGRAMS.
8 Q.     NOW, BESIDES THE SPECIFIC PROCEDURE THAT YOU FOLLOWED
9 HERE TO REMOVE IE, DID YOU REVIEW ANY OTHER ALTERNATIVES TO
10 ACHIEVE THE REMOVAL OF IE?
11 A.     YES.
12 Q.     NOW, MR. WEADOCK, I HAVE HANDED YOU TWO EXHIBITS -- TWO
13 DOCUMENTS MARKED GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT -- MARKED FOR
14 IDENTIFICATION AS GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 4 AND GOVERNMENT'S
15 EXHIBIT 5, LET'S START WITH GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 4. DO YOU
16 RECOGNIZE WHAT THIS IS?
17 A.     YES. THIS IS ANOTHER KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLE FROM
18 MICROSOFT.
19 Q.     AND GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 5?
20 A.     YES. THIS IS AN ARTICLE FROM COMPUTER RESELLER NEWS,
21 DATED DECEMBER 18, 1997.
22 Q.     AND HAVE YOU REVIEWED THESE ARTICLES BEFORE?
23 A.     YES, I HAVE.
24 Q.     GENERALLY, WHAT DO THEY DEAL WITH?
25 A.     THEY DEAL WITH METHODS OF REMOVING INTERNET EXPLORER
 
1 FROM WINDOWS 95.
2         MS. WAN: YOUR HONOR, WE OFFER GOVERNMENT'S 4 AND
3 5?
4         MR. HOLLEY: YOUR HONOR, I JUST OBSERVE FOR THE
5 RECORD THAT GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 4 IS NOT, IN FACT, AN
6 ACCURATE REFLECTION OF WHAT APPEARS ON THE WEB PAGE, BUT I
7 DON'T THINK IT DIFFERS IN MATERIAL RESPECTS. THERE ARE TAGS
8 IN THIS DOCUMENT THAT SHOULD SHOW EITHER TEXT OR PICTURES.
9 AND I AM MOT OBJECTING. THE TEXT IS CORRECT, BUT THE PAGE
10 WOULD NOT LOOK LIKE THIS IF YOU WENT TO THE WEB. WITH THAT
11 NOTATION FOR THE RECORD, I HAVE NO OBJECTION.
12         THE COURT: VERY WELL. GOVERNMENT'S 4 AND 5 ARE
13 ADMITTED.
14 (WHEREUPON, GOVERNMENT'S
15 EXHIBIT NUMBER 4 AND 5 WERE
16 RECEIVED IN EVIDENCE.)
17 BY MS. WAN:
18 Q.     LET'S FOCUS ON GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 4 FIRST. NOW, WHAT
19 DOES THIS MICROSOFT DOCUMENT DESCRIBE?
20 A.     YES. THE TITLE IS "HOW TO REMOVE AND REINSTALL IE 3.0
21 FOR WINDOWS 95."
22 Q.     AND HOW DOES THE PROCEDURE THAT IS OUTLINED THERE
23 COMPARE WITH WHAT YOU DID?
24 A.     IT'S QUITE SIMILAR- THERE IS ONE DIFFERENCE IN THAT
25 THIS PARTICULAR KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLE RECOMMENDS THE
 
1 DELETION OF A COUPLE OF FOLDERS AT THE END OF THE PROCESS,
2 SPECIFICALLY MICROSOFT INTERNET AND WINDOWS/TEMPORARY
3 INTERNET FILES ~ THOSE TWO FOLDERS. PRETTY MUCH KIND OF A
4 TIDYING UP OR A HOUSEKEEPING STEP,
5 Q.     WHAT IS THE IMPACT ON THE USER IF YOU WERE TO TAKE THESE
6 TWO ADDITIONAL STEPS?
7 A.     OH, I DON'T THINK THE USER WOULD SEE ANY DIFFERENCE,
8 OTHER THAN THAT THEY WOULD HAVE A LITTLE BIT MORE FREE
9 HARD-DISK SPACE AFTER DELETING THESE DIRECTORIES.
10 Q.     NOW, LET'S TURN TO GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 5, WHICH WAS THE
11 NEWS ARTICLE.
12 A.     RIGHT.
13          MR. HOLLEY: YOUR HONOR, I OBJECT TO THE USE OF
14 THIS ARTICLE IF MS. WAN INTENDS TO INTRODUCE IT FOR THE
15 TRUTH OF WHAT IT SAYS.
16          MS. WAN: YOUR HONOR, I AM NOT INTENDING TO
17 INTRODUCE IT FOR THE TRUTH OF WHAT IT SAYS. I AM MERELY
18 OFFERING IT TO SHOW THAT THERE ARE OTHER -- THAT THERE WERE
19 REPORTED IN THE TRADE PRESS OTHER ALTERNATIVES TO REMOVING
20 IE, BUT NOT NECESSARILY THAT THOSE ALTERNATIVES WOULD WORK.
21          THE COURT: AS SO LIMITED, DO YOU STILL OBJECT?
22          MR. HOLLEY: I'M SORRY, YOUR HONOR.
23          THE COURT: AS SO LIMITED, DO YOU STILL OBJECT?
24          MR. HOLLEY: I WITHDRAW MY OBJECTION, YOUR HONOR.
25          THE COURT: VERY WELL.
 
1 BY MS. WAN:
2 Q.     OKAY. NOW, DID YOU REVIEW GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 5, THE
3 NEWS ARTICLE?
4 A.     YES.
5 Q.     AND WHAT DOES IT RECOMMEND? WHAT DOES IT SUGGEST AS A
6 WAY OF REMOVING IE?
7 A.     IT RECOMMENDS SIMPLY THE DELETION OF A SINGLE FILE,
8 IEXPLORE.EXE.
9 Q.     AND HOW DOES THIS COMPARE WITH THE PROCEDURE THAT YOU
10 ACTUALLY FOLLOWED?
11 A.     WELL, THE PROCEDURE THAT I FOLLOWED INVOKING THE
12 ADD/REMOVE PROGRAMS UTILITY TAKES SEVERAL STEPS ABOVE AND
13 BEYOND THIS SINGLE STEP,
14 Q.     SO DOES IT INCLUDE -- DOES IT ALSO INCLUDE THIS STEP?
15 A.     YES, IT DOES.
16 Q.     NOW, YOU MENTIONED EARLIER THAT GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBITS 3
17 AMD 4 CAME FROM SOMETHING CALLED THE "MICROSOFT KNOWLEDGE
18 BASE." CAN YOU GIVE US A LITTLE MORE EXPLANATION OF WHAT
19 THAT IS?
20 A.     YES. THE KNOWLEDGE BASE IS A COLLECTION Of QUITE A
21 NUMBER OF ARTICLES, TECHNICAL NOTES, AND ADVISORIES, PUT
22 TOGETHER, I UNDERSTAND. BY MICROSOFT PRODUCT SUPPORT
23 SERVICES. THIS INFORMATION IS AVAILABLE VIA MICROSOFT'S WEB
24 SITE. IT IS AVAILABLE IN OTHER FORMS AS WELL VIA THE
25 TECH-NET CD-ROM SUBSCRIPTION THAT ONE CAN PAY FOR AND
 
1 SUBSCRIBE TO. ALSO, IF YOU ARE A MEMBER OF THE MICROSOFT
2 DEVELOPER NETWORK. I MEAN THERE ARE ANY NUMBER OF MAYS THAT
3 USERS AND TECHNICAL PEOPLE CAN ACCESS THESE KNOWLEDGE-BASE
4 ARTICLES.
5 Q.     YOU MENTIONED TECH-NET. WHAT IS THAT, BRIEFLY?
6 A.     WELL, TECH-NET IS A PRODUCT -- A MICROSOFT PRODUCT THAT
7 SUPPLIES EACH MONTH ONE OR MORE CO-ROMS CONTAINING, AMONG
8 OTHER THINGS, KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLES LIKE THESE.
9 Q.     IS TECH-NET RELATED TO PRODUCT SUPPORT OR IS IT A
10 PRODUCT ITSELF?
11 A.     I WOULD CONSIDER IT A PRODUCT -- A MICROSOFT PRODUCT.
12 TECH-NET. IT IS SOMETHING THAT YOU CAN BUY AND SUBSCRIBE
13 TO.
14 Q.     IS IT IN THE NATURE OF DOCUMENTATION OR A PRODUCT THAT
15 ONE WOULD --
16 A.     IT'S IN THE NATURE OF DOCUMENTATION, THEY ALSO
17 INCLUDE -- MICROSOFT ALSO INCLUDES IN TECH-NET SOFTWARE
18 UPDATES, SERVICE PACKS, AND VARIOUS OTHER
19 UPDATE-AND-MAINTENANCE SOFTWARE.
20 Q.     NOW, GOING BACK TO THE KNOWLEDGE-BASE MATERIAL, IN THE
21 COURSE OF PREPARING FOR WRITING YOUR BOOKS AND TEACHING YOUR
22 SEMINARS, DO YOU HAVE OCCASION TO LOOK THROUGH THE
23 KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLES?
24 A.     YES, I DO. FREQUENTLY.
25 Q.     AND WHAT TYPE OF INFORMATION IS CONTAINED IN THESE
 
1 ARTICLES, AGAIN?
2 A.     WELL, A LOT OF THE TIME IT'S ADVICE ON HOW TO DO
3 SOMETHING THAT ISN'T PROPERLY EXPLAINED IN THE STANDARD
4 MICROSOFT DOCUMENTATION, ADVICE ON WHAT TO DO IF YOU RUN
5 INTO CERTAIN KINDS OF COMMON PROBLEMS, AND THAT SORT OF
6 INFORMATION,
7 Q.     NOW, DO THESE KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLES EVER WARN USERS
8 ABOUT THE CONSEQUENCES OF PERFORMING CERTAIN PROCEDURES?
9 A.     YES. THEY CERTAINLY DO. I AM IN THE MIDDLE OF WRITING
10 A BOOK ABOUT SOMETHING CALLED "THE WINDOWS 95 REGISTRY,"
11 WHICH IS KIND OF A CENTRAL STOREHOUSE OF CONFIGURATION
12 INFORMATION ABOUT WINDOWS 95. AND I THINK THAT EVERY
13 KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLE THAT I HAVE SEEN THAT HAS ANYTHING TO
14 DO WITH THE REGISTRY HAS A VERY CLEAR WARNING THAT YOU CAN
15 DAMAGE WINDOWS 95 IF YOU LON'T KNOW WHAT YOU'RE DOING WHEN
16 MODIFYING THE REGISTRY, AND IF YOU DON'T KNOW WHAT YOU'RE
17 DOING, YOU SHOULDN'T FOLLOW THE STEPS OUTLINED IN THE
18 KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLE,
19 Q.     NOW, AT THIS POINT I WOULD LIKE TO DIRECT YOUR ATTENTION
20 BACK TO THE TWO EXHIBITS, GOVERNMENT'S EXHIBIT 3 AND 4,
21 WHICH WERE THE TWO MICROSOFT KNOWLEDGE-BASE ARTICLES.
22 A.     OKAY.
23 Q.     WHAT IF ANY WARNINGS ARE THERE IN THESE TWO DOCUMENTS TO
24 THE USER OF THE IMPACT ON WINDOWS OF UNINSTALLING IE, USING
25 THE PROCEDURES THAT ARE DESCRIBED IN THOSE ARTICLES?
 
1 A.     WHAT IF ANY WARNINGS APPEAR?
2 Q.     YES.
3 A.     I DON'T SEE ANY WARNINGS OF ANY KIND.
4         MS. WAN: YOUR HONOR, AT THIS POINT I THINK WE'RE
5 AT A CONVENIENT BREAKING POINT, IF IT'S CONVENIENT FOR THE
6 COURT AS WELL.
7         THE COURT: ALL RIGHT, I THINK IT IS.
8         WE WILL TAKE OUR NOONTIME RECESS AND RECONVENE AT
9 2:00 O'CLOCK,
10         (WHEREUPON, AT 12:22 P.M., THE ABOVE-ENTITLED
11 MATTER WAS RECESSED TO RECONVENE AT 2:00 O'CLOCK.)
12  
13  
14                 CERTIFICATE OF REPORTER
15       THIS RECORD IS CERTIFIED BY THE UNDERSIGNED REPORTER TO
16 BE THE OFFICIAL TRANSCRIPT OF THE PROCEEDINGS INDICATED,
17 _______________/s/________________
18 PHYLLIS MERANA
19  
20  
21  
22  
23  
24  
25  

How to Uninstall Internet Explorer 4.0

Last reviewed: October 17,1997
Article ID: Q174265
The Information in this article applies to:

SUMMARY

This article describes how to uninstall (or remove) Internet Explorer 4.0 (version 4.71.1712.6). For information about uninstalling Internet Explorer Platform Preview 2.0 (version 4.71.1008). please see the following article in the Microsoft Knowledge Base:

When to Remove Interner Explorer

Remove Internet Explorer 4.0 before you perform any of the following actions:

Updated January 11, 2023